Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Energy Res., 15 September 2021
Sec. Sustainable Energy Systems
Volume 9 - 2021 | https://doi.org/10.3389/fenrg.2021.628206

Efficiency Power Plant Implementation Decision-Making Based on the Profit Function and Its Numerical Simulation

www.frontiersin.orgYiping Zhu* www.frontiersin.orgYue Jin
  • School of Management, Nanchang University, Nanchang, China

The efficiency power plant (EPP) is a kind of virtual power plant with zero emission, zero pollution, and low cost and exhibits a high-quality low-carbon production behavior in input-output analysis. In the process of implementing EPP, enterprises not only save electricity but also reduce carbon emissions, while increasing the cost of R&D and equipment. Therefore, it is very necessary to study relationships between carbon quota and EPP implementation decision. In this paper, we build the profit functions of three different types of enterprises implementing EPP and analyze the relationship of main parameters, such as the probability of implementing EPP, electricity saving, income, cost, and carbon quota, and obtain nine relative results. Then, we use ‘Maple’ software to simulate the results by drawing images of parameters, and all the above nine results passed the simulation test verification. At last, we collect the actual survey data and use VC++ programming to carry out an empirical study in China to prove the practicability of the model and the results. The results show that, under the carbon quota trading system, enterprises should tend to implement EPPs and increase investment in R&D and acquisition of EPPs and are needed to adjust the intensity of implementing EPPs according to the change of carbon quota and unit carbon quota income, to obtain higher income.

Introduction

Background

Electricity demand side management (DSM) is to let enterprises and users manage their own enterprise electricity situation through the construction of electricity fine management platform. Efficiency power plant (EPP) is a representative DSM energy efficiency resource project. EPP can be considered as a collection of some DSM energy efficiency resource projects with better combination. EPPs use high-efficiency electrical equipment and products, based on the energy-saving transformation plan of an industry or a regional enterprise, to form a regional electricity utilization efficiency optimization in different ways, which has the same important significance with the construction of a new power plant.

Over the past 10 years, the development of DSM has achieved abundant energy conservation and emission reduction effects and formed a certain scale. For example, the State Grid Energy Research Institute of China counts that the generation capacity of the DSM project is 640.7 billion kWh in China from 2011 to 2015 and estimates that the same in 2016–2020 is 1.3254 trillion kWh. It can reach 1.9661 trillion kWh during the period of 2010–2020, equivalent to a reduction of 22,598 kWh in generation capacity, and nearly 57 billion USD in investment compared with the conventional power plants (Energy Research Institute of State Grid of China, 2010).

The China government has introduced a carbon quota management system (Chang et al., 2020), which has a significant impact on the implementation of EPP. Under the carbon quota system, enterprises must control the greenhouse gas emissions, mainly carbon dioxide (CO2). The implementation of EPP cannot only reduce power consumption but also reduce carbon emissions, which, to some extent improves the willingness of enterprises to implement EPP (Li et al., 2016). Moreover, as the EPP grew in size, massive fiscal and tax subsidies became unsustainable, and carbon quotas became the government’s main means of controlling carbon emissions.

In this paper, on the basis of predecessors’ research summarized, we further combine government carbon quota with EPP, through the establishment of EPP implementation decision model based on the profit function, analyze the decisions of enterprises under different carbon quota, and verify the correctness and rationality of the results through system simulation. We hope this article could provide a reference for enterprises to make correct decisions under different carbon quota and different technology maturity when implementing EPPs.

Literature Review

EPP and DSM are hot topics in energy management, as they grew in size; they encountered economic, technological, and managerial problems in the development process (Haydt et al., 2014). Thus, most scholars prefer to focus on the three aspects of EPPs, such as in the economic field, such as billing (Çakmak and Altaş, 2020), pricing (Venizelou et al., 2020), and cost-benefit analysis (Wang and Zhu, 2014); in the field of mathematics, such as scheduling (Chamandoust et al., 2020) and planning (Zhu et al., 2017) and energy efficiency (Wang et al., 2015; Wang et al., 2016; Chakraborty et al., 2020); and in the field of technology, such as renewable energy (Kalair et al., 2020), smart distribution system (Reddy et al., 2020), and others (Mendes et al., 2020).

Among the field of energy management, the game analysis of low-carbon investment behavior is meaningful and necessary. Rai and Beck (2017) stated the importance of using behavioral science to address the persistent gaps between the technical potential of low-carbon technologies and the actual adoption of these technologies. The game analysis in low-carbon environment is derived from the low-carbon supply chain research. Du et al. (2015) conducted a game-theoretical analysis and gave low-carbon supply policies for supply chain management (Du et al., 2017). Chen et al. (2014) investigated a practical demand side management scenario where the selfish consumers compete to minimize their individual energy cost through scheduling their future energy consumption profiles using an aggregative game approach. Li et al. (2017) examined the influences of different game structures on the optimal decisions and performance of a low-carbon closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) with price and carbon emission level-dependent market demands. Then, the scholars put forward the game behavior of each participant in low-carbon investment. Du et al. (2013) considered the emission cap of emission-dependent manufacturer allocated by the government as a kind of environmental policy and formally investigated its influence on decision-making within the concerned emission-dependent supply chain and distribution fairness in social welfare. Luo et al. (2016) derived the optimal solutions for the two manufacturers in the purely competitive and co-opetitive market environments, respectively. Based on non-cooperative and cooperative games, Huang et al. (2018) proposed a hierarchical game playing scheme and a simplified multienergy system optimization method to assist stakeholders to participate in technoeconomic analysis process. Sun et al. (2020) constructed a Stackelberg differential game model (dominated by manufacturers) under both centralized and decentralized decisions considering the lag time of emission reduction technologies and the low-carbon preferences of consumers. Zhu et al. (2018) investigated how to optimize the strategy of low carbon investment for suppliers and manufacturers in supply chains and discussed the impacts of various factors on evolutionarily stable strategies. Arai et al. (2014) proposed a comprehensive framework for evaluating the performance of demand-side actors in a demand-side management system using each control scheme according to both communication availability and sampling frequency. Liu et al. (2017) proposed a scenario for DSM programs to schedule household energy consumption considering bidirectional energy trading of PEVs by a Bayesian game approach. Mahmoudi et al. (2019) evaluated the performance of Iranian thermal power plants combined with multivariate data analysis techniques, game theory, Shannon entropy, and the technique for the order of preference by similarity with ideal solution. Dou, 2015, established a dispatching optimization model of regional integrated power and gas energy system and analyzed the node energy price through the node energy balance equation and a demand response model based on evolutionary game.

Implementing EPP is a special low-carbon behavior, which can not only reduce carbon emission but also reduce electricity consumption. Therefore, the decision analysis of EPP needs to consider both low carbon and power-saving benefits. The author puts forward EPP implementation by government and enterprise, but it is far from enough (Zhu et al., 2019). Research on decision analysis among EPP enterprises is likewise important, but unfortunately, there is a lack of research on this aspect, especially about the EPP implementation decision with carbon quotas and carbon reduction benefits. Above all, the literature that analyzes the decision analysis among EPP enterprises urgently needs to be supplemented. Therefore, this study of relationship analysis for EPP implementation decision and carbon quota is innovative and of practical value.

Theoretical Basis

Efficiency Power Plant

EPP is a packaged set of DSM items or collections. The brief summary is EPPs realize energy saving transformation of energy-consuming equipment, and the energy saved is equivalent to the electricity generated by conventional coal-fired power plants (Zhu et al., 2017). Compared with conventional power plants, which are power plant entities, EPPs are designed to save electricity, not produce electricity, and save as much electricity as they produce. Although an EPP is not a real power plant, compared with power generation resources, it has the same importance in the optimal allocation of regional power supply and demand resources. It is an effective and convenient way to realize energy conservation and emission reduction and control power consumption (Maria et al., 2020). EPPs have many advantages, such as zero emission, zero pollution, low cost, non-land occupation construction cost, and operation benefit. Based on these advantages, EPPs can be used to optimize regional power resource allocation and improve the reliability and stability of the power system.

Table 1 compares fuel consumption, pollution emissions, and cost comparisons, and the comparison is about producing (or saving) per 1 kWh electricity between conventional power plants and energy-efficient power plants (source: Castro et al., 2020). The conventional power plant in the table takes a typical coal-fired power plant with an installed capacity of 300,000 kW as an example, and the annual utilization hours of its power generation equipment are about 5000 h.

TABLE 1
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 1. Comparison of conventional power plants and efficiency power plants.

Carbon Quota

Carbon quota refers to the greenhouse gas emission reduction targets that must be completed according to the regulations. For an EPP, it refers to the carbon dioxide emission reduction during the implementation of EPP. Many scholars have conducted research studies on carbon quota, but they almost took carbon quota as a constraint condition, and few literature studies have studied it as an endogenous variable. Carbon cap-and-trade was first proposed by J.H.Dales in his book “Pollution, Property and Price” (Dales, 1968), which pointed out that the government could consider pollution as a transfer of the right through the process of mutual trading of emission rights by enterprises and the regulation of the market, so as to improve the efficiency of energy use. At present, the carbon quota trading system is a relatively effective incentive means in the market, which can urge enterprises to take emission reduction measures. There are three typical distribution methods: free distribution, priced sale, and full market (Chen, 2003). There are mainly four typical carbon emission trading systems in the world (Zhang et al., 2014), namely, the European Union Carbon Emission Trading System (EUETS), the United States Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI), Australia’s New South Wales Greenhouse Gas Emission Reduction System (NSWGGAS), and Japan’s Tokyo Carbon Emissions Trading System (Tokyo ETS).

Methodology

The Behavior of Implementing Efficiency Power Plant

In China, the initial government subsidies are one of the impetuses of the enterprises implementing EPPs. With the increase of the size of the EPP, government financial subsidies began to gradually withdraw from the market, and carbon quota, as another kind of subsidies for the development of enterprises, began to appear. The government sets different carbon quota levels according to the ability of different enterprises to implement EPP, thus encouraging the development of EPP. The government stipulates a certain amount of carbon quota at the initial stage of the enterprise. With the implementation of the EPP, the government will subsidize a certain amount of carbon quota for unit reduction of electricity consumption. When not implementing the EPP, a certain amount of carbon quota will be consumed in normal enterprise production. At the end of each year, the total amount of carbon quota of the enterprise is accounted. The excess carbon quota can be exported by the enterprise to obtain funds. If the excess carbon quota is less than zero, the enterprise needs to buy excess carbon quota, or it will have to pay high compensation to the government.

This paper takes the government carbon quota level as an endogenous variable and studies how enterprises should formulate EPP implementation decision with the change of carbon quota level to ensure the maximization of their own income.

1) For enterprises that choose to implement EPP, we analyze the carbon quota level that enterprises will reach the critical value of R&D investment, and with the constant change of the carbon quota level, we research how the electricity reduced and the income obtained by implementing EPP will change with the change of carbon quota. 2) For enterprises that do not choose to implement EPP, we study the carbon quota level that enterprises will start to tend to implement EPP and research what extent will they continue to ignore EPP. 3) For enterprises that are uncertain whether to implement EPP or not, we study how should they make EPP decision with the change of carbon quota, that is, determine the tendency (probability) of implementing EPP, so as to maximize their own income, and research the change trend of enterprise output and income with the change of carbon quota.

Assumptions

1) Subject

There are three different types of enterprises, namely, enterprise E1 which always implements EPP, enterprise E2 which never implements EPP, and enterprise E3 which implements EPP as the case may be.

2) Electricity saved or consumed (unit: kWh, MWh, and GWh)

Set the electricity saved in enterprise E1 as Q1; enterprise E2 does not save electricity, but consumes electricity, so the electricity consumed by enterprise E2 can be set as Q2; when EPP is implemented for enterprise E3, electric energy is saved; when EPP is not implemented, electric energy is consumed, so set the electricity saved by enterprise E3 at last as Q3.

In addition, we can set the probability, tendency, or strength λ(0<λ<1) of enterprise E3 to implement EPP, and then, the probability of not implementing EPP is 1λ.

3) Price (this is the price at which EPP saves electricity, not the market price)

In fact, the electricity reduced by implementing EPP has exactly the same function as the electricity generated by the power plant, and the products can be completely replaced. But unlike electricity prices, which are controlled by the government, we assume that the price of electricity reduced by EPP is affected by market supply and demand, and its price can be expressed as P. P=αbQ, where α is the market acceptable price caps and b is the market demand-back coefficient. The larger the demand-back coefficient is, the smaller the market is.

4) Cost

It is assumed that the cost of EPP implementation is mainly divided into two parts: R&D cost and operation cost. R&D cost includes the costs of key processes, technologies, and equipment of EPP, expressed as C1; operating costs include energy-efficient processes and equipment produced or purchased for EPP implementation, as well as personnel inputs, etc., expressed as C2. For enterprise E1 and E3, the unit R&D cost and unit operation cost decrease with the increase of power saving. For enterprise E2, this kind of enterprise has no R&D cost but only has operation cost.

4) Carbon quotas

It mainly refers to the carbon emission quota determined by the government according to the situation of enterprises. Assume that the carbon quota stipulated by the government for each enterprise is H. The government will subsidize the carbon quota of h for every 1 kWh of electric quantity reduced by EPP. The government will deduct the carbon quota of h for every 1 kWh of electric quantity consumed by the enterprise without EPP. The carbon quota can be sold or purchased, and the economic benefit of carbon quota of h unit is d.

The main parameters and implications of the above assumptions can be represented in Table 2, and the revenue, costs, and variable returns of three different kinds of enterprises implementing EPP are presented in Figure 1.

TABLE 2
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 2. Variables and meanings in the assumptions.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 1. The revenue, costs, and variable returns of three different kinds of enterprises implementing EPP.

Building the Profit Functions

1) Business revenue functions for three types of enterprises:

1) Set π1 as the revenue function of enterprise E1, according to the hypothesis; then,

π1=PQ1+hdQ1+HhdC1C2Q1.(1)

Put P=αbQ, P=abq, and Q=Q1+Q2+Q3 into Eq. 1 to get

π1=aQ1bQ12bQ1Q2bQ1Q3+hdQ1+HhdC1C2Q1.(2)

Take the derivative of Q1 first order and set it equal to 0 in Eq. 1.

π1Q1=a2bQ1bQ2bQ3+hdC2=0.(3)

Thus, the optimal power saving Q1 can be obtained:

Q1=abQ2bQ3+hdC22b.(4)

2) Set π2 as the revenue function of enterprise E2, according to the hypothesis; then,

π2=PQ2+HhdhdQ2C2Q2.(5)

In the same way, take the derivative of Q2 first order and set it equal to 0 in Eq. 5. Thus, the optimal power consumption Q2 of enterprise E2 can be obtained:

Q2=abQ1bQ2hdC22b.(6)

3) Set π3 as the revenue function of enterprise E2, according to the hypothesis; then,

π3=PQ3+Hhd+λQ3hd(1λ)Q3hdC1C2Q3.(7)

In the same way, take the derivative of Q3 first order and set it equal to 0 in Eq. 7. Thus, the optimal power consumption Q3 of enterprise E3 can be obtained.

Q3=abQ1bQ2+2λhdhdC22b.(8)

Joint establishment of optimal power consumption of three kinds of enterprises, which can be simplified to

{Q1=a2λhd+5hdC24bQ2=a2λ|hd3hdC24bQ3=a+6λhd3hdC24bQ=3a+2λhdhd3C24b.(9)

By substituting the optimal solution of the above formula into the profit function of the respective enterprises, the optimal earnings of the three types of enterprises can be further obtained as follows:

{π1=(a2λhd+5hdC2)216b+HdhC1π2=(a2λ|hd3hdC2)216b+Hdhπ3=(a+6λhd3hdC2)2|16b+HdhC1.(10)

Results

Relationship Analysis of Main Parameters

1) For enterprise E1

According to Eq. 9, the electricity saved by enterprise E1 has no relationship with the total carbon quota set by the government for the enterprise and is related to the carbon quota obtained by saving each unit of electricity and the benefit of unit carbon quota. In Eq. 9, the optimized first-order derivative of Q1 to h can be obtained as follows:

Q1h=5d2λd4b.(11)

Then, result 1 can be obtained as follows. Result 1: the income of enterprise E1 is directly related to the carbon quota for implementing EPP. There is a unit of carbon quotas h0. When the carbon quota obtained by the implementation of EPP is higher than h0, the income of enterprise E1 will increase with the increase of unit carbon quota, and enterprise E1 will continuously increase its sales volume to obtain greater income. When the carbon quota obtained from the implementation of EPP is lower than h0, the enterprise income decreases with the increase of unit carbon quota, and the enterprise reduces the intensity of the implementation of EPP to ensure its own interests within a reasonable range.

Then, we analyze the relationship between revenue and R&D investment. The optimized first derivative of revenue π1 with respect to R&D investment C1can be obtained as follows:

π1C1=1.(12)

Then, result 2 can be obtained as follows. Result 2: in Eq. 12, π1C1<0, therefore, for enterprise E1, its incomes are negatively correlated with R&D investment, and enterprise income π1 decreases with the increase of R&D investment C1. In order to ensure the normal operation of the enterprise, there must be a critical value of the R&D investment. Below this value, the enterprise can operate normally and obtain profits. If the R&D investment exceeds this value, the enterprise will be unprofitable and gradually eliminated by the market.

Then, we analyzed the relationship between income π1 of enterprise E1 and income d from the unit carbon quota. In Eq. 10, the optimized first derivative of the enterprise income with respect to the unit carbon quota income can be obtained as follows:

π1d=(104λ)ah+8λ2h2d+(5040λ)h2d+4λhC216b+Hh.(13)

Then, result 3 can be obtained as follows. Result 3: in Eq. 13, all the unknowns are positive values, and we know 0 < λ < 1; so, (104λ)ah>0, (5040λ)h2d>0, and so π1d>0. There is a positive correlation between the income of enterprise E1 and the income of unit carbon quota, that is, with the increase of the income of unit carbon quota formulated by the government, the income of enterprises is gradually increasing. Similarly, the income of enterprise E1 is positively correlated with the total carbon quota set by the government and the higher the carbon quota set by the government, the higher the profit obtained by the enterprise.

2) For enterprise E2

In Eq. 10, the optimized first-order derivative of revenue π2 of enterprise E2 with respect to revenue d of the unit carbon quota can be obtained as follows:

π2d=(6+4λ)ah+8λ2h2d+24λh2d+4λhC2+18h2d+6hC216b+Hh.(14)

We cannot determine if π2d is greater than 0 in Eq. 14. Let π2d=0, we can get

d0=16bh8λ2h3+24λh3+18h2+6a+4λa+4λC2+6h8λ2h+24λh+18h.(15)

In Eq. 15, when d=d0, π2d=0. Therefore, the second derivative of Eq. 14 can be obtained as follows:

2π2d2=8λ2h2+24h2+18λh216b.(16)

Then, result 4 is obtained as follows. Result 4: in Eq. 16, h and b are constants greater than 0, 0<λ<1. That is, 2π2d2>0, and the second derivative is greater than 0, indicating that the first derivative is monotonically increasing function. When d>d0, the first derivative is greater than 0, and the first derivative is a monotonically increasing function. Therefore, the original function π2 is a monotonically increasing function, that is, enterprise E2 and incomeπ2 increase with the increase of income d of the unit carbon quota. When d<d0 , the first derivative is less than 0, that is, the original function π2 is a monotonically decreasing function, and the enterprise incomeπ2 decreases with the increase of income d of the unit carbon quota. Enterprise E2 income decreases first and then increases with the increase of the carbon quota income, and when d=d0 , the enterprise income is the smallest.

Similarly, in order to study the relationship between enterprise E2, income π2, and carbon quota h consumption, the modeling process is similar to the above contents. Taking the second derivative of income π2 and carbon quota h of consumption,h0 can be obtained; making π2h=0 and then judging the monotonicity of the function, result 5 can be obtained as follows.

Result 5: there is a negative correlation between enterprise E2 income and consumed carbon quota, that is, the income decreases with the increase of unit carbon quota. Within a certain range of unit carbon quota h, enterprise E2 income will increase with the increase of carbon quota consumed, but beyond a certain range, the enterprise income will decrease with the increase of carbon quota consumed. For the government, the carbon quota of E2 per unit enterprise determined must be greater than h0, so that enterprises can be urged to reduce energy consumption in traditional production and then transform to implement EPP.

2) For enterprise E3

In this part, we analyze the electricity saved and the revenue from enterprise E3 and discuss how the parameter changes with carbon quota and the value of the probability a of implementing EPP, so as to maximize the enterprise revenue. That is, to study the electricity saved by enterprise E3 and analyze the variation trend between electricity saved and carbon quota h, revenue d per unit carbon quota, and probability λ of EPP implementation.

Firstly, in Eq. 9, the first derivative of electricity quantity Q3 consumed by the enterprise with respect to carbon quota h and revenue d of the unit carbon quota can be obtained as follows:

{Q3h=12λd6d8bQ3d=12λh6h8b.(17)

Then, result 6 can be obtained as follows. Result 6: in Eq. 17, h, d and b are constants greater than 0, and 0<λ < 1. When 0<λ < 0.5, 12λd−6d < 0, and 12λℎ−6ℎ<0, that is, Q3h>0 and Q3d>0, the electricity saved by enterprise E3 decreases with the increase of the unit carbon quota h and unit carbon quota income d; when 0.5<λ < 1, 12λd−6d> 0, and 12λℎ−6ℎ> 0, that is, Q3h>0 and Q3d>0, the electricity saved by enterprise E3 increases with the increase of unit carbon quota d and unit carbon quota revenue d.

Secondly, we analyze the income in Eq. 10 of enterprise E3 and find that the factors affecting enterprise income are related to the development cost, the total carbon quota given by the government, the income of carbon quota per unit, and the carbon quota obtained (or consumed) from energy saving (consumption). The relationship between the enterprise income and unit carbon quota income is analyzed as follows. In Eq. 10, the first derivative of the enterprise income π3 with respect to revenue d of the unit carbon quota can be obtained as follows:

π3d=12λah6ah+72λ2h2d72λh2d+18h2d+6hC212λhC216b+Hh.(18)

We cannot determine whether π3d is greater than 0 in Eq. 18. Therefore, the second derivative of d can be obtained as follows:

2π3d2=72λ2h272λh2+18h216b.(19)

In Eq. 19, h and b are constants greater than 0, and 0<λ < 1. So, 2π3d2 is greater than 0 is equal to 72λ2h272λh2+18h2 is greater than 0. Because ℎ2 must be greater than 0, we just need to determine whether 72λ2h272λh2+18 is greater than 0. Let 72λ2h272λh2+18=0, we get λ=12λ=12; in other words, this quadratic opens up and only intersects the X-axis at one point. Therefore, it can be concluded that 2π3d20 is always true, that is, the first derivative function is monotonically increasing function. Set the first derivative function equal to 0, and we can get d0':

d0'=8Hb36λ2h336λh3+9h32aλa+C22λC212λ2h12λh+3h.(20)

Then, result 7 can be obtained as follows. Result 7: when d<d0', π3d<0, and the second derivative function 2π3d2 is a monotonically increasing function, so the original function π3 is a monotonically decreasing function. That is, enterprise E3 income π3 is negatively correlated with unit carbon quota income d, that is, the enterprise income decreases with the increase of unit carbon quota income. When d>d0', π3d>0, and the second derivative function 2π3d2 is a monotonically increasing function, so the original function π3 is a monotonically increasing function. In other words, enterprise E3 income π3increases with the increase of unit carbon quota income d. With the increase of the unit carbon quota income, enterprise E3 income shows a trend of decreasing first and then increasing, and when unit carbon quota income d=d0', the enterprise income is the lowest and then increases with the increase of the unit carbon quota. When d<d0', the enterprise income decreases with the increase of the unit carbon quota. The main reason is that enterprises are unwilling to implement EPP in the early stage; the higher the income of unit carbon quota increases, the higher the government punishment the enterprises will accept. When d>d0', the enterprise begins to implement EPP, and the increase of unit carbon quota income will greatly increase the income brought by power saving, so the enterprise income will gradually increase.

Similarly, the change trend between enterprise benefit and unit carbon quota h is as same as the relationship between enterprise income and unit carbon quota income d, and we would not analyze separately. In other words, enterprise E3 income will decrease first and then increase with the increase of the unit carbon quota, and when h=h0, the income reaches the minimum value.

Next, we analyze the relationship between the corporate income and total carbon quota. In Eq. 10, the first derivative of enterprise E3 incomeπ3 with respect to the total carbon quota H can be obtained as follows:

π3H=dh.(21)

Then, result 8 can be obtained as follows. Result 8: in Eq. 21, d and h are constants greater than 0, so π3H>0. And, the original function is a monotonically increasing function. In other words, there is a positive correlation between enterprise E3 income π3 and total carbon quota H, and enterprise E3 income increases with the increase of the total carbon quota given by the government.

Then, the first derivative of enterprise E3 income π3 with respect to the probability λ of EPP implementation can be obtained as follows:

π3λ=3hd(a+6λhd)3hdC24b.(22)

In Eq. 22, we cannot determine whether π3λ is greater than 0, so the second derivative of λ can be obtained as follows:

2π3λ2=27h2d22b.(23)

In Eq. 23, h, d, and b are constants greater than 0, so 2π3λ2>0. The first derivative π3λ is a monotonically increasing function. Let π3λ=0, we get λ0:

λ0=C2+3hda6hd.(25)

Then, result 9 can be obtained as follows. Result 9: when λ<λ0, π3λ<0, and the first derivative function is monotonically increasing function. Therefore, the function π3 is a monotonically decreasing function, and enterprise E3 earnings π3 decreases with the increase of λ. When λ>λ0, the first derivative is a monotonically increasing function, and π3λ>0, the functionπ3is a monotonically increasing function, that is, enterprise E3 earnings π3increases with the increase of λ. In the change process of probability λ of implementing EPP, the enterprise income first gradually decreases and then increases. The previous enterprise income will decrease with the increase of λ, The main reason lies in the large investment in the research and development of EPP technology and equipment in the early stage. With the increase of λ, EPP is gradually recognized and promoted by the government and enterprises due to its advantages of zero emission and energy saving. After a period of promotion and gradual improvement of government policies, the benefits brought to enterprises by the implementation of EPP are gradually reflected. Therefore, whenλ>λ0, the enterprise income will increase with the increase of λ.For enterprise E3, λ should not be set asλ0 because the enterprise income is the lowest at this time; if the enterprise prefers not to implement EPP, the ratio λ should be set below λ0; if the enterprise is inclined to implement EPP, the production ratio λ should be set above λ0(0<λ0<1), and the higher the proportion is set, the greater the profit of the enterprise will be.

Verification of Results

The previous nine results are mainly obtained through mathematical model construction and derivation. In order to verify the validity of the results, this part uses Maple, simulation software, to verify the validity of the results. Maple software is one of the most general mathematical and engineering computing software in the world and is widely used in the field of mathematics and science, among which the application of Maple software to test the correctness of decision results is one of its main applications. Main steps of Maple simulation include four steps, namely, assignment of variables, establishment of simulation model, analysis model, and conclusion. Among them, numerical setting plays a crucial role in the establishment of the simulation model, which determines whether the simulation model can correctly verify the decision results.

According to the above parameter setting and requirements and referring to literature studies (Du et al., 2015; Luo et al., 2016; Huang et al., 2018), we set the values of each parameter as shown in Table 3.

TABLE 3
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 3. The value setting of some parameters in simulation.

Now, Maple software was used to verify nine results of the changes of industry income, output, and other variables of three kinds of enterprises, respectively, and the verification processes are as follows.

1) For enterprises E1

Verification of result 1: the relationship image between enterprise E1 income π1 and unit carbon quota h is plotted according to known conditions, as shown in Figure 2. It can be seen that when 0 < h < 1.4, the enterprise income decreases with the increase of the unit carbon quota. When h > 1.4, the enterprise income increases with the increase of the unit carbon quota, and the increasing amplitude is gradually expanding. When h = 1.4, the enterprise income reaches the minimum, which is consistent with result 2.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 2. The relationship between enterprise E1 income π1 and h.

Verification of results 2 and 3: similarly, we set λ=0.5 and plot the relationship image between enterprise E1 income π1, R&D cost C1, and unit carbon quota income d, as shown in Figure 3. It can be seen that π1 decreases with the increase of R&D cost and increases with the increase of the unit carbon quota income. In other words, the larger the income per unit carbon quota is, the higher the income from implementing EPP to save electricity will be, and the more enterprises tend to implement EPP, the more conducive to the development of EPP, which is consistent with result 3 and result 4. It should be noted that the above situation does not hold indefinitely because in the actual cases, the enterprise income will increase with the increase of carbon quota income over a period of time. However, after a certain range, under the influence of some factors such as policies, market saturation, and diminishing marginal return, the enterprise income will not continue to increase with the increase of carbon quota income.

2) For enterprise E2

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 3. The relationship between enterprise E1 income π1 with C1and d.

Verification of result 4: let λ=0.5 and draw the graph of the first-order derivative function of enterprise E2 income π2 with respect to unit carbon quota income d, as shown in Figure 4A. According to the image, when d>0, only the value of the first derivative function of enterprise E2 income π2 with respect to unit carbon quota income d is constant when the value is greater than 0. In other words, the enterprise income is positively correlated with the unit carbon quota income, which increases with the increase of the unit carbon quota income. When the first derivative is equal to d=d0<0, in the actual operation of an enterprise, the income per unit carbon quota will not be negative. So, the function of d0<0 is not analyzed. Plot the relationship image between enterprise E2 income π2 and unit carbon quota income d, as shown in Figure 4B. The analysis based on Figure 5A shows that when d0>0, enterprise the income increases with the increase of unit carbon quota, which is consistent with result 4.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 4. (A) The function image of the derivative of π2 with respect to d. (B) The relationship between π2 and d.

FIGURE 5
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 5. The function image of the derivative of π2 with respect to h.

Verification of result 5: let λ=0.5 and draw the graph of the first-order derivative function of enterprise E2 income π2 with respect to unit carbon quota h, as shown in Figure 5. In practice, it is impossible to take a negative value of carbon quota h, so the function image is taken as the function image of h > 0. According to the image, when h <−0.76, π2h>0, that is, enterprise E2 income π2 increases with the increase of carbon quota h consumed; when h > −0.76, π2h<0, that is, enterprise E2 incomeπ2decreases with the increase of carbon quota h consumed, which is consistent with result 5.

3) For enterprise E3

Verification of result 6: we analyze the relationship between electric quantity Q3 saved by enterprise E3 with unit carbon quota d and unit carbon quota income h. In this model, there are two stages according to whether λ is greater than 0.5. When 0<λ<0.5, set λ=16, and draw the changing trend image of the relationship between Q3, d, and h. As shown in Figure 6A, Q3 decreases with the increase of d and h. However, since the slope of curve h is significantly higher than that of curve d, the degree of influence of h is higher than that of d. When the two factors influence the output of an enterprise at the same time, the range of change of variable h should be given the priority. When 0.5<λ<1, set λ=23, and draw the changing trend image of the relationship between enterprise electric saved quantity Q3, d, and h, as shown in Figure 6B. Q3 increases with the increase of d and h, similarly, h has a higher influence on Q3 than d. The result of this part is consistent with result 6, which verifies the correctness of result 6.

FIGURE 6
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 6. (A) The relationship between electricity Q3saving in enterprise E3 with h and d(0<λ<0.5). (B) The relationship between electricity Q3saving in enterprise E3 with h and d(0.5<λ<1).

Verification of result 7: study the relationship between enterprise E3 income π3 and unit carbon quota revenue d, set λ=16, and draw the first-order derivative function image of π3 with respect to d, as shown in Figure 7. According to the figure, when d is small enough, the first-order derivative function will be less than 0. At this time, the enterprise income will decrease with the increase of unit carbon quota. Subsequently, with the gradual increase of d, the enterprise income will increase with the increase of the unit carbon quota income, which is consistent with result 7.

FIGURE 7
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 7. The function image of the derivative of π3 with respect to d.

Verification result 8: now, study the relationship between enterprise E3 income π3 and total carbon quota H, set λ=0.5, and draw the changing trend diagram between π3 and total carbon quota according to known data, as shown in Figure 8. According to Figure 8, the enterprise income is positively correlated with the total carbon quota, that is, the enterprise income continues to increase with the increase of the total carbon quota, which is consistent with result 8. In addition, for every unit of change in the total carbon quota obtained from the image, the enterprise income will change by 203 units, that is, the total carbon quota has a great impact on the enterprise income, which is a key factor that enterprises must consider in production.

FIGURE 8
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 8. The relationship between π3 and total carbon quota H.

Verification of result 9: finally, we study the relationship between enterprise E3 income π3 and total carbon quota H, set λ=0.5, and draw the changing trend diagram between π3 and willingness (probability) λ to implement EPP according to known data, as shown in Figure 9A. According to Figure 10A, the enterprise income first decreases and then increases with the gradual increase of λ. However, the effective value range of λ in this paper is 0λ1. Therefore, we select part of the function images in Figure 10A to obtain Figure 9B, and when 0λ1, the enterprise income π3 continues to increase with the increase of λ. It can be seen from the figure that when λ=0 and the enterprise does not implement EPP, the enterprise has a certain income, and with the gradual increase of λ, the enterprise income continues to increase. When λ=1, enterprise income reaches the maximum, which is consistent with result 9.

FIGURE 9
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 9. (A) The relationship between enterprise E3 earnings π3 and λ(1000λ1000). (B) The relationship between enterprise E3 earnings π3 and λ(0λ1).

FIGURE 10
www.frontiersin.org

FIGURE 10. The block diagram of the case study.

Case Study

To prove the practicability of the model and the results, this part will use a case study to analyze the influence on the initial total amount of carbon quota H, carbon quota h obtained from unit energy saving, and unit carbon quota income d to the probabilityλ the enterprise implementing EPP. The authors and their research team members conducted a 2-month field survey at four EPP projects in Jiangxi Province in July and August 2019, to collect two kinds of original data as follows, aiming at providing basic data for VC++ program operation:

1) The basic information and data of the EPP project, such as project name, investment amount, annual power saving, annual carbon emission, equipment life, and other information come from field investigation of EPP project in Jiangxi province.

2) The common parameters, such as sales price of power saved by EPP, cost of EPP implementation, and other data are referred to recent data released by authorities and Energy Statistics Yearbook.

Table 4 shows the survey object descriptions and fixed parameter setting.

TABLE 4
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 4. The survey object descriptions and fixed parameter setting.

Note: 1Sales price of power saved by EPP fluctuates with the market, but this part does not take electricity price as the focus problem. In order to simplify the problem, we take the average selling electricity price during the observation period as the final value. 3For the cost of EPP implementation, which is also variable, we take the average value.

2The implementation of EPP has zero carbon emission, and enterprises only have carbon emissions when they do not implement EPP. Therefore, the carbon emission of the investigated enterprises is much lower than that of ordinary small or medium-sized manufacturing enterprises.

Next, we will adjust the initial total amount of carbon quota H, carbon quota h obtained from unit energy saving, and unit carbon quota income d, which will influence the decision of enterprises to implement EPP, and finally calculate the power saving and income of enterprises under the specified decision. Because the data in this study are complex and there are multifarious index operations, the VC++ (version 6.0) is used to construct a program to achieve the solution of this case study. The main code of VC++ program can refer to the code in the attachment of a previous article by Zhu et al., 2019. The block diagram of this case study can be shown in Figure 10.

The results are shown in Table 5.

TABLE 5
www.frontiersin.org

TABLE 5. The probability λ of EPP implementation and its power saving Q and revenue π3 under different H, h, and d.

According to Table 5, lines 1 through line 3 show that unit carbon quota income d has a positive effect on power saving Q and revenue π3. With the increase of d, enterprises are more inclined to implement EPP. Line 4 through line 6 show that carbon quota h obtained from unit energy saving has a positive effect on power saving Q and revenue π3. With the increase of h, enterprises are more inclined to implement EPP. Line 7 through line 9 show that initial total amount of carbon quota H has a positive effect on power saving Q and revenue π3. With the increase of H, enterprises are more inclined to implement EPP. Line 10 through line 12 show that h has a greater influence than d, and the change of h plays a more important role in the decision of enterprises to implement EPP.

The results in Table 5 are consistent with those obtained in Relationship Analysis of Main Parameters, that is, we prove the above results from the perspective of empirical analysis.

Discussion

In this paper, three important contents are put forward:

Firstly, we build the profit functions of three types of enterprises, analyze the relationships of main parameters, and get nine results.

Secondly, we use Maple, the simulation software, to verify the validity of the results by drawing images of parameters. All the above nine results passed the simulation test.

Finally, we carry out an empirical analysis of a Chinese case and verify the practicability of the profit functions and the results of parameter relationship analysis through the actual survey data, which has practical guiding significance.

Compared to Zhu et al.’s, 2018, study about the general study of low-carbon investment, low-carbon investment is translated into implementation of EPP, and specific research conclusions and specific recommendations are given. Compared to literature studies by Li et al., 2017 and Sun et al., 2020, about the income study of carbon emission, the carbon emission energy savings are considered as one of the benefits of implementing EPP. Compared to (Arai et al.’s, 2014, study, correlation analysis of parameters is constructed based on three different types of enterprises and under different carbon quota constraints. Compared to literature studies by Zhu et al., 2018 and Dou et al., 2020, a simulation by Maple software and a case study in China are put forward to verify the research results.

Above all, this paper has three innovation points or improvements:

First, most research objects in literature studies about general low-carbon investment only have the function of reducing carbon emission or pollutant emission, while our research object-EPP in this paper is a special low-carbon behavior, which can reduce power consumption and carbon emission at the same time.

Second, the correlation analysis of parameters we constructed takes into account not only three types of different enterprises but also different carbon quota constraints.

Finally, through simulation and empirical analysis, we double test the profit function model and relevant results to verify their scientific effectiveness.

Conclusion and Suggestion

Conclusion

Firstly, the paper analyzed the factors affecting the earnings and output of EPP enterprises, non-EPP enterprises, and selective EPP enterprises by establishing the profit functions, and then, we studied how the income and output of three kinds of enterprises change with the carbon quota. Thus, production decisions of different types of enterprises under different carbon quotas are obtained, and the results through Maple simulation software and empirical analysis are verified, in order to provide theoretical reference for different types of enterprises to make production decisions under different carbon quotas.

Suggestions

1) As the carbon quota given by the government and the carbon quota obtained by implementing EPP increase, the enterprise will gain more disposable carbon quotas, so enterprises can sell excess carbon quotas to reap the benefits and their profits will soar. At this time, enterprises should increase the investment in EPP research and input to acquisition, continuously improve the ability of EPP core technology, so as to expand their market share, and obtain the long-term development of the enterprise.

2) The effect of carbon quota obtained by implementing EPP on the output of enterprises is much greater than that of carbon quota income per unit. When both factors have an impact on the output of an enterprise, the enterprise should give priority to the carbon quota obtained by implementing EPP, so as to ensure the maximum income of the enterprise.

3) According to the change of carbon quota and unit carbon quota income, enterprises should adjust the intensity of EPP implementation to obtain higher income. Enterprise income is positively correlated with total carbon quota, carbon quota income per unit, and the intensity (probability) of EPP implementation. Therefore, when the total carbon quota and revenue per unit of carbon quota given by the government increase, enterprises should enhance the implementation of EPP, so that enterprises can obtain higher revenue.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/Supplementary Material. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author Contributions

YZ constructed the theoretical framework of the manuscript. YJ collected the data and made statistical analysis.

Funding

This work was supported by the Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC; grant number: 71964022, grant number: 72164026), Educational Science Project of Jiangxi Province (grant number: 18YB012), and Jiangxi Culture, Art and Science Planning Project (grant number: YG2018037).

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s Note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors, and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

Arai, R., Yamamoto, K., Nishio, T., and Morikura, M. (2014). Differential Game-Theoretic Analysis on Information Availability in Decentralized Demand-Side Energy Management Systems. IEICE Trans. Commun. E97.B (9), 1817–1825. doi:10.1587/transcom.e97.b.1817

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Çakmak, R., and Altaş, İ. H. (2020). A Novel Billing Approach for Fair and Effective Demand Side Management: Appliance Level Billing (AppLeBill). Int. J. Electr. Power Energ. Syst. 121, 106062. doi:10.1016/j.ijepes.2020.106062

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Castro, M. d. F., Colclough, S., Machado, B., Andrade, J., and Bragança, L. (2020). European Legislation and Incentives Programmes for Demand Side Management. Solar Energy 200, 114–124. doi:10.1016/j.solener.2019.12.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Castro, M. d. F., Colclough, S., Machado, B., Andrade, J., and Bragança, L. (2020). European Legislation and Incentives Programmes for Demand Side Management. Solar Energy 200, 114–124. doi:10.1016/j.solener.2019.12.004

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chakraborty, N., Mondal, A., and Mondal, S. (2020). Efficient Load Control Based Demand Side Management Schemes towards a Smart Energy Grid System. Sustain. Cities Soc. 59, 102175. doi:10.1016/j.scs.2020.102175

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chamandoust, H., Bahramara, S., and Derakhshan, G. (2020). Day-ahead Scheduling Problem of Smart Micro-grid with High Penetration of Wind Energy and Demand Side Management Strategies. Sustainable Energ. Tech. Assessments 40, 100747. doi:10.1016/j.seta.2020.100747

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chang, L., Hao, X., Song, M., Wu, J., Feng, Y., Qiao, Y., et al. (2020). Carbon Emission Performance and Quota Allocation in the Bohai Rim Economic Circle. J. Clean. Prod. 258, 120722. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.120722

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chen, H., Li, Y., Louie, R. H. Y., and Vucetic, B. (2014). Autonomous Demand Side Management Based on Energy Consumption Scheduling and Instantaneous Load Billing: an Aggregative Game Approach. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 5 (4), 1744–1754. doi:10.1109/tsg.2014.2311122

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Chen, W. (2003). Carbon Quota price and CDM Potentials after Marrakesh. Energy Policy 31 (8), 709–719. doi:10.1016/s0301-4215(02)00122-2

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dales, J. H. (1968). Pollution, Property and Prices: An Essay in Policy-Making and Economics. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Dou, X. (2015). The Essence, Feature and Role of Low Carbon Economy. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 17 (1), 123–136. doi:10.1007/s10668-014-9542-9

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Dou, X., Wang, J., Wang, X. Y., and Wu, L. (2020). Analysis of User Demand Side Response Behavior of Regional Integrated Power and Gas Energy Systems Based on Evolutionary Game. Proc. Chin. Soc. Electr. Eng. 40 (12), 3775–3785. doi:10.13334/j.0258-8013.pcsee.190581

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Du, S., Hu, L., and Wang, L. (2017). Low-carbon Supply Policies and Supply Chain Performance with Carbon Concerned Demand. Ann. Oper. Res. 255 (1-2), 569–590. doi:10.1007/s10479-015-1988-0

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Du, S., Zhu, J., Jiao, H., and Ye, W. (2015). Game-theoretical Analysis for Supply Chain with Consumer Preference to Low Carbon. Int. J. Prod. Res. 53 (12), 3753–3768. doi:10.1080/00207543.2014.988888

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Du, S., Zhu, L., Liang, L., and Ma, F. (2013). Emission-dependent Supply Chain and Environment-Policy-Making in the 'cap-And-Trade' System. Energy Policy 57, 61–67. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.09.042

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Energy Research Institute of State Grid of China (2010). Study on Ways and Means to the Construction of EPP. Beijing, China: China Electric Power Press. (In Chinese).

Haydt, G., Leal, V., and Dias, L. (2014). A Multi-Objective Approach for Developing National Energy Efficiency Plans. Energy Policy 67, 16–27. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.06.133

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Huang, Z., Yu, H., Chu, X., and Peng, Z. (2018). A Novel Optimization Model Based on Game Tree for Multi-Energy Conversion Systems. Energy 150, 109–121. doi:10.1016/j.energy.2018.02.091

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Kalair, A. R., Abas, N., Hasan, Q. U., Seyedmahmoudian, M., and Khan, N. (2020). Demand Side Management in Hybrid Rooftop Photovoltaic Integrated Smart Nano Grid. J. Clean. Prod. 258, 120747. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.120747

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, H., Wang, C., Xu, L., and Ou, W. (2017). Pricing, Carbon Emission Reduction, Collection Decision, and Coordination in a Low-Carbon Closed-Loop Supply Chain. J. Renew. Sustain. Energ. 9 (6), 065907. doi:10.1063/1.4991668

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Li, M.-J., Song, C.-X., and Tao, W.-Q. (2016). A Hybrid Model for Explaining the Short-Term Dynamics of Energy Efficiency of China's thermal Power Plants. Appl. Energ. 169, 738–747. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.02.082

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Liu, X., Gao, B., Wu, C., and Tang, Y. (2018). Demand-Side Management with Household Plug-In Electric Vehicles: a Bayesian Game-Theoretic Approach. IEEE Syst. J. 12 (3), 2894–2904. doi:10.1109/jsyst.2017.2741719

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Luo, Z., Chen, X., and Wang, X. (2016). The Role of Co-opetition in Low Carbon Manufacturing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 253 (2), 392–403. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2016.02.030

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mahmoudi, R., Emrouznejad, A., Khosroshahi, H., Khashei, M., and Rajabi, P. (2019). Performance Evaluation of thermal Power Plants Considering CO2 Emission: A Multistage PCA, Clustering, Game Theory and Data Envelopment Analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 223, 641–650. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.03.047

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Mendes, D. L. S., Rabelo, R. A. L., Veloso, A. F. S., Rodrigues, J. J. P. C., and dos Reis Junior, J. V. (2020). An Adaptive Data Compression Mechanism for Smart Meters Considering a Demand Side Management Scenario. J. Clean. Prod. 255, 120190. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.120190

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Rai, V., and Beck, A. L. (2017). Play and Learn: Serious Games in Breaking Informational Barriers in Residential Solar Energy Adoption in the United States. Energ. Res. Soc. Sci. 27, 70–77. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2017.03.001

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Srikanth Reddy, K., Lokesh Kumar Panwar, L. K., Panigrahi, B. K., Rajesh Kumar, R., and Xu, Y. (2020). A Dual Objective Approach for Aggregator Managed Demand Side Management (DSM) in Cloud Based Cyber Physical Smart Distribution System. Future Generation Comput. Syst. 105, 843–854. doi:10.1016/j.future.2017.08.019

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Sun, L., Cao, X., Alharthi, M., Zhang, J., Taghizadeh-Hesary, F., and Mohsin, M. (2020). Carbon Emission Transfer Strategies in Supply Chain with Lag Time of Emission Reduction Technologies and Low-Carbon Preference of Consumers. J. Clean. Prod. 264, 121664. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.121664

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Venizelou, V., Makrides, G., Efthymiou, V., and Georghiou, G. E. (2020). Methodology for Deploying Cost-Optimum price-based Demand Side Management for Residential Prosumers. Renew. Energ. 153, 228–240. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2020.02.025

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, J.-M., Ge, X., Zhang, L., and Zhang, H. (2016). Management Index Systems and Energy Efficiency Diagnosis Model for Power Plant: Cases in China. Math. Probl. Eng. 2016, 1–13. doi:10.1155/2016/8159871

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, J. M., and Zhu, Y. P. (2014). Cost-benefit Analysis of DSM Energy-Efficiency Project in Low-Carbon Vision: a Case in China. Energy Education Science and Technology Part A. Energ. Sci. Res. 32 (1), 645–658. doi:10.1016/j.enbuild.2014.07.008

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Wang, J., Zhu, Y., and Li, Y. (2015). EPP Energy Efficiency Calculation and Influencing Factor Analysis: Cases in China. Math. Probl. Eng. 2015, 1–8. doi:10.1155/2015/986562

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhang, Y.-J., Wang, A.-D., and Da, Y.-B. (2014). Regional Allocation of Carbon Emission Quotas in China: Evidence from the Shapley Value Method. Energy Policy 74, 454–464. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2014.08.006

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhu, G., Pan, G., and Zhang, W. (2018). Evolutionary Game Theoretic Analysis of Low Carbon Investment in Supply Chains under Governmental Subsidies. Ijerph 15 (11), 2465. doi:10.3390/ijerph15112465

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhu, Y., Hu, Y., and Zhang, F. (2017). Progressive IRP Models for Power Resources Including EPP. Math. Probl. Eng. 2017, 1–7. doi:10.1155/2017/2520346

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Zhu, Y. P., Feng, W., and Fan, L. Z. (2019). An Evolutionary Game Study on Implementation of Energy Efficiency Power Plants between Government and enterprise Considering Carbon Emission Right Trading. Appl. Ecol. Env. Res. 17 (1), 699–722. doi:10.15666/aeer/1701_699722

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: efficiency power plants, implementation decision, carbon quota, relationship analysis, maple

Citation: Zhu Y and Jin Y (2021) Efficiency Power Plant Implementation Decision-Making Based on the Profit Function and Its Numerical Simulation. Front. Energy Res. 9:628206. doi: 10.3389/fenrg.2021.628206

Received: 11 November 2020; Accepted: 18 August 2021;
Published: 15 September 2021.

Edited by:

Hong-zhou Li, Dongbei University of Finance and Economics, China

Reviewed by:

Neeraj Dhanraj Bokde, Aarhus University, Denmark
Shuai Geng, Shandong Jianzhu University, China

Copyright © 2021 Zhu and Jin. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Yiping Zhu, zhuyipingnet@ncu.edu.cn

Download