Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Domestic interest rate, foreign direct investment, and corruption

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It has been argued that foreign direct investment can exert upward or downward pressure on the domestic interest rate depending on foreign investors’ relative weights on internal and external finance with respect to the domestic economy. Additionally, a country’s level of corruption can influence firms’ ability to obtain external finance. We find that across countries a 1 percent increase in FDI inflows (outflows) is more likely to reduce the domestic interest rate by as much as 0.7 (1) percent. This empirical association between domestic interest rates and FDI flows is non-monotonically contingent on a country’s level of corruption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for e.g., Calvo et al. (1996), Sun (2002), Agosin and Machado (2005), Magud et al. (2014), Harrison and McMillan (2003), Harrison et al. (2004).

  2. Using data from over 135,000 manufacturing firms in 135 countries from 2005 to 2014, the Enterprise Surveys record different qualifiers that signal foreign firms and banks in host countries do engage in credit-based interactions. For example, of all foreign firms surveyed, an average of approximately 90 percent have a checking or savings accounts, 35 percent have a bank loan or line of credit, 25 percent use banks to finance investments, and 29 percent use banks to finance working capital. These averages are from the authors’ computations.

  3. Different international organizations have conducted surveys to assess the factors that impinge on investors’ decision to undertake business in their respective host countries. A country’s level of institutional uncertainty is the common denominator across the principal subsets of factors identified by these surveys. For example, in 1996, a World Bank survey of 3685 firms in 69 countries reveals that (of 15 obstacles) corruption ranks as the second most important obstacle to business worldwide (Brunetti et al. 1997, p. 59). In 2007, the Worldwide Survey of Foreign Affiliates, conducted jointly by UNCTAD and the World Association of Investment Promotion Agencies, involving 96 chief executive officers of foreign affiliates around the world were asked to indicate the policy area that governments should improve upon to render their locations more attractive to FDI; the most important policy area was the regulatory and institutional environment—which includes curbing corruption (UNCTAD 2007).

  4. In welfare economics, a first-best equilibrium is a competitive market equilibrium free from market distortions, whereas a second-best equilibrium is the market equilibrium when distortions are present. The traditional view of universal benefit of a reduction in corruption is a first-best view because this perspective fails to account for many market imperfections or distortions that are present across countries. Taking these distortions into account requires one to recognize that under certain circumstances corruption need not have a monotonic effect on the FDI-interest rate relationship. A second-best view recognizes that reductions in corruption need not be optimal in light of other market frictions.

  5. Detailed summaries of the FDI-corruption literature with evidences of nonmonotonic interactions are included in Cuervo-Cazurra (2008), Brada et al. (2012), and Brada et al. (2017), and the references cited therein.

  6. Given the structure of Eq. (2.1), readers should note that \(\gamma _j(Z_{it}) : \mathbb {R}^p \rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) for \(j=0,1,2,3\) but \(\gamma _j(Z_{it}) : \mathbb {R}^p \rightarrow \mathbb {R}^l\) for \(j=4\).

  7. The wild bootstrap that we use to estimate the standard errors mitigates, among other things, imprecision of the estimates that may arise as a result of estimation using a small sample.

  8. Note that many of these explanatory variables have been linked theoretically to FDI flows (see, for example, Calvo et al. 1996), and some variables such as domestic investment and economic growth, have been found to be correlated empirically with FDI flows across countries; thus, these explanatory variables should mitigate omitted variable bias in the estimated effects of FDI on the lending rate.

  9. The first year that this corruption index is available is 1984; hence, the availability of the corruption index places a restriction on the beginning year of our analysis.

  10. It has been documented (e.g.,World Bank 1997a, b; UNCTAD 2000) that governments may try to attract FDI by offering tax credits, infrastructure subsidies and import duty exemptions to foreign investors.

  11. Using only discrete variables in Z reduces our local-linear least squares smooth coefficient estimator to a local-constant least squares smooth coefficient estimator. We refer to Li and Racine (2007) for technical details.

  12. We highlight the stability of the dynamic specifications in both Tables 2 and 3, which can be deduced from the magnitude and statistical significance of the reported percentiles for the one-period lagged interest rate regressor.

  13. The thirteen countries are Albania, Angola, Azerbaijan, Bahrain, Bolivia, Cameroon, Kenya, Kuwait, Latvia, Libya, Malawi, Mexico and Poland.

  14. This graph can be retrieved from the appendix.

  15. A careful analysis of the relationship between FDI inflows coefficient estimates and partial effects reveals no dependence between the type and magnitude of the FDI inflows coefficient estimates and those of their partial effects.

  16. A careful analysis of the relationship between FDI outflows coefficient estimate and partial effects shows no general association between the type and size of the FDI outflows coefficient estimates and those of their partial effects.

  17. This joint kernel density can be retrieved from the appendix.

  18. The kernel densities coupled with the density equality test of Li et al. (2009), as well as significance plots, for these coefficients all reveal that the densities of estimated coefficients for these explanatory variables are statistically different from their counterparts in Table 3.

  19. For the intial-valued regressions our primary results remain largely unchanged, indicating that our main results are not driven by substantial biases.

  20. We construct exchange rate volatility following (Clark et al. 2004) as the standard deviation of the first difference of the logarithm of the bilateral real exchange rate in the five preceding years; this variable is from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics. The additional TI and WGI regressions have smaller sample sizes relative to our main model due to their initial coverage years.

  21. We also consider different measures of institutional uncertainty from the ICRG index; specifically, we replace corruption in our main model (one at a time) with Investment Profile, Law and Order, Democratic Accountability, and Bureaucracy Quality. Though there are some differences in these heterogeneous estimates, the overall qualitative features of these distributions are remarkably similar across measures of institutions. Our general conclusion of non-monotonic effects of corruption carry over into other measures of institutional quality.

  22. These are widely used proxies for financial and economic development in the empirical literature; moreover, in pooled data of developed and developing countries, such as our data, a strong correlation between corruption and each of these proxies is an empirical regularity.

  23. This seemingly ad-hoc choice set is driven by data paucity. However, the interest rates that we do not control for are highly correlated with those in this set.

  24. In China, Héricourt and Poncet (2009) show that joint ventures between foreign and private domestic firms is a source of finance for the latter in the presence of legal and financial domestic obstacles.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of Economic Growth, 1A, 385–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agosin, M. R., & Machado, R. (2005). Foreign investment in developing countries: Does it crowd in domestic investment? Oxford Development Studies, 33, 149–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, F., Atkeson, A., & Kehoe, P. J. (2002). Money, interest rates, and exchange rates with endogenously segmented markets. Journal of Political Economy, 110(1), 73–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arbatli, E. (2011). Economic politics and FDI inflows to emerging market economies. IMF Working Paper No. 192.

  • Barbieri, K. & Keshk, O. (2012). Correlates of war project trade data set codebook, Version 3.0’. Online: http://correlatesofwar.org.

  • Barth, J. R., Lin, C., Lin, P., & Song, F. M. (2009). Corruption in bank lending to firms: Cross-country micro evidence on the beneficial role of competition and information sharing. Journal of Financial Economics, 91(3), 361–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2006). Bank supervision and corruption in lending. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53, 2131–2163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (2005). Financial and legal constraints to growth: Does firm size matter? Journal of Finance, 60(1), 137–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Laeven, L., & Maksimovic, V. (2006). The determinants of financing obstacles. Journal of International Money and Finance, 25, 932–952.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, J. H. & Champ, B. (2003). Inflation and financial market performance: What have we learned in the last ten years? Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, working paper no. 03-17.

  • Brada, J. C., Drabek, Z., Mendez, J. A. & Perez, M. F. (2017). A model of corruption and foreign direct investment a la John Dunning. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2938370 (March 21, 2017).

  • Brada, J. C., Drabek, Z., & Perez, M. F. (2012). The effect of home-country and host-country corruption on foreign direct investment. Review of Development Economics, 16(4), 640–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunetti, A., Kisunko, G. & Weder, B. ( 1997). Institutional obstacles to doing business: Region-by-region results from a worldwide survey of the private sector. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 1759, Washington, D.C.

  • Cai, Z., & Li, Q. (2008). Nonparametric estimation of varying coefficient dynamic panel data models. Econometric Theory, 24, 1321–1342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G. A., Leiderman, L., & Reinhart, C. M. (1996). Inflows of capital to developing countries in the 1990s. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, 123–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chinn, M. & Frankel, J. (2007). Debt and interest rates: The U.S. and Euro area. Economics Discussion Paper 2007–11, Kiel Institute for the World Economy.

  • Clark, P., Tamirisa, N., Wei, S.-J., Sadikov, A. & Zeng, L. (2004). Exchange rate volatility and trade flows—some new evidence. IMF discussion paper.

  • Coibion, O., & Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012). Why are target interest rate changes so persistent? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(4), 126–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2008). Better the devil you don’t know: Types of corruption and FDI in transition economies. Journal of International Management, 14(1), 12–27.

  • Davidson, R., & Flachaire, E. (2008). The wild bootstrap, tamed at last. Journal of Econometrics, 146(1), 162–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haas, R., Ferreira, D., & Taci, A. (2010). What determines the composition of banks’ loan portfolios? Evidence from transition countries. Journal of Banking and Finance, 34, 388–398.

  • Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Laeven, L., & Levine, R. (2004). Regulations, market structure, institutions, and the cost of financial intermediation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36(3), 593–622.

  • Desai, M. A., Foley, C. F., & Hines, J. R. (2009). Domestic effects of the foreign activities of US multinationals. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1, 181–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Shleifer, A. (2007). Private credit in 129 countries. Journal of Financial Economics, 12(2), 77–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engen, E. M., & Hubbard, R. G. (2005). Federal government debt and interest rates. In M. Gertler & K. Rogoff (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004, Volume 19 (pp. 83–160). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enterprise Surveys (2014). The World Bank http://www.enterprisesurveys.org.

  • Frankel, J. A., Okita, S., Peterson, P. G., & Schlesinger, J. R. (1988). International capital flows and domestic economic policies. In: M. Feldstein (Ed.), The United States in the World Economy, (pp. 559–658). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Frankel, J. A., & Roubini, N. (2003). The role of industrial country policies in emerging market crises. In M. Feldstein (Ed.), Economic and financial crises in emerging market economies (pp. 155–278). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gale, W. G., & Orszag, P. R. (2004). Budget deficits, national saving, and interest rates. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 101–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, A. E., Love, I., & McMillan, M. S. (2004). Global capital flows and financing constraints. Journal of Development Economics, 75, 269–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, A. E., & McMillan, M. S. (2003). Does direct foreign investment affect domestic credit constraints? Journal of International Economics, 61, 73–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Héricourt, J., & Poncet, S. (2009). FDI and credit constraints: Firm-level evidence from China. Economic Systems, 33, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinoshita, N. (2006). Government debt and long-term interest rates. IMF Working Paper No. 63.

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Q., Maasoumi, E., & Racine, J. S. (2009). A nonparametric tets for equality of distributions with mixed categorical and continuous data. Journal of Econometrics, 148, 186–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Q., & Racine, J. S. (2007). Nonparametric Econometrics: Theory and Practice. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, K. (1956). The general theory of second best. Review of Economic Studies, 24, 11–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magud, N. E., Reinhart, C. M., & Vesperoni, E. R. (2014). Capital inflows, exchange rate flexibility and credit booms. Review of Development Economics, 18, 415–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paesani, P., Strauch, R. and Kremer, M. (2006). Public debt and long-term interest rates: The case of Germany, Italy and the USA’, European Central Bank Working Paper.

  • Qian, J., & Strahan, P. E. (2007). How laws and institutions shape financial contracts: The case of bank loans. Journal of Finance, 62, 2803–2834.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2008). Second-best institutions. American Economic Review, Papers & Proceedings, 98, 100–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, X. (2002). Foreign direct investment and economic development: What do the states need to do?. Foreign Investment Advisory Service.

  • UNCTAD (2000). Tax incentives and foreign direct investment: A global survey, Technical Report 16, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, United Nations, Geneva.

  • UNCTAD (2007). Worldwide survey of foreign affiliates: Occasional note’, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, United Nations, Geneva.

  • World Bank. (1997a). ‘Global development finance 1997’. Washington D.C.

  • World Bank. (1997b). ‘Private capital flows to developing countries: The road to financial integration’. Washington D.C.

  • World Bank. (2002). World Development Report 2002: Building institutions for markets. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • World Bank. (2012). World Development Indicators [CD-ROM]. Washington D.C.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael S. Delgado.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

McCloud, N., Delgado, M.S. Domestic interest rate, foreign direct investment, and corruption. Rev World Econ 158, 467–491 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-021-00435-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-021-00435-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation