Skip to main content
Log in

Learning under uncertainty with multiple priors: experimental investigation

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We run an experiment to compare belief formation and learning under ambiguity and under compound risk at the individual level. We estimate a four-type mixture model assuming that, for each type of uncertainty, subjects may either learn according to Bayes’ Rule or learn according to a multiple priors model of learning. Our results indicate that majority of subjects are Bayesian, both under compound risk and under ambiguity, while the second most frequent type are subjects that are Bayesian under compound risk but who use a multiple priors model of learning under ambiguity. In addition, we find strong evidence against a common assumption that participants’ initial beliefs (and priors) are consistent with information provided about the uncertain process.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. While the gap between the certain amounts for Option A (Fig. 2) may seem large, it is worth noting that in the experiment subjects will see two signals about each urn with each signal consisting of three draws with replacement. For context, the indifference point for a risk neutral subject who considers objective composition of the C urn, who follows Bayes’ rule, and who sees six successes would increase by approximately $6.

  2. For robustness, we augment the current data set with data from Moreno & Rosokha (2016) that includes 113 participants. Results are presented in Online Appendix B.

  3. The random lottery incentive mechanism has several known issues when it comes to the elicitation of preferences for risk and uncertainty. For example, Freeman et al. (2019) show that when compensated based on one randomly selected lottery from a list, subjects are more likely to select the sure payment over risky lottery as compared to the case when facing only one payoff-relevant decision. Harrison et al. (2015) show that the random lottery incentive mechanism may in itself lead to violations of the reduction of compound lotteries. However, a between-subject design with each subject facing only one, payoff-relevant decision would not be able to address whether the same subject learns differently under compound risk or under ambiguity.

  4. This corresponds to the same ranges of p0(B) and p0(W) in the Simplex priors example.

  5. Our specification is therefore a mixture model at the subject level with a “correlated random coefficients” assumption about individual specific parameters. It is therefore more akin to Conte et al. (2011) than Harrison and Rutström (2009) in two important ways: firstly, the mixing is at the subject level rather than the decision level, and secondly, parameters 𝜃i are assumed to be random draws, rather than deterministic functions of observable characteristics. Our estimation differs from Conte et al. (2011) in only three notable ways: (i) we consider different behavioral models, hence our likelihood functions are different; (ii) where Conte et al. (2011) has two behavioral types, we have four; and (iii) we use Bayesian techniques instead of (simulated) maximum likelihood.

  6. For robustness, we carry out the analyses from above while restricting the priors (and posteriors) to follow Beta distribution truncated to [.25,.75]. Results are presented in Tables B-1 and B-3 of Online Appendix B. We find the main results are quantitatively similar —the proportion of AB-CB type is approximately 60%, and the proportion of AM-CB type is approximately 29%— though individual preference and learning parameters change.

  7. Harrison and Rutström (2009), Conte et al. (2011), and Harrison et al. (2015), for example, make this assumption. Ferecatu and Önçüler (2016) on the other hand assumes choice precision is subject-specific.

References

  • Abdellaoui, M., Klibanoff, P., & Placido, L. (2015). Experiments on compound risk in relation to simple risk and to ambiguity. Management Science, 61(6), 1306–1322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillon, A., Bleichrodt, H., Keskin, U., l’Haridon, O., & Li, C. (2013). Learning under ambiguity: An experiment using initial public offerings on a stock market. Economics Working Paper Archive (University of Rennes 1 & University of Caen), Center for Research in Economics and Management (CREM), University of Rennes, 1.

  • Bossaerts, P., Ghirardato, P., Guarnaschelli, S., & Zame, W.R. (2010). Ambiguity in asset markets: Theory and experiment. The Review of Financial Studies, 23(4), 1325–1359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buser, T., Gerhards, L., & Van Der Weele, J. (2018). Responsiveness to feedback as a personal trait. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 56(2), 165–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chew, S.H., Miao, B., & Zhong, S. (2017). Partial Ambiguity. Econometrica, 85(4), 1239–1260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M., Gilboa, I., Jaffray, J.-Y., & Schmeidler, D. (2000). An experimental study of updating ambiguous beliefs. Risk, Decision and Policy, 5(2), 123–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conte, A., Hey, J.D., & Moffatt, P.G. (2011). Mixture models of choice under risk. Journal of Econometrics, 162(1), 79–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coutts, A. (2019). Good news and bad news are still news: Experimental evidence on belief updating. Experimental Economics, 22(2), 369–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dean, M., & Ortoleva, P. (2015). Is it all connected? a testing ground for unified theories of behavioral economics phenomena. Working Paper.

  • Dominiak, A., Dürsch, P., & Lefort, J-P (2012). A dynamic ellsberg urn experiment. Games and Economic Behavior, 75(2), 625–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • El-Gamal, M.A., & Grether, D.M. (1995). Are people bayesian? uncovering behavioral strategies. Journal of the American statistical Association, 1137–1145.

  • Ellsberg, D. (November 1961). Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75(4), 643–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G., & Schneider, M. (October 2007). Learning under ambiguity. The Review of Economic Studies, 74(4), 1275–1303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G., & Schneider, M. (2010). Ambiguity and asset markets. Working Paper 16181, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Ert, E., & Trautmann, S.T. (2014). Sampling experience reverses preferences for ambiguity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 49(1), 31–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferecatu, A., & Önçüler, A. (2016). Heterogeneous risk and time preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 53(1), 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, D.J., Halevy, Y., & Kneeland, T. (2019). Eliciting risk preferences using choice lists. Quantitative Economics, 10(1), 217–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilboa, I., & Schmeidler, D. (1989). Maxmin expected utility with non-unique prior. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 18.

  • Gilboa, I., & Schmeidler, D. (1993). Updating ambiguous beliefs. Journal of economic theory, 59(1), 33–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halevy, Y. (2007). Ellsberg revisited: An experimental study. Econometrica, 75(2), 503–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G.W., & Cox, J.C. (2008). Risk aversion in experiments Vol. 12. Emerald Group Pub Ltd.

  • Harrison, G.W., & Elisabet Rutström, E. (2008). Risk aversion in the laboratory. In Risk aversion in experiments (pp. 41–196). Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

  • Harrison, G.W., Martínez-Correa, J., & Swarthout, J.T. (2015). Reduction of compound lotteries with objective probabilities: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 119, 32–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G.W., & Rutström, E.E. (2009). Expected utility theory and prospect theory: One wedding and a decent funeral. Experimental economics, 12 (2), 133–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C.A., & Laury, S.K. (December 2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. The American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1973). On the psychology of prediction. Psychological review, 80(4), 237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1921). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. University of Chicago Press.

  • Moreno, O.M., & Rosokha, Y. (2016). Learning under compound risk vs. learning under ambiguity–an experiment. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 53 (2-3), 137–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prokosheva, S. (2016). Comparing decisions under compound risk and ambiguity: The importance of cognitive skills. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 64, 94–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qiu, J., & Weitzel, U. (2013). Experimental evidence on valuation and learning with multiple priors. SSRN Scholarly Paper, Social Science Research Network.

  • Qiu, J., & Weitzel, U. (2016). Experimental evidence on valuation with multiple priors. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 53(1), 55–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savage, L.J. (1954). The foundations of statistics. Wiley.

  • Stahl, D.O. (2014). Heterogeneity of ambiguity preferences. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(4), 609–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcox, N.T. (2011). Stochastically more risk averse:’A contextual theory of stochastic discrete choice under risk. Journal of Econometrics, 162(1), 89–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yaroslav Rosokha.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This paper benefited from discussions and comments from Ernan Haruvy, Othon Moreno, Dale Stahl, as well as from workshop participants at the 2012 North American ESA meetings, the 2014 Annual Informs Meetings, and seminar participants at the University of Texas and Purdue University. This work was supported by a grant from the Russell Sage Foundation.

Electronic supplementary material

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bland, J.R., Rosokha, Y. Learning under uncertainty with multiple priors: experimental investigation. J Risk Uncertain 62, 157–176 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-021-09351-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-021-09351-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation