Skip to main content
Log in

Weighted scoring elections: is Borda best?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 26 November 2021

This article has been updated

Abstract

Weighted scoring rules, perhaps the most common procedures for multi-candidate, single-winner elections, are defined by score vectors, of which the Borda Count is the best known example. The concept of Borda dominance identifies candidates who cannot win under any score vector; we assess its usefulness in the context of single-winner elections. We propose several families of score vectors that can accommodate any number of candidates, asking whether any of them can improve on Borda Count. Using large-scale simulation, we compare score vectors on Condorcet efficiency, or ability to find a Condorcet winner when one exists, on resilience to ballot truncation, and on ability to maximize the Copeland score using both complete and uniformly truncated ballots. Borda performs well on criteria related to Condorcet winner and Copeland score but, depending on the preference model, may not be optimal. Convex score vectors are the most resilient to ballot truncation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

References

  • Ayadi M, Ben Amor N, Lang J, Peters D (2019) Single transferable vote: Incomplete knowledge and communication issues. In: AAMAS 19: Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems, International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, pp 1288–1296

  • Ayadi M, Ben Amor N, Lang J (2020) Approximating voting rules from truncated ballots. arXiv:2002.06009, 13 February 2020

  • Benoit J-P (1992) Scoring reversals: a major league dilemma. Soc Choice Welf 9:89–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentert M, Skowron P (2019) comparing election methods where each voter ranks only few candidates. arXiv:1901.10848, 30 January 2019

  • Black D (1958) Theory of committees and elections. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brams SJ (1982) The AMS nominating system is vulnerable to truncation of preferences. Not AMS 29:136–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Cervone DP, Gehrlein WV, Zwicker WS (2005) Which scoring rule maximizes Condorcet efficiency under IAC? Theory Decis 58(2):145–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cullinan J, Hsiao SK, Polett D (2014) A Borda count for partially ordered ballots. Soc Choice Welf 42:913–926

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dogan O, Giritligil AE (2014) Implementing the Borda outcome via truncated scoring rules: a computational study. Public Choice 159:83–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emerson P (2013) The original Borda count and partial voting. Soc Choice Welf 40:353–358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filmus Y, Oren J (2014) Efficient voting via the top-\(k\) elicitation scheme: a probabilistic approach. In: EC 14: Proceedings of the Fifteenth ACM Conference on economics and computation, ACM, pp 295–312

  • Fishburn PC (1981) Inverted orders for monotone scoring rules. Discrete Appl Math 3:27–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn PC (1964) Decision and value theory. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn PC (1974) Paradoxes of voting. Am Polit Sci Rev 68:537–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn PC, Gehrlein W (1978) Condorcet paradox and anonymous preference profiles. Public Choice 26:1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn PC, Brams SJ (1983) Paradoxes of preferential voting. Math Mag 56:207–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fraenkel J, Grofman B (2014) The Borda count and its real world alternatives: comparing scoring rules in Nauru and Slovenia. Aust J Polit Sci 49:186–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV (2003) Coincidence probabilities for simple majority and positional voting rules. In: Sertel MR, Koray S (eds) Advances in economic design. Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp 53–63

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein WV, Fishburn PC (1978) Coincidence probabilities for simple majority and positional voting rules. Soc Sci Res 7:272–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillett R (1977) Collective indecision. Behav Sci 22:383–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbaud GT (1952) Les théories de l’intérêt général et le problème logique de l’agréation. Écon Appl 5:501–584

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalech M, Kraus S, Kaminka GA, Goldman CV (2011) Practical voting rules with partial information. Auton Agents Multi-Agent Syst 22:151–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamiya H, Orlik P, Takemura A, Terao H (2006) Arrangements and ranking patterns. Ann Combin 10:219–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamwa E (2021) To what extent does the model of processing sincere incomplete rankings affect the likelihood of the truncation paradox? hal-02879390v2, Université des Antilles

  • Kilgour DM, Grégoire J-Ch, Foley AM (2020) The prevalence and consequences of ballot truncation in ranked-choice elections. Public Choice 184(1):197–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lackner M (2014) Incomplete preferences in single-peaked electorates. In: AAAI-14, Proceedings of the Twenty-Eighth AAAI Conference on artificial intelligence, pp 742–748

  • Lepelley D (1993) On the probability of electing the Condorcet loser. Math Soc Sci 25(2):105–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B, Peña T (2015a) Positional voting systems generated by cumulative standings functions. Group Decis Negot 24:777–801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llamazares B, Peña T (2015b) Scoring rules and social choice properties: some characterizations. Theory Decis 78:429–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marchant T (2001) The probability of ties with scoring methods: Some results. Soc Choice Welf 18:709–735

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margolis H (1977) Probability of a tie election. Public Choice 31:135–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McIntee TJ, Saari DG (2017) Likelihood of voting outcomes with generalized IAC probabilities. Math Soc Sci 87:1–10

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merlin V, Tataru M, Valognes F (2000) On the probability that all decision rules select the same winner. J Math Econ 33:183–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyers A, Orrison ME, Townsend J, Wolff S, Wu A (2014) Generalized Condorcet winners. Soc Choice Welf 43:11–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montes I, Rademalker M, Pérez-Fernández R, De Baets B (2020) A correspondence between voting procedures and stochastic orderings. Eur J Oper Res 285:977–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narodytska N, Walsh T (2014) The computational impact of partial votes on strategic voting. arXiv:1405.7714

  • Nurmi H, Salonen H (2008) More Borda count variations of project assessment. AUCO Czech Econ Rev 2:109–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Oren J, Flimus Y, Boutilier C (2013) Efficient vote elicitation under candidate uncertainty. In: IJCAI-13: Proceedings of the Twenty-Third International Joint Conference on artificial intelligence, AAAI Press, pp 309–316

  • Pérez-Fernández R, De Baets B (2019) The superdominance relation, the positional winner, and more missing links between Borda and Condorcet. J Theoret Polit 31:46–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reilly B (2002) Social choice in the South Seas: electoral innovation and the Borda count in the Pacific Island countries. Int Polit Sci Rev 23:355–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1984) The ultimate of chaos resulting from weighted voting systems. Adv Appl Math 5:286–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1992) Millions of election outcomes from a single profile. Soc Choice Welf 9:277–306

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1995) Basic geometry of voting. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1999) Explaining all three-alternative voting outcomes. J Econ Theory 87(2):313–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2000) Mathematical structure of voting paradoxes. Econ Theory 15:1–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG, McIntee TJ (2013) Connecting pairwise and positional election outcomes. Math Soc Choice 66:140–151

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein WE, Mizzi PJ, Pfaffenberger RC (1994) A stochastic dominance analysis of ranked voting systems with scoring. Eur J Oper Res 74:78–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Newenhizen J (1992) The Borda method is most likely to respect the Condorcet principle. Econ Theory 2(1):69–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcox R (2019) Can sports show the way to smarter voting?, May 15, 2019. http://www.deadspin.com/can-sports-show-the-way-to-smarter-voting-1834144248. Accessed 22 Aug 2019

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank two anonymous referees for extensive and insightful comments that helped us to improve the paper. This work was supported by the Canadian Tri-Council Research Support Fund, specifically by the authors’ individual Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada (NSERC) Discovery Grants.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to D. Marc Kilgour.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The original online version of this article was revised due to incorrect Tables 5 and 7. Now, they have been corrected.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kilgour, D.M., Grégoire, JC. & Foley, A.M. Weighted scoring elections: is Borda best?. Soc Choice Welf 58, 365–391 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01347-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01347-6

Navigation