Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 200, October 2022, 107509
Ecological Economics

Do social norms trump rational choice in voluntary climate change mitigation? Multi-country evidence of social tipping points

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2022.107509Get rights and content

Abstract

The rational choice model of voluntary public good provision predicts that an individual's contribution to climate change mitigation responds negatively to larger contributions by others whereas social norm theory maintains that one's own contribution is positively related to that of others. This paper tests the competing hypotheses empirically using representative data for about 30,000 individuals from 23 European countries. The paper finds that, up to a threshold percentage of others perceived to engage in mitigation, individuals' willingness to engage in mitigation themselves is lower the more other individuals are perceived to engage in such behavior, whereas the relationship is positive when the threshold is passed. Since the actual percentage of others perceived to engage in mitigation is lower than the estimated threshold (30 to 56%) in a number of countries, marginal increases in the percentage of others perceived to behave in a climate-friendly way may backfire by enhancing free-rider behavior. For the social norm to take grip, policy-induced non-marginal increases of perceptions may be required to shift the system past the tipping point.

Introduction

The past three decades have seen a departure from the standard rational choice model of pro-social and pro-environmental behavior. While the rational choice model is of a consequentialist nature, assuming that people do what yields the individually optimal (expected) outcome, alternative approaches are deontological, maintaining that individuals evaluate behaviors per se and choose among them based on conformity with moral norms – inner feelings of what is right or wrong – and social norms – what most people do (descriptive social norms) or approve of doing (injunctive social norms).1

Conformity to moral and social norms is generally understood as a mechanism that enhances the voluntary provision of public goods by countervailing the free-rider incentives highlighted by rational choice theory (e.g., Nyborg, 2018). With respect to voluntary public good provision there is, however, an important difference between moral-norm and injunctive-social- norm accounts of behavior, on the one hand, and descriptive-social-norm accounts, on the other. While the former are logically independent of rational choice theory, descriptive-social-norm accounts are logically opposed to rational choice theory, that is, the two make opposite behavioral predictions: While rational choice theory predicts that an individual's contribution to the public good responds negatively to others' contributions (e.g., Buchholz and Sandler, 2021), conformity to a descriptive social norm – what most others do – implies that an individual's contribution is positively related to the contributions provided by others.

Focusing on climate change mitigation, this paper tests the competing predictions empirically, using representative survey data for about 30,000 individuals from 23 European countries. Specifically, based on the idea of social tipping points (see below), the hypothesis will be explored that there are threshold levels of others' behavior that need to be passed for the descriptive social norm mechanism to dominate the rational choice mechanism.

The literature on the behavioral theory and empirical evidence on social norms as applied to pro-environmental behavior is concisely reviewed by Farrow et al. (2017). The review identified 42 studies, of which 11 referred to energy use, 11 referred to recycling, and 20 referred to green consumption, littering, water conservation, hotel guests' towel reuse, and pesticide use. These studies covered both behaviors and behavior intentions and involved descriptive and injunctive norms. The behaviors studied were found to be significantly positively related to descriptive norms (others' actual or perceived pro-environmental behaviors) in 31 out of 39 studies. An early example where clues about others' behavior prompted pro-environmental behavior change refers to the reuse of bath towels in hotels (Schultz et al., 2008). A more recent study (Falk et al., 2021) found that individuals' donations to curtail climate change were significantly positively related to the percentage of people they believed to engage in climate change curtailment. Farrow et al. (2017) take such findings to suggest that people take information or beliefs about what others do (descriptive norms) as a signal of which behaviors are socially approved and which are not (injunctive norms).

While the evidence found in this literature is often context-specific and local in nature, Nyborg et al. (2016) note that recent history has seen large-scale changes of norms and behaviors, for instance with respect to fertility behavior or the cessation of smoking in public places. However, for such changes to be self-reinforcing, they argue, it is necessary that social tipping points are passed, that is, for social conformity to induce behavior changes a sufficiently large number of people must already have changed their behavior so that a “new” social norm emerges. Below such thresholds, social conformity implies vicious rather than virtuous circles.

Though fertility and smoking behaviors do not necessarily or to a large extent refer to public goods, the notion of threshold values or tipping points may be even more relevant when public goods are involved. In such cases “new” norms of behavior (e.g., environment-friendliness) do not only compete with “old” ones (e.g., “keeping up with the Joneses”) but with incentives to free-ride on others' contributions to the public good. This makes it likely that public good provision by others may not only be ineffective in triggering an individual to behave similarly, but counter-productive unless a tipping point is passed where the “virtuous” conformity mechanism starts to dominate rational-choice free-rider considerations.

While the rational-choice/free-rider model is the standard framework that predicts a negative relationship between own mitigation behavior and that of others, non-standard mechanisms have been proposed that lead to the same prediction. One is so-called moral licensing. This involves the idea that people's sense of duty to contribute to a public good is inversely related to the level of the public good: When morally motivated people learn that the level of a public good increases, due to larger contributions by others, their sense of duty and the corresponding contribution may diminish, possibly in favor of other collective goals/goods (Mullen and Monin, 2016; Lasarov et al., 2022). The notion of moral licensing combines consequentialist (outcome-focused) and deontological aspects since the (collective) outcome of behaviors (or perception of outcome) influences an individual's behavior (as in the rational choice framework) even though the behavior's motivation may be of a deontological nature.2

Another mechanism that implies a negative relationship between own and others' behavior involves social distinction: Low overall levels of a desirable behavior may raise the adoption of this behavior through motivations to seek distinction (e.g., Bénabou and Tirole (2006). If, conversely, the overall level of the behavior increases (from a low level), the behavior becomes less attractive as a vehicle for attaining distinction and may thus be reduced. Consistent with a distinction as well as a moral licensing account it was found that informing people about the energy consumption of their neighbors had a boomerang effect for some individuals who learned that they outperformed the average (Allcott and Rogers, 2014; Schultz et al., 2007).

Focusing on climate change mitigation – by means of buying the most energy efficient home appliances – this paper contributes to the literature by studying the potentially opposing effects of others' behavior in a large-scale multi-country representative sample, the European Social Survey. Controlling for variables that capture the activation of a moral norm of climate change mitigation, income, and a battery of sociodemographic correlates, the paper finds that, up to a threshold level of others perceived to engage in mitigation, individuals' willingness to engage in mitigation themselves is lower the more other individuals are perceived to engage in such behavior, whereas the relationship is positive when the threshold (tipping point) is passed. The u-shaped relationship between own and others' perceived behavior is found to exist both in the overall sample and in the majority of individual countries as well as in all subgroups of the population (by age, gender, level of education, ideological position, and sense of moral duty). It is robust to including close to a dozen additional covariates that may determine both individuals' own behavior intentions and their beliefs about what others intend to do.

Since the percentage of others perceived to engage in mitigation is lower than the estimated threshold (30 to 56%) in a number of (but not all) countries, marginal increases in the percentage of others perceived to behave in a climate-friendly way may backfire by enhancing free-rider (or moral-licensing) behavior. For the social norm to take grip, policy-induced non-marginal increases may be required in such cases. If the actual level of the relevant behavior is sufficiently large relative to the perceived level, informing people about the actual level may trigger an increase in the behavior studied.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 lays out the conceptual framework and empirical approach and describes the data and variables used. Section 3 reports the results. Section 4 addresses issues of identification. Section 5 provides a general discussion, and Section 6 concludes.

Section snippets

Theoretical framework

We start by sketching a stylized analytical framework for climate change mitigation which adds moral and social norms to the standard model of voluntary public good provision.

The standard public good model consists of a utility function, an aggregator function and a budget constraint (e.g. Buchholz and Sandler, 2021). Individual i's strictly quasi-concave utility function Ui(G, xi) has two arguments, the overall level of the public good, G, and individual i's consumption of a private numeraire

Basic regression results

Table 2 reports OLS regression results for eq. (2), using Willingness to Contribute as the dependent variable. Column 1 shows that the variable Others' Perceived Contribution attracts a significantly negative coefficient, whereas, as expected, the two moral-norm variables (Sense of Consequence and Sense of Responsibility) attract significantly positive coefficients. Income, age, being female, the level of education, and whether children live in the household attract significantly positive

The nature of the evidence

Using representative data for >30,000 individuals, the empirical analysis up to this point has established a u-shaped relationship between people's propensity to buy the most energy efficient home appliances and their perceptions as to how many people limit their energy use to try to reduce climate change. The u-shaped relationship is robust across countries and subgroups of the population. This section discusses the nature of the evidence with respect to the interpretation of the variables

Interpretation and comparison with the literature

A considerable number of studies have found that people's pro-environmental behaviors are positively related to their perceptions of what other people do (Farrow et al., 2017). The results of the present paper imply a qualification to these findings as they suggest that for a positive relationship between own behavior and the perceived behavior of others to exist, a threshold level of the latter has to be passed. Below the threshold, the relationship is negative rather than positive.

While

Conclusion

Pro-environmental social norms have become a topical issue in environmental studies in recent years. As suggested by social-norm theory, information or perceptions that others behave in more pro-environmental ways (descriptive social norms) may prompt individuals to behave accordingly, due to a desire for social conformity. This proposition found considerable, but not universal, empirical support. It stands, however, in stark contrast to the standard rational-choice model of voluntary public

Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Acknowledgement

I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for insightful and constructive comments.

References (42)

  • J.C. Price et al.

    Predicting pro-environmental agricultural practices: the social, psychological and contextual influences on land management

    J. Rural. Stud.

    (2014)
  • J.D.M. Saphores et al.

    Willingness to engage in a pro-environmental behavior: an analysis of e-waste recycling based on a national survey of US households

    Resour. Conserv. Recycl.

    (2012)
  • E. Van Der Werff et al.

    One model to predict them all: predicting energy behaviours with the norm activation model

    Energy Res. Soc. Sci.

    (2015)
  • J.J. Vaske et al.

    Carbon footprint mitigation on vacation: a norm activation model

    J. Outdoor Recreat. Tour.

    (2015)
  • H. Welsch

    Moral foundations and voluntary public good provision: the case of climate change

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2020)
  • H. Welsch

    How climate-friendly behavior relates to moral identity and identity-protective cognition: evidence from the European social surveys

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2021)
  • H. Allcott et al.

    The short-run and long-run effects of behavioral interventions: experimental evidence from energy conservation

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2014)
  • M. Andor et al.

    Consumer inattention, heuristic thinking and the role of energy labels

    Energy J.

    (2020)
  • J. Andreoni

    Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving

    Econ. J.

    (1990)
  • R. Bénabou et al.

    Incentives and prosocial behavior

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2006)
  • R. Bénabou et al.

    Identity, morals and taboos: beliefs as assets

    Q. J. Econ.

    (2011)
  • Cited by (7)

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text