1 Introduction

The impact of the exchange rate on international trade has been widely investigated in the literature. Some studies have emphasized the risks associated with exchange rate variability, which should discourage economic agents from international trading. Other studies have emphasized that exchange rate volatility should have no impact on cross-border transactions because of the availability of instruments with which to hedge against risks of this type. The question of the effect of exchange rate variability on trade is therefore an empirical matter.

The literature dealing with cross-border trade in goods and services has been rather mixed (McKenzie, 1999; Tenreyro, 2007), and, also in regard to financial markets, empirical analyses have reported controversial results (Jorion, 1991; Fidora et al., 2007; Sandoval & Vàsquez, 2009; Borensztein & Loungani, 2011; Caporale et al., 2015; Dyakov & Wipplinger, 2018).

The above-mentioned literature encompasses analyses that rely on different exchange rate volatility measures, bilateral or effective exchange rates, nominal or real exchange rates, and that span different time periods and country samples.Footnote 1

The first contribution of this paper is its investigation of the impact of exchange rate volatility on financial transactions across borders in a wide perspective. Indeed, we analyze the role played by bilateral nominal and real exchange rate volatility in bilateral foreign portfolio equity investments, in 68 developed and emerging markets, in the period 2001–2017, which encompasses a pre-crisis, a crisis, and a post-crisis period.

We find that exchange rate volatility negatively and significantly affected cross-border portfolio investments, when considering either nominal or real exchange rates, using either a continuous or a dichotomic definition of volatility with different time lags.

The literature studying the impact of the exchange rate on cross-border trade of goods and services has identified a multi-dimensional heterogeneity in this effect. The survey by McKenzie (1999) concluded that exchange rate volatility may have a different impacts on different markets. Exchange rate volatility has been found to affect trade flows asymmetrically, with a very different impact of extremely large versus extremely small changes in volatility (Chang et al., 2020). The effect is found to be larger for smaller and developing economies (Micco et al., 2003; Baldwin, 2006; Santos Silva & Tenreyro, 2010), and to vary over time (De Sousa, 2012). In particular, Sandoval & Vàsquez (2009) highlighted an asymmetry in pricing exchange rate risk, with a small and insignificant risk premium of exchange rate exposure in up-market periods, and a significant one in down-market periods.

The paper’s second contribution is therefore its search for the presence of heterogeneity in the impact of exchange rate volatility on financial markets, as already found in regard to trade of goods. Indeed, the controversial results in financial markets may hide a significant heterogeneity which might have generated an aggregation bias similar to the one found, across countries or sectors, in the trade literature (Péridy, 2003; Bahmani-Oskooee & Hegerty, 2007).

The empirical evidence points to the presence of a source of heterogeneity between emerging and developed economies: the exchange rate has become more volatile in the major emerging market economies, as a consequence of the global financial stress (Coudert et al., 2011; Ilzetzki et al., 2019), while major currency exchange volatility has substantially decreased. Ilzetzki et al. (2019), for instance, demonstrate a visible secular decline in exchange rate volatility in the dollar-Deutschmark cross-rate from the end of the Bretton Woods system to 2018, despite the volatility’s counter-cyclical nature.

We find that the negative association between bilateral foreign portfolio investments and the volatility of the exchange rate crucially depends upon both the time period and the groups of countries considered. Indeed, it significantly weakened after 2012—that is, after the crisis—with an especially strong and significant effect for large economies, the ones experiencing the most visible decline in exchange rate volatility.

These findings may have had important implications also in regard to bilateral cross-border portfolio equity holdings within the European Monetary Union. The assumption of a negative nexus between exchange rate volatility and trade was one of the pillars of the creation of the European Monetary Union (Commission, 1990): the adoption of a common currency was indeed expected to lead to an increase in the volume of trade among member countries, as reviewed in Glick & Rose (2016).Footnote 2

Interestingly, De Sousa (2012) found that the currency union’s impact on trade was decreasing over time. Similarly, Giofré & Sokolenko (2022), for equity holdings, highlighted that the crisis has drastically weakened the linkages among the original members: a marked decline of economic development and, more importantly, a deterioration of the control of corruption standards by periphery countries, those hardest hit by the European sovereign debt crisis, induced a sharp decrease of their inward investments from the Euro area as a whole.

The third contribution of the paper lies in the investigation and discussion of this specific point. We conjecture that the declining global effect of exchange rate volatility in the post-crisis period can be adduced as one of the main drivers of the fall in bilateral equity investment in the Euro area in that period. The data do not reject this hypothesis: it is indeed likely that a lower responsiveness of international investment to exchange rate volatility challenged the relevance of the full exchange risk hedging system represented by the common currency area in the post-crisis period, when the countercyclical spikes of exchange rate volatility were absorbed.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the literature on the linkage between exchange rate volatility and trade in goods and financial transactions. In Sect. 3, we outline the estimable equation. In Sect. 4, we describe the data and discuss some descriptive statistics. In Sect. 5, we perform the empirical analysis. Section 6 summarizes and concludes.

2 Exchange rate volatility and trade: a short review

Theoretically, transaction costs, and especially currency risks, constitute a barrier to trade which dampens the volume of the exchange of goods and services. The elimination of these costs and exchange rate variability should expand cross-border transactions and produce greater integration. On the other hand, sceptics stress that, even in a turbulent currency environment, there are various financial instruments that enable exporters and importers to hedge against exchange risks, so that the potential increase in trade deriving from the elimination of exchange rate volatility is at best small. The counter-argument is that exchange rate risk hedging cannot be complete, and it is in any case costly, especially for small-size exporting firms: if exchange rate movements are not fully anticipated, an increase in exchange rate volatility may induce risk-averse agents to reduce their international trading activities (De Nardis & Vicarelli, 2003).

Empirically, the evidence in support of the hypothesis of a negative link between exchange rate volatility and trade remains somewhat ambiguous (see (McKenzie, 1999; Auboin & Ruta, 2013), for a review). These mixed conclusions are illustrated in an IMF study on exchange rate volatility and trade flows (IMF, 2004), which explores various dimensions, such as type of volatility (short- and long-run, real and nominal), country groups (by regions and income levels), and type of trade (different types of goods).

The impact of exchange rate volatility on financial markets has also been widely investigated by the literature (Biger, 1979; Cushman, 1985; Doidge et al., 2001; Gorg & Wakelin, 2002; Brzozowski, 2006; Mishra, 2011), considering both the nominal (Biger, 1979; Doidge et al., 2001; Gorg & Wakelin, 2002; Brzozowski, 2006) and the real exchange rate (Cushman, 1985; Mishra, 2011). Also in the case of financial markets, the empirical evidence remains mixed.

Biger (1979) studied the importance of the exchange risk on the portfolio allocation from 1966 to 1976 for 13 industrialized countries and found that exchange risk matters much less than would be expected for international portfolios. Jorion (1991) found that the exchange rate risk is diversifiable, and his empirical findings provide little evidence that US investors require compensation for bearing the exchange rate risk. Gorg & Wakelin (2002) studied the impact of the level of the exchange rate, volatility in the exchange rate, and exchange rate expectations on outward US foreign direct investment in 12 developed countries from 1983 to 1995, and found no evidence of an effect on either US outward investment or inward investment in the USA. Conversely, exchange rate volatility increases the costs of international financial transactions, thus reducing potential gains from international diversification by making the acquisition of foreign equities more risky (Solnik & McLeavey, 2004; Caporale et al., 2015). Indeed, Fidora et al. (2007) and Borensztein & Loungani (2011) found that exchange rate volatility is an essential factor for bilateral equity and bond portfolio home bias in developed and emerging economies. When dealing more specifically with foreign equity investment, Thapa & Poshakwale (2011) found that investors tend to invest less in countries experiencing higher movement in their exchange rates, and, more recently, Dyakov & Wipplinger (2018) have show that international equity mutual funds underweight equity markets with risky currencies and overweight equity markets with less risky ones.

3 Estimable equation

Our baseline estimation builds on the following specification:Footnote 3

$$\begin{aligned} \log (FPE_{sh})&= \alpha +\sum _{j=1,..,J}\beta ^{j}X_{h}^{j}+\sum _{k=1,..,K}\varphi ^{k}Y_{s}^{k}+\sum _{l=1,..,L}\delta ^{l}Z_{sh}^{l}+\sum _{m=1,..,M}\theta ^{m}\log (Q_{h}^{m})\\&\quad+\sum _{n=1,..,N}\rho ^{n}\log (T_{s}^{n}) +\sum _{p=1,..,P}\sigma ^{p}\log (W_{sh}^{p})+\gamma D+\varepsilon _{sh} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

The dependent variable \(\log (FPE_{sh})\) is the logarithm of the foreign portfolio equities (FPE) invested by source country s in host country h.

Our regression specification accounts for pair-specific regressors (\(Z_{sh}\) or \(W_{sh}\)), such as the bilateral exchange rate volatility, country-specific variables (\(X_{h},Y_{s},Q_{h}\), \(T_{s}\)), such as size variables, and time factors (D).

Among these covariates, continuous regressors (\(Q_{h}\), \(T_{s}\) and \(W_{sh}\)) are expressed in logarithmic terms, so that their coefficients can be easily interpreted in elasticity terms (e.g., if a significant coefficient is equal to 0.3, then a 10% increase in the regressor induces a 3% increase in the dependent variable). Conversely, the effect of a dichotomous variable (\(X_{h},Y_{s}\) and \(Z_{sh}\)) on a dependent variable expressed in logs is captured by the following transformation of its coefficients \(\beta\) : \(e^{\beta }-1\) (e.g., if a significant coefficient \(\beta\) is equal to 0.3, then the effect of a dummy equal to 1 on the dependent variable is \(e^{0.3}-1=0.35,\) to be interpreted as the effect being \(35\%\) larger than the effect of a dummy equal to 0).Footnote 4

Finally, D is a dummy capturing the time dimension, such as the pre-crisis, crisis, or post-crisis period, which enables us to detect any global shift in foreign investment due to macroeconomic shocks.

To investigate the evolution of the linkages between bilateral FPE and bilateral exchange rate volatility (\(sd\_RE_{sh}\)), the econometric specification (1) is enriched to include interactions between \(sd\_RE_{sh}\) and time factors (D). Using a Difference-in-Difference approach, we seek to grasp the eventual time-varying effect of exchange rate volatility on FPE, on top of the global effect exerted by D on FPE.

$$\begin{aligned} \log (FPE_{sh})=\alpha +\beta (sd\_ER_{sh})+\gamma D+\delta (sd\_ER_{sh}\cdot D)+controls+\varepsilon _{sh} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

Our econometric strategy follows Santos Silva & Tenreyro (2006) who explicitly addressed, within the standard trade log gravity models, the problem of inflation of zero investment data, and the need to obtain estimates robust to different patterns of heteroskedasticity. Accordingly, we model the dependent variable \(FPE_{sh}\) as following a Poisson distribution. We apply the Poisson Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood estimator, with year dummy, individual fixed effect, which in our case corresponds to country-pair fixed effects, and with standard errors adjusted for two-way clustering at the investing-destination country pair and year levels.

4 Data and descriptive statistics

4.1 Data

We examined the impact of exchange rate volatility on the bilateral equity portfolio investments using panel data on 68 countries in the 2001–2017 period.Footnote 5

The data on the bilateral equity portfolio investments were drawn from the Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey (CPIS), issued by the IMF, a dataset which has been used in many papers in recent decades (Fidora et al., 2007; Lane & Milesi-Ferretti, 2007), Sorensen et al., 2007; Giannetti & Koskinen, 2010; Giofré, 2014). This survey collects security-level data from the major custodians and large end-investors. Portfolio investment is broken down by instrument (equity or debt) and residence of issuer, the latter providing information on the destination of portfolio investment.Footnote 6

However, the CPIS is unable to address the issue of third-country holdings and round-tripping, which is very frequent in the case of financial offshore centers. Following the more recent literature on offshore center classifications, we excluded from our sample "the eight major pass-through economies—the Netherlands, Luxembourg, Hong Kong SAR, the British Virgin Islands, Bermuda, the Cayman Islands, Ireland, and Singapore— [hosting] more than 85 percent of the world’s investment in special purpose entities, which are often set up for tax reasons” (Damgaard et al., 2018).Footnote 7

To construct the measure of exchange rate volatility, we relied on raw data drawn from the International Financial Statistics (IMF). The exchange rate volatility that we adopted is quite standard in the literature (see (Rose, 2000), among others): it is measured by the standard deviation of the first-difference of the monthly natural logarithm of the bilateral exchange rate in the five preceding years. Since the literature has relied on both the nominal and the real exchange rate, we considered both measures in our analysis. The real exchange rate volatility was defined by relying on the consumer price index (CPI) or on the producer price index (PPI).

Details on the definition of the dependent variable and the regressors, and information on their respective sources are reported in “Appendix 1”.

4.2 Descriptive statistics

Table 1 reports the main descriptive statistics of the variables included in our analysis.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

The first panel reports the dependent variable, i.e., the bilateral portfolio equities holdings expressed in US$. The second panel refers to the main regressor, i.e., the exchange rate volatility. We first report the descriptive statistics of the nominal exchange rate (NER) volatility, defined as the standard deviation of the first-difference of the monthly natural logarithm of the bilateral nominal exchange rate in the 5 preceding years: its mean is equal to 1.2%, with a standard deviation equal to 0.7% and a maximum equal to 6.2%. We then report its dichotomic counterpart (H NER (5y)), which is equal to 1 if the nominal exchange rate volatility is high, i.e., if it is above the mean, and 0 otherwise. We also report the corresponding 1-year NER volatility measure, in its continuous and dichotomic version. Finally, we report the statistics for two measures of volatility of the real exchange rate (CPI-based and PPI-based), with their dichotomic counterparts, in both their 5-year and 1-year specifications. Their mean, standard deviation, and range are close to the corresponding nominal exchange rate’s statistics.

The third panel comprises all other regressors, and is further split into sub-groups. We first report the bilateral stock returns’ correlation variable, with a mean equal to 0.34, a median of 0.37, and a standard deviation equal to 0.62. Its dichotomic counterpart (H correl\(_{sh}\)) is equal to 1 if the bilateral returns correlation between source country and destination country is high, i.e., if it is above the mean, and 0 otherwise.

With the sole exception of the distance variable, the bilateral gravity variables are binary, expressing whether country-pairs share a border, a common language, colonial linkages, or legal origins.

The capital mobility variable ranges from 0 to 10, to indicate increasing levels of capital mobility. Finally, the size variables are stock market capitalization, GDP per capita and GDP, all defined in US$ and all displaying a notable cross-country dispersion.

5 Empirical analysis

5.1 The role of exchange rate volatility

Recently, Ilzetzki et al. (2019) have shown that, even if some emerging markets have become more volatile with the global financial crisis, major currency exchange volatility has substantially decreased. In Fig. 1, we report Ilzetzki et al. (2019)’s Figure I, which shows the absolute value of the monthly change in the dollar-Deutschmark cross-rate from the end of the Bretton Woods system to 2018 (the German DM is replaced by the euro after 1999): despite its counter-cyclical nature, a visible secular decline in exchange rate volatility clearly emerges.Footnote 8

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: Ilzetzki et al. (2019) (figure 1, p. 604)

Declining volatility in Dollar-Deutschmark (Euro) Exchange Rate. This figure is drawn from Ilzetzki et al. (2019). The original caption is reported at the bottom of the figure.

In this paper, we explore the conjecture that the generalized decline in exchange rate volatility, probably correlated with a lower perceived currency risk, is paired with a decrease in the need for risk exchange hedging among foreign portfolio equity investors.

Figure 2 reports the dynamics of the bilateral exchange rate volatility from 2001 to 2017 for the country pairs considered in the analysis. Panel (a) refers to the bilateral nominal exchange rate, while panel (b) refers to the CPI-based real exchange rate, where the consumer price index (CPI) is used to convert the nominal into the real exchange rate.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Volatility in bilateral exchange rate. This figure reports the volatility of the real exchange rate, defined as the standard deviation of the first-difference of the monthly natural logarithm of the bilateral exchange rate in the 5 preceding years. Panel a refers to the bilateral nominal exchange rate, while panel b refers to CPI-based real exchange rate

Our graphs are based on the worldwide bilateral exchange rate volatility, but they quite faithfully replicate the dynamics observed by Ilzetzki et al. (2019) in the corresponding period: a rise during the crisis, within a general declining trend. A similar pattern is observed when considering a different definition of the real exchange rate, PPI-based, where the producer price index (PPI) is used to convert the nominal into the real exchange rate (Fig. 3 in “Appendix 2”).

In Table 2, we consider an econometric specification that follows Eq. (1), in which the dependent variable is the logarithm of bilateral foreign equity investment (FPE) and the regressors are reported at the head of the rows. The specification includes standard gravity variables used in literature to define the cultural and geographic proximity between two countries, the size variables, which express the economic weight of the investing and host countries, such as market capitalization and GDP per capita, and the control for capital mobility. As specified above, the coefficients of all regressors expressed in logs can be interpreted in elasticity terms, while the effect of dummy variables on the dependent variable is captured by the coefficient \(\beta\) as follows: \(e^{\beta }-1.\)

Table 2 FPE and exchange rate volatility

Our main regressor is the exchange rate volatility.Footnote 9 Columns (#a) consider the bilateral exchange rate volatility in the 5 preceding years, columns (#b) instead consider the volatility in the previous year. Since the literature has studied how foreign investments have been affected by the volatility of both nominal (Biger, 1979; Doidge et al., 2001; Gorg & Wakelin, 2002; Brzozowski, 2006) and real exchange rates (Cushman, 1985; Mishra, 2011), columns (1a) and (1b) consider the nominal exchange rate volatility, columns (2a) and (2b) consider the CPI-based real exchange rate, and columns (3a) and (3b) consider the PPI-based real exchange rate. In all specifications, the coefficient of the exchange rate volatility is negative and strongly significant, thus suggesting that a higher bilateral exchange rate volatility deters cross-border investments.

To underline the economic significance of this effect, we point out that a 1% increase of the exchange rate volatility of the nominal exchange rate induces a change in bilateral FPE ranging from \(-\,15\) to \(-\,20\)%, which is a quite sizable effect. The effect of real exchange rate volatility appears to be stronger than the effect of nominal exchange rate volatility, while the comparison between the 5-year and the 1-year indicators does not yield any clear-cut pattern.

In Table 3, we replicate the same analysis as in Table 2, but we replace the exchange rate volatility with its binary counterpart. We define with NERH RER_CPIH RER_PPI a dummy variable equal to 1 if the bilateral (nominal, real CPI-based or real PPI-based) exchange rate volatility is above the mean, and 0 otherwise. This binary redefinition is intended to make the interpretation of the coefficients more immediate when dealing with the interaction terms of the exchange volatility indexes with time dummies, following the specification in Eq. (2). We report in columns (#a) the 5-year indicator and in columns (#b) the 1-year indicator. The interpretation of the high exchange rate volatility coefficient confirms the results of Table 2: country pairs with a high bilateral volatility of the nominal exchange rate (5-year), for instance, feature 12% lower bilateral FPE \((e^{-0.125}-1=-0.12).\)

Table 3 FPE and High exchange rate volatility (binary)

5.2 Heterogeneity over time and country-size

The trade literature has highlighted a significant heterogeneity in the impact of exchange rate volatility along several dimensions, such as size (Micco et al., 2003; Baldwin, 2006; Santos Silva & Tenreyro, 2010) and time period (De Sousa, 2012).

To check for the presence of heterogeneity in the role of exchange rate volatility also in financial markets, we start from considering the time dimension.

In columns (1a) of Table 4, we include a Period 2 dummy covering the 2008–2017 period, and its interaction with the binary exchange rate volatility, as in equation (2). Since the exchange rate volatility displays a countercyclical dynamic, as shown in Figs. 1 and 2, with a marked rise associated with the crisis period, in columns (1b), we further split the Period 2 into a crisis (2008–2012) and a post-crisis period (2013–2017).

Table 4 Heterogeneity over time

Columns (#a) show that the negative effect of exchange rate volatility on bilateral cross-border investments has dramatically decreased: column (1a), for instance, shows that the average \(-\,12\)% of Table 2 is the aggregated result of a larger negative impact in the first period (\(e^{-0.235}-1=-0.21\)) and an almost null effect in the second period (\(e^{-0.235+0.210}-1=-0.02\)). When splitting the second period into crisis and post-crisis, in columns (#b), we observe more specifically that the reduction of the exchange rate volatility effect over time is confined to the post-crisis period. Indeed, the negative impact of stock exchange volatility has almost vanished in the post-crisis period, while in the crisis period, when the exchange volatility experienced a peak, only a marginally significant and non-systematic decrease (only for the nominal exchange rate measure) is detected.

These results are consistent with the idea that the deterring role of exchange rate volatility may depend upon the importance of the associated risk for foreign investors: in periods with lower exchange rate volatility, the risk appears to be less significant, and cross-border investments are less affected by its presence.Footnote 10

As far as the cross-country heterogeneity dimension is concerned, Saiki (2005) emphasized that the negative effect of exchange rate uncertainty on trade of goods and services is less of a concern for large developed countries for several reasons, including the availability of risk hedging in the financial markets.

In order to understand the heterogeneous impact of exchange rate volatility across financial markets, we compare its effect on the sample of large and small countries.

In Table 5, we split the sample into country-pairs with a large destination economy (GDP above the median, columns (1a) to (2b)), and country pairs with a small destination economy (GDP below the median, columns (3a) to (4b)).

Table 5 Heterogeneity over country-size

We observe, first, that the effect of exchange rate volatility in the pre-crisis period is always significantly larger for countries investing in small countries: a high nominal exchange rate volatility induces a 51% lower investment in small economies, versus a 21% lower investment in large economies (similar percentages for the real exchange rate volatility). Secondly, for both groups of countries, the decrease of investment in the crisis period, when the exchange rate volatility notably surge, is not statistically different from zero. Finally, after the crises, the role of exchange rate volatility vanishes for investment in larger destination countries, while it decreases, but is still present, for investment in smaller destination economies.

These findings seem to suggest that exchange rate volatility has a more significant impact in crisis periods rather than in stable ones, and on small destination economies than on large ones.

5.3 Implications for EMU countries

The occurrence of the global financial crisis and of the immediately subsequent European sovereign debt crisis has drastically weakened reciprocal portfolio investment among EMU member countries (Giofré & Sokolenko, 2022).

The findings reported so far suggest that the global trend of the exchange rate volatility may have played a role. Indeed, on the one hand, its secular decline may have induced investors to disregard the exchange rate risk shielded in a common currency. On the other hand, Euro-area members’ economies are, on average, larger than the median country and then, accordingly to the findings above, relatively less sensitive to the exchange rate volatility issue. As a consequence, after the crisis, when the impact of exchange rate volatility on portfolio investments has globally decreased, the presence of a common currency area that eliminates this source of risk may have become less important, thus making the reciprocal investments among Euro-area members relatively less attractive.

However, we are unable to directly test the change in the impact of exchange rate volatility on FPE within the Euro area because the common currency entirely removes the exchange rate volatility. To deal with this issue, we can check if the decline in the common currency effect on cross-border investments persists, even after partialling out the dynamics of the exchange rate volatility.

Since the inception of the European Economic and Monetary Union, more than two decades ago, the effect of the common currency on cross-border investments has been very strong, with Eurozone countries disproportionately investing in their partners’ assets, both in bonds (Lane, 2006; Giofré, 2013) and in equities (Lane & Milesi-Ferretti, 2007; Balta & Delgado, 2009; Berkel, 2004; Slavov, 2009). Since 2007, however, this tendency has greatly diminished.

Amid the general downturn of international financial flows after the financial crisis (Lane, 2013; Milesi-Ferretti & Tille, 2011), bilateral cross-border portfolio equity holdings within the EMU area experienced a more abrupt and persistent fall. The recent literature has highlighted that this markedly weaker effect of the common currency on cross-border investments was mainly due to the financial crisis and the ensuing sovereign debt crisis, rather than to the enlargement of the EMU itself, although these events occurred jointly after 2007 (Giofré & Sokolenko, 2022; Giofré, 2022).

In Table 6, we add the exchange rate volatility indicator to the estimation specification adopted by Giofré & Sokolenko (2022) in order to test if and how the inclusion of this new covariate and its dynamics over time helps explain the fall in bilateral investments among Euro area countries. Columns (#a) consider the volatility indicator based on the nominal exchange rate, while columns (#b) consider the indicator based on the CPI-based real exchange rate. Columns (1a) and (1b) consider the EMU countries’ dummy, columns (2a) and (2b) consider the OLD EMU members’ dummy, columns (3a) and (3b) consider OLD EMU countries investing in EMU countries, and columns (4a) and (4b) consider EMU countries investing in OLD EMU economies.Footnote 11

Table 6 Exchange rate volatility and EMU

The first thing to be noted is that the results are very similar when considering the whole EMU area (columns (1a) and (1b)) or its sub-samples (columns (2a) to (4b)), which confirms the marginal role played in the area by the new members (Giofré & Sokolenko, 2022). After partialling out the exchange rate volatility indicator, we observe that the coefficient of the EMU dummy in the excluded period (pre-crisis) accounts for 93% higher bilateral investments; this effect drops to 61% in the crisis period and, interestingly, the drop becomes non-significant in the post-crisis period (except in column (1b), where the coefficient is however only marginally significant). The novel finding is therefore that, after accounting for the declining role of exchange rate risk hedging documented in the data, we do not observe any ‘unexplained’ significant fall in the EMU linkages after the crisis period. The global declining role of exchange rate risk hedging helps explain the persistent decline in bilateral equity investments within the Euro area after the financial crisis: the lower responsiveness of international investment to exchange rate volatility caused a decrease in significance of the full exchange risk hedging system represented by the common currency area.

Vermeulen (2013) showed a significant negative relationship between foreign equity holdings and stock market correlations during the financial crisis, while no such a relationship was detected before the crisis. Giofré (2022) focused specifically on the contraction of ‘core’ EMU countries’ investments in the Euro area, and found that lower diversification opportunities, due to the increase in stock return correlation induced by the global crisis, played a significant role in explaining the change in the investment pattern of core countries in the Euro-area since 2007.Footnote 12

Table 7 sets out the dynamics of the EMU linkages when accounting also for the bilateral stock return correlation.

Table 7 EMU, exchange rate volatility and return correlation

As a measure of return correlation, we consider, consistently with Giofré (2022), a dichotomic index, \(H\, correl_{s,h}\), equal to 1 if the correlation of the stock returns between country s and h is larger than the mean, and 0 otherwise. The stock return correlation is computed as the bilateral correlation of monthly returns in the previous year.

The results in regard to the declining role of exchange rate volatility after the crisis are confirmed, and so too are the results in regard to the stronger (negative) role of returns correlation found by Giofré (2022): the fall in the EMU linkages can be successfully explained by the forces driving these two factors.Footnote 13

To sum up, the drop in bilateral EMU investment during the crisis period cannot be explained by exchange rate volatility because of its countercyclical nature; rather, it is explained by the decline in economic development and, more importantly, by deterioration of the control of corruption standards of Euro periphery countries (Giofré & Sokolenko, 2022). However, our findings suggest that, in the post-crisis period, when the countercyclical spikes of exchange rate volatility were absorbed, the persistent drop in bilateral portfolio investments in the Euro area has instead been driven by a weaker (negative) response to exchange rate volatility, besides a stronger (negative) response to diversification benefits (Giofré, 2022). In fact, after accounting for these dynamics, the evidence of a distinctive fall in bilateral foreign investments among Euro members in the post-crisis period disappears.

6 Conclusions

In this paper we have tested the conjecture that the generalized decline in exchange rate volatility, probably correlated with a lower perceived currency risk, is paired with a decreased need for risk exchange hedging among foreign portfolio equity investors. We have found that the significant negative association between bilateral foreign portfolio investments and the volatility of the exchange rate has significantly weakened worldwide since 2012, especially for large economies.

We have discussed the implications of these results for the reciprocal investments among Euro-area members. Giofré and Sokolenko (2022) highlighted that the crisis drastically weakened the financial linkages among original members after 2007. The decline in economic development and the deterioration of the control of corruption standards of Euro periphery countries were found to be the drivers of the fall in the crisis period. This paper helps explain the persistent reduction of reciprocal EMU investment even in the post-crisis period. The weaker response of portfolio investments to a declining exchange rate risk, combined with the diversification motive, can account for the lower bilateral investments after the crisis.

In particular, the generalized reduction in the perceived exchange rate risk, as a consequence of the global decline of exchange rate volatility, raises a fatal challenge to the relevance of the common currency area and hence to the attractiveness of reciprocal investments by member countries.