Tolls vs tradable permits for managing travel on a bimodal congested network with variable capacities and demands

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.trc.2023.104028Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Tradable Permit Schemes (TPS) are a promising tool to control traffic congestion.

  • We compare the efficiency of TPS and tolls on a bimodal network under uncertainty.

  • Neither the toll nor the permit quota can depend on demand or link capacities.

  • The toll is invariant to some model parameters, whereas the permit quota is not.

  • The toll also outperforms the TPS numerically in most instances examined.

Abstract

Congestion pricing has long been considered an efficient tool for tackling road traffic congestion, but tolls are generally unpopular. Interest is growing in tradable permits as an alternative. Tolls and tradable permits are interchangeable if travel conditions are unchanging, but not if conditions vary and tolls and permit quantities are inflexible and cannot be adapted to current conditions. We compare the allocative efficiency of tolls and tradable permits on a bimodal network under uncertainty. Road links are congestion prone and public transit may be crowded. Road traffic entering a cordon area around the downtown is controlled using either a toll or a tradable permit. Two groups of travelers can drive or take transit. Group 1 travels downtown, and if it drives it must either pay the toll or use a permit. Group 2 travels to a suburb, and can avoid the cordon by taking a bypass. All demand and cost parameters of the model can vary, either systematically or irregularly. Each parameter combination constitutes a state. Travelers learn the state in advance, and adapt their mode and route choices accordingly. A planner minimizes expected total travel costs by either setting the level of the toll or choosing the quota of permits to distribute. Two cases are considered. In the first, the toll and quota are flexible and can be adjusted to daily travel conditions. In the second, the instruments are inflexible and must be set at the same level regardless of the state. If travelers have identical preferences, the optimal flexible toll is invariant to the numbers of travelers in each group and the capacity of the link entering the cordon. The toll is robust in the sense that inflexibility causes no welfare loss if these parameters vary. By contrast, the quota is not robust.

We derive a general rule for ranking the efficiency of a fixed toll and fixed quota. We then explore a numerical example. In most instances, the fixed toll outperforms the fixed quota by a significant margin although the quota can do better in some states. We also compare the welfare-distributional effects of tolls and permits, and find that suburban travelers fare better than downtown travelers from both forms of regulation.

Introduction

Traffic congestion is a burden worldwide. Inrix reports that in 2019, US drivers lost nearly 100 h to traffic congestion on average, at a personal cost of $1377, amounting to a loss of nearly $88 billion to the US economy.1 Congestion imposes similar costs in the UK, France, and Germany.2 Congestion pricing has long been considered an efficient, if not the most efficient, tool for tackling traffic congestion. Advances in tolling and IT technology have reduced the costs of imposing tolls, billing motorists, and informing them about where, when, and how much they will pay. Yet, only a few city-scale congestion pricing schemes exist: in Singapore (1975), London (2003), Stockholm (2006), Milan (2008), and Gothenburg (2013). Smaller schemes have been established in Durham (2002) and Valletta (2007), and several cities including New York City have plans to introduce charges. However, many proposed schemes have failed. Public opposition and equity concerns are the most frequently cited explanations (Jaensirisak et al., 2005, Grisolía et al., 2015, Krabbenborg et al., 2020).

Due in part to opposition to tolls, quantity controls and regulations are much more widely used than tolls. These include limits on vehicle registrations, license plate number restrictions on daily use, perimeter control of traffic, driving bans, and traffic calming. These measures are often intended to curb not only congestion, but also reduce pollution, enhance safety, and reduce noise. For example, Fageda et al. (2020) report that low emission zones have been implemented in 46 out of 130 large cities in 12 European countries.

Quantity controls are generally less efficient than tolls because they do not allocate road space to those who value it the most. Tradable Permits Schemes (TPS) are a hybrid measure that combines price and quantity controls. TPS can improve on pure quantity controls by granting driving rights, and allowing agents to trade them. TPS have been used to reduce acid rain, lead, and carbon emissions; to administer Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards; and to allocate taxi licenses, vehicle quotas, and airport landing slots. TPS have not yet been applied to road travel. However, advances in information technology and familiarity with it are making TPS increasingly feasible. The idea is conceptually straightforward. Drivers would need a permit to make a trip, access a road, or enter a restricted area. The amount of travel would be regulated by limiting the number of permits that are issued. If permits are distributed free of charge, individuals in aggregate would not incur an additional monetary cost to travel. Furthermore, if permits are distributed on an equal-per-capita basis, lower-income households, which tend to travel less by car, would receive more permits than they use, and would earn income from selling the excess. Vertical equity could be improved further by giving lower-income households more permits.

If travel conditions are known and unvarying, a TPS can be designed to support the same travel pattern as tolls. The two instruments are then allocatively equivalent, with the TPS having a likely advantage in terms of acceptability. However, as initially shown by Weitzman (1974) in a planned-economy context, price and quantity instruments are not equivalent in a nonstationary environment if they cannot be adjusted as conditions change. Moreover, road travel conditions do fluctuate. Travel demand varies predictably by time of day, day of week, and season. Unanticipated fluctuations in capacity and demand are also common. According to US FHWA (2020), about half of total congestion delays arises from nonrecurring events such as crashes, debris, work zones, traffic signal failures, bad weather, special events, and so on. These shocks can cause substantial delays. Closure of one lane of a three-lane highway due to an incident reduces total capacity by about half.3 Heavy rain can reduce freeway capacity by 10%–15% (van Lint et al., 2000, Chung et al., 2006, Brilon et al., 2008), and snow storms and other severe weather conditions by more than 20%. Capacity can also drop if individual drivers change lanes or brake sharply, and cause traffic flow to break down (Brilon et al., 2008). Public transit service disruptions due to strikes and other shocks are also common in some cities, and they can affect traffic congestion if transit users switch to driving.4 Rain, snowfall, and high temperatures encourage commuters to drive rather than take public transit or walking (Belloc et al., 2022). Finally, great shocks such as the COVID pandemic can affect travel demand for extended periods (de Palma et al., 2022).

Tradable permits and tolling schemes would still be allocatively equivalent if they could adapt to all these fluctuations. Yet, with the exception of dynamic pricing on some High Occupancy Toll (HOT) lanes in the US and Israel, real-time, state-dependent road pricing has not been adopted (Lombardi et al., 2021). Several explanations have been suggested. The infrastructure, operating, and accounting costs may be too high to justify state-dependent pricing over short time horizons. People may prefer fixed charges because adapting to frequent price changes is difficult (Bonsall et al., 2007), or because the outlays are easier to predict (Li and Hensher, 2010). People may also dislike price uncertainty per se (Lindsey, 2011), and they may dislike having to pay high tolls if they have no good alternative.

The potential for an adaptable TPS is still unknown since no schemes are operational yet. Nevertheless, transactions costs militate against frequently changing either the number of permits distributed, or the number of permit units required to use particular roads or enter certain areas. Permit quotas are likely to be distributed weekly, monthly, or quarterly rather than daily, and requirements are likely to be set systematically (e.g., by day of week or season) rather than adjusted according to current travel conditions.5

In this paper, we assume that tolls and tradable permits allocations are inflexible, and thus cannot be adjusted on the basis of daily travel conditions. We compare the allocative efficiency of tolls and permits in the face of shocks to demand, road capacity, and transit, assuming no administration, transactions, or traveler compliance costs are incurred for either instrument. Unlike earlier studies that compare tolls and permits under variable conditions, in our model the instruments are applied over only part of the transport network. Hence, they are second-best and cannot support a first-best optimum even under stationary conditions. We summarize our main results at the end of the literature review in the next section.

Section snippets

Literature review

This paper relates to three streams of literature: on congestion pricing, on tradable permits systems, and on network reliability and robustness.

Congestion pricing

The literature on congestion pricing is vast.6 Most work has assumed that travel conditions are known, but

Network components and travel choices

The bimodal city network is shown in Fig. 1. There is one origin, O, which could be an inner or outer suburb. Two groups of travelers live at O and travel to distinct destinations. Group g=d comprises Nd individuals who travel to downtown (D).11 Group g=s comprises Ns individuals who travel to a more distant suburban workplace (S). The two groups are hereafter called downtown travelers and suburban travelers, respectively. The numbers in each group

Regulation to control congestion and crowding

Given traffic congestion, transit crowding (in the case of Crowded transit), and biases in mode and route choices, the total costs of travel are not, in general, minimized in the unregulated equilibrium. Total costs, TC, equal the combined travel costs incurred by downtown and suburban travelers, or, equivalently, the combined costs of driving and using transit: TC=acavava+gC̃gRNgRNgR.

The first-best optimum for a given state can be derived by minimizing total costs in Eq. (6) subject to the

The flexible toll

General properties

Let τox denote the flexible toll, where superscript o denotes optimal. The flexible toll is chosen to minimize total costs in Eq. (7): τox=ArgminτTCNτ,x,x.

The analytics of the toll resemble second-best pricing of two parallel routes in Verhoef et al. (1996), but they are more complex and the formula for the flexible toll is very complicated for the general case with parameter f. With possible exceptions, an increase in the toll reduces congestion on the upper, cordon, and

Welfare effects of regulation on individual travelers

Attention so far has focused on the aggregate effects of the toll and TPS. From both a public policy and a political economy standpoint, it is also important to examine the impacts on individuals  (De Borger and Russo, 2018). Three assumptions will be made to limit the complexity of analysis. First, all travelers receive the same permit allocation regardless of their destination and choice of travel mode.21

The inflexible toll and inflexible quota

We now assume that the toll and quota are inflexible, and chosen to minimize the expected value of total social costs. For brevity, the optimized toll will be called the fixed toll, and the optimized quota the fixed quota. The fixed toll, τ, solves: τ=ArgminτETCNτ,x,x,where E is the expectations operator. Expectations are taken over the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of states, F(x), which may be discrete or continuous. The state, x, is assumed to be bounded, and all states are

Setup

Although a number of analytical results have now been derived, gaps remain and the quantitative difference in performance of the toll and TPS remains unexplored. To proceed further, numerical examples are investigated. Base-case parameter values are chosen to correspond approximately with the network used in de Palma et al. (2005) to study dynamic cordon and area-based tolls on a bimodal network with traffic congestion, but no transit crowding. Values of travel time by road and transit are

Conclusions

Tolls and tradable permits are alternative tools for tackling road traffic congestion. They are interchangeable if travel conditions are unchanging, but not if conditions vary and the instruments are inflexible. We compare the efficiency of a fixed toll and a fixed permit quota for controlling entry to a downtown area. Travel demand, road conditions, and transit service can all fluctuate. We analyze the model in a series of steps. First, we examine how travelers’ mode and route choices vary

CRediT authorship contribution statement

Robin Lindsey: Conceptualization, Methodology, Formal analysis, Validation, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing, Supervision, Validation, Funding acquisition, Project administration. André de Palma: Conceptualization, Methodology, Writing – review & editing, Supervision, Validation. Pouya Rezaeinia: Conceptualization, Methodology, Software, Writing – review & editing, Validation.

Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Acknowledgments

For helpful comments and suggestions we are grateful to Paolo Delle Site, Patrick Stokkink, and other seminar participants at the CY Transport and Urban Seminar. Thanks are also due to Erik Verhoef and other session participants at the 2021 conference of the International Transportation Economics Association. Any errors are ours. Financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (Grant 435-2019-0525) is gratefully acknowledged. This study was also supported by

References (74)

  • DogteromN. et al.

    Tradable credits for managing car travel: A review of empirical research and relevant behavioural approaches

    Transp. Rev.

    (2017)
  • DongJ. et al.

    State-dependent pricing for real-time freeway management: Anticipatory versus reactive strategies

    Transp. Res. C

    (2011)
  • FanW. et al.

    Tradable mobility permits in roadway capacity allocation: Review and appraisal

    Transp. Policy

    (2013)
  • GrisolíaJ.M. et al.

    Increasing the acceptability of a congestion charging scheme

    Transp. Policy

    (2015)
  • HaywoodL. et al.

    The distribution of crowding costs in public transport: New evidence from Paris

    Transp. Res. Part A: Policy Pract.

    (2015)
  • HörcherD. et al.

    A review of public transport economics

    Econ. Transp.

    (2021)
  • KickhöferB. et al.

    Pricing local emission exposure of road traffic: An agent-based approach

    Transp. Res. Part D: Transp. Environ.

    (2015)
  • KrabbenborgL. et al.

    Public frames in the road pricing debate: A Q-methodology study

    Transp. Policy

    (2020)
  • LamW.H.K. et al.

    Modeling impacts of adverse weather conditions on a road network with uncertainties in demand and supply

    Transp. Res. B

    (2008)
  • LeheL.

    Downtown congestion pricing in practice

    Transp. Res. C

    (2019)
  • LindseyR.

    State-dependent congestion pricing with reference-dependent preferences

    Transp. Res. B

    (2011)
  • MayA.D. et al.

    Optimal locations and charges for cordon schemes

  • MunS.I. et al.

    Optimal cordon pricing

    J. Urban Econ.

    (2003)
  • MunS.I. et al.

    Optimal cordon pricing in a non-monocentric city

    Transp. Res. Part A: Policy Pract.

    (2005)
  • NicholsonA. et al.

    Degradable transportation systems: An integrated equilibrium model

    Transp. Res. B

    (1997)
  • RussoA. et al.

    Welfare losses of road congestion: Evidence from Rome

    Reg. Sci. Urban Econ.

    (2021)
  • SeshadriR. et al.

    Congestion tolling — dollars versus tokens: Within-day dynamics

    Transp. Res. C

    (2022)
  • TabuchiT.

    Bottleneck congestion and modal split

    J. Urban Econ.

    (1993)
  • VosoughS. et al.

    Predictive cordon pricing to reduce air pollution

    Transp. Res. Part D: Transp. Environ.

    (2020)
  • AgarwalA. et al.

    The correlation of externalities in marginal cost pricing: Lessons learned from a real-world case study

    Transportation

    (2018)
  • ArnottR. et al.

    A structural model of peak- period congestion: A traffic bottleneck with elastic demand

    Amer. Econ. Rev.

    (1993)
  • BellocI. et al.

    Weather Conditions and Daily CommutingIZA Discussion Paper No. 15661

    (2022)
  • BrilonW. et al.

    Implementing the concept of reliability for highway capacity analysis

    Transp. Res. Rec.

    (2008)
  • ChenA. et al.

    Network-based accessibility measures for vulnerability analysis of degradable transportation networks

    Netw. Spat. Econ.

    (2007)
  • Chung, E., Ohtani, O., Warita, H., Kuwahara, M., Morita, H., 2006. Does weather affect highway capacity. In:...
  • CzernyA.I.

    Managing congested airports under uncertainty

  • DalziellE.P. et al.

    Risk and impact of natural hazards on a road network

    ASCE J. Transp. Eng.

    (2001)
  • View full text