On absolute and comparative advantage in international trade: A Pasinetti pure labour approach

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2021.09.005Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Pasinetti's insights into international trade are formalized.

  • Absolute advantage is rehabilitated based on wage disparities.

  • Absolute advantage is important to the realization of comparative advantage.

Abstract

This paper builds upon Pasinetti's pure labour model, formalizing some of the insights that he has provided into the structure of international trade. A systematic approach is followed, starting with restrictive assumptions that are relaxed in subsequent stages of analysis. The starting point is a model in which two countries, one advanced and the other underdeveloped, have equal costs of production. This implies that there are no incentives for trade. At a second stage, we introduce and formalize the conditions required for these countries to exhibit absolute cost advantages, based on wage disparities. Finally, the paper establishes the conditions required for comparative advantage, based on relative differences in technology. Building on an interpretation of Ricardo's writings on trade, it is shown that absolute advantage is critical for the two countries to realise potential cost reductions afforded by comparative advantage. This abstract insight, based on the Pasinetti pure labour system, suggests that absolute advantage has a more fundamental role in international trade than given by previous studies, which focus more on either the international mobility of money capital or the international fragmentation of production.

Introduction

The main legacy of Ricardo's contribution to international trade theory is the theory of comparative advantage. Samuelson (1969, p. 9), for example, calls it one of the few propositions “in all of the social sciences which is both true and non-trivial”. And for Krugman (2002, p. 35), “Ricardo's idea is truly, madly, deeply difficult. But it is also utterly true, immensely sophisticated – and extremely relevant to the modern world”.

The usual interpretation is that comparative advantage represents a major analytical improvement over absolute advantage theory. Ruffin (2005, p. 746), for example, argues that Ricardo's true genius is to work out that a country can gain an advantage, compared to other countries, in its relative costs of production, as opposed to the ‘fallacy of absolute advantage’. The bulk of the economics profession thus views absolute advantage as a mere stepping stone for trade theory.

There has, however, been some questioning of this deprecation of absolute advantage in studies of classical political economy, as associated with the production-based approach of Sraffa (1960).1 One particular strand of this literature has developed an external critique of Ricardo's model that abandons the assumption of immobility of money capital between countries (Shaikh, 1999, 2016; Parrinello, 2010; Bellino and Fratini, 2019; Crespo et al., 2020). The introduction of free international mobility of money capital implies that capitalists can move their capital to other countries in search for higher rates of profit. The idea is that countries with lower costs of production, however defined, will support higher rates of profit and hence attract capital. In this way, it is suggested that the driver of international trade and specialization could be lower absolute costs.

An alternative study advocating the importance of absolute advantage is that of Baldone et al. (2007). Here, the criticism of comparative advantage is not based on mobility of money capital, but rather due to the complications associated with trade in (physical) intermediate goods. With the fragmentation of production there is a “lessening of the power of the concept of comparative advantages (…) while it is the concept of absolute advantage that becomes increasingly relevant” (Baldone et al., 2007, p. 1727). Traditional measures of comparative advantage might suggest that a country should specialize in the production of a particular final commodity; but with fragmentation it might be cheaper for the country to export the intermediate inputs necessary for another country to produce the final commodity – which the original country then imports. It is argued, using a two-country model, with zero profits and traded intermediate capital inputs, that trade patterns can thus be explained by actual costs of producing the commodities: absolute advantage.

There is, however, a dimension to this analysis that has been somewhat neglected: it rests on a fundamental assumption that each country has a given money wage, both measured in a common unit of account (Baldone et al., 2007, p. 1733). This modelling of wage disparities allows for a comparison between money costs (and absolute advantage) between countries which, it may be argued, is more fundamental than Baldone et al.’s focus on intermediate inputs.

The contribution of this paper is thus to further investigate the role of wage disparities and absolute advantage in a production system with international trade that is more abstract than Baldone et al.’s formulation. The framework employed is perhaps the most abstract available in classical political economy, the two-country system developed by Pasinetti (1993) under pure labour technology, with zero profits and labour the only input to production. Our approach is to emphasize the role of money wage disparities in determining trade patterns and world prices. It will be shown that even in this simplified model absolute cost advantages can dominate competition between countries under given money wages. What sets our contribution apart is that we need not rely on either free mobility of money capital or trade in intermediate capital goods in order to establish a role for absolute advantage in international trade.

Though Pasinetti has much to say about international trade there has been very little attention to this aspect of his work. International trade is not, for example, considered in the intellectual biography of Pasinetti's work and the secondary literature provided by Baranzini and Mirante (2018). A further contribution here is thus to introduce a formalisation of the model of international trade developed in Chapter 9 of Pasinetti (1993).2 It will be argued that Pasinetti's step-by-step approach, with the systematic relaxation of restrictive assumptions at each stage of the analysis, can throw light on some of the core aspects of complex trade relationships.

The structure of the paper follows a step-by-step approach. Section 2 starts by setting up Pasinetti's two-country model of trade in its most concise form. By starting with Pasinetti's assumption of a uniform ten-fold disparity in technology and wage rates, between the two countries, costs are shown to be the same, providing no inducement to trade. Section 3 then introduces absolute advantage into the model by relaxing the assumption of a ten-fold difference in wages. It is shown that under wage disparities one of the countries will have cheaper production costs across all commodities. Finally, by then relaxing the assumption of uniform differences in technology, the possibility of comparative advantage is introduced in Section 4, together with a consideration of how absolute advantage may also retain its relevance. The final section provides a summary of the contribution and some concluding remarks.

Section snippets

The two-country Pasinetti model

Pasinetti (1993, Chapter 9) develops a rudimentary model of international trade in which there are two economic systems, each represented by a separate country. Each system has its own methods of production, with single commodity-producing industries employing direct (unassisted) labour to produce the same m commodities in each country. This is a pure labour economy in which there are zero profits and all income is allocated to labour. A key restriction is that the free movement of labour is

Absolute advantage

We have thus seen how Pasinetti's two-country model is constructed in such a way to exclude between-country differences in costs. Since there are no differences in costs between countries a world price is established for each commodity by construction. In this section we will introduce differences in absolute costs between countries in Pasinetti's model, keeping his assumption regarding a uniform ten-fold disparity in technologies. As a first step we consider the notion of absolute advantage.

A

Comparative advantage

In the analysis thus far, we have assumed that technology is uniformly inferior in one country relative to the other country. Country U had to employ ten times more workers per unit of output in every industry. The consequence of this assumption is that relative costs, and hence prices, are the same in both countries, as shown in expression (9). In this section we follow Pasinetti (1993, p. 178) by relaxing this assumption, still under the rubric of the pure labour model. This will allow us to

Conclusions

Pasinetti's writings on international trade have not hitherto been formalised as a mathematical system. Filling this gap in the literature, this paper explores in equation form the structure of the of the two-country model of international trade developed in Chapter 9 of Pasinetti (1993). This is a pure labour model, in which labour is the sole input of production to be considered under international trade.

The first contribution is to formalise Pasinetti's analytical starting point in which

References (37)

  • A. Brewer

    Trade with fixed real wages and mobile capital

    J. Int. Econ.

    (1985)
  • A.V. Deardorff

    Ricardian comparative advantage with intermediate inputs

    North Am. J. Econ. Finance

    (2005)
  • S. Baldone et al.

    On some effects of international fragmentation of production on comparative advantages, trade flows, and the income of countries

    World Econ.

    (2007)
  • M. Baranzini et al.

    Luigi L. Pasinetti: An Intellectual Biography

    (2018)
  • E. Bellino et al.

    Absolute advantages and capital mobility in international trade theory

    Centro Sraffa Working Papers

    (2019)
  • G. Bhering et al.

    There is no room: the role of reciprocal effectual demands in Ricardo’s theory of foreign trade

    Texto para Discussão - IE

    (2019)
  • E. Crespo et al.

    Exclusion in 'Ricardian' trade models

    Rev. Polit. Econ.

    (2020)
  • R. Dornbusch et al.

    Comparative advantage, trade, and payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1977)
  • A. Dvoskin et al.

    Income distribution and the balance of payments: a formal reconstruction of some Argentinian structuralist contributions Part I: technical dependency

    Rev. Keynesian Econ.

    (2018)
  • A. Dvoskin et al.

    Income distribution and the balance of payments: a formal reconstruction of some Argentinian structuralist contributions Part II: Financial dependency

    Rev. Keynesian Econ.

    (2018)
  • J. Eatwell

    Competition

  • P. Garegnani

    The Classical Theory of Wages and the Role of Demand Schedules in the Determination of Relative Prices

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1983)
  • C. Gehrke

    Ricardo's discovery of comparative advantage revisited: a critique of Ruffin's account

    Eur. J. History Econ. Thought

    (2015)
  • C. Gehrke

    Foreign trade, international values, and gains from trade: Ricardo, Pennington, Whewell, and John Stuart Mill

  • F.D. Graham

    The Theory of International Values

    (1948)
  • P. Krugman

    Ricardo's difficult idea: why intellectuals don't understand comparative advantage

  • P. Krugman et al.

    International Trade: Theory and Policy

    (2018)
  • S. Metcalfe

    Comparative Advantage

  • Cited by (9)

    • Effective way to measure the specialization levels of an economy in the era of global value chains

      2022, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Researchers should consider the labor market, production, R&D, foreign direct investment, impact on the local market, industry-university-government relationships, technological trajectories, insertion of small and medium enterprises, etc. This is because the indexes are simply a reflection of decisions made by policymakers about these issues, in order to achieve the desired objective in a geostrategic context (Moreno-Brieva and Merino-Moreno, 2020, 2021), where the role of multinational companies and their absolute advantages—conditioned by production costs—are relevant to dominate a global value chain despite geographic fragmentation (Garbellini, 2021; Machado and Trigg, 2021). Finally, as suggested by Pleticha (2021), more emerging countries should be included in the databases related to value-added.

    • Comparative advantage

      2023, Dictionary of Ecological Economics: Terms for the New Millennium
    View all citing articles on Scopus

    The authors would like to thank José Bruno Fevereiro, Santiago Gahn, and Guilherme Morlin for reading a previous draft of this paper and making suggestions. We are also thankful for helpful and challenging comments from two anonymous referees. All remaining errors are our own.

    View full text