Economic policy uncertainty, value of cash and financial crisis

Quoc Trung Tran (Foreign Trade University, Ho Chi Minh City Campus, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam)

European Journal of Management and Business Economics

ISSN: 2444-8494

Article publication date: 27 July 2021

Issue publication date: 28 February 2023

1781

Abstract

Purpose

This paper investigates the effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash before and after the global financial crisis.

Design/methodology/approach

We investigate the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and value of excess cash based on the valuation model of Fama and French (1998). Baker et al. (2016) news-based index (BBD index) is employed to calculate measures of economic policy uncertainty. Our research sample includes 103,474 observations from 11,000 firms across 19 countries over the period 2004–2016.

Findings

We find that economic policy uncertainty is negatively “positively” related to value of cash in the pre-crisis “post-crisis” period. Moreover, we also document that the positive effect of economic policy uncertainty in the post-crisis period is stronger in financially constrained firms.

Originality/value

While prior studies find a relationship between economic policy uncertainty and cash levels or the effect of firm-level uncertainty on value of cash, this paper shows how economic policy uncertainty as an institutional environment factor affects value of cash. Moreover, it documents that economic policy uncertainty has opposite effects on value of cash before and after the global financial crisis.

研究目的

本研究旨在探討經濟政策不確定性在全球金融危機之前及之後對現金價值的影響。

研究設計/方法/理念

我們基於法馬及佛倫奇(1998) (Fama and French (1998)) 的估值模型,來探討經濟政策不確定性與過剩現金價值的關係。我們採用了貝克等人(2016) (Baker et al. (2016)) 以新聞訊息為基礎的指數 (BBD指數) 、來計算經濟政策不確定性的程度。我們的研究樣本包括橫跨19個國家、涵蓋期為2004年至2016年、取自11,000間公司之103,474個觀察。

研究結果

我們發現經濟政策不確定性與現金價值在危機前時期成負相關,在危機後時期則成正相關。而且,我們也記錄了在危機後時期經濟政策不確定性的正面影響於財務受限的公司會較大的情況。

原創性/價值

過去的研究發現了經濟政策不確定性與現金水平之間存有關係、及企業層面的不確定性對現金價值的影響。唯本研究顯示了經濟政策不確定性作為一機構環境因素,如何影響現金價值;同時,亦記錄了經濟政策不確定性在全球金融危機之前及之後對現金價值會有相反影響的情況。

Keywords

Citation

Tran, Q.T. (2023), "Economic policy uncertainty, value of cash and financial crisis", European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 32 No. 1, pp. 24-46. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJMBE-10-2020-0292

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Quoc Trung Tran

License

Published in European Journal of Management and Business Economics. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Policy making and implementing processes typically result in a large amount of uncertainty in the economy and thus influence corporate financial behavior (Zhang et al., 2015). Recently, the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and corporate liquidity policy has attracted much attention from researchers. Economic policy uncertainty increases precautionary motive for saving cash. Demir and Ersan (2017), Phan et al. (2019) show that economic policy uncertainty is positively related to corporate cash holdings. However, there has been little knowledge about how economic policy uncertainty determines value of cash. In addition, prior studies show that a financial crisis is an exogenous shock to corporate financial decisions through the mechanism of external financial constraint (Tran et al., 2017). Therefore, this paper investigates the effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash before and after the global financial crisis.

When facing high economic policy uncertainty, investors may have two opposite views on corporate cash holdings. On the one hand, they tend to value cash higher because corporate cash holdings become more important for firms' survival and investment. Firms have to struggle to survive or lose their investment opportunities if they fail to have enough cash and their external financing are more expensive due to high uncertainty (External financing channel). On the other hand, investors may recognize that high economic policy uncertainty is an opportunity for corporate managers to save more cash and overinvest in unprofitable projects. Due to the separation of ownership and control, corporate managers tend to use their firms' resources to overinvest in unprofitable projects in order to serve their own benefits. When firms face high uncertainty caused by economic policy, managers take advantage of precautionary reasons to hold more cash and then use it to benefit themselves through overinvestment. Therefore, investors assign lower value to cash (agency cost channel). We argue that in the pre-crisis period, the financial system is in normal condition and thus investors have high incentives to focus more on agency cost channel than external financing channel. As a result, high economic policy uncertainty leads to lower value of cash during the pre-crisis period. However, when the financial system is under crisis, investors tend to concentrate on external financing channel more than agency cost channel. Therefore, economic policy uncertainty positively affects value of cash during the post-crisis period.

Following Drobetz et al. (2010), Kyröläinen et al. (2013), Pinkowitz et al. (2006), we investigate the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and value of excess cash based on the valuation model of Fama and French (1998). Baker et al. (2016) news-based index (BBD index) is employed to calculate measures of economic policy uncertainty. With a sample of 103,474 observations from 11,000 firms across 19 countries over the period 2004–2016, the effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash is negative in the pre-crisis period 2004–2008 but it becomes positive in the post-crisis period 2009–2016. Our robustness checks with a reduced sample, an alternative measure of cash and other measures of economic policy uncertainty also show consistent results. Moreover, we continue to examine how firm-specific financial constraint determines the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and value of cash in the post-crisis period. We use the country-year top and bottom 30th percentiles of Kaplan and Zingales (1997) index, Whited and Wu (2006) index and firm size as criteria to classify observations into sub-samples of financially constrained and unconstrained firms. We find that the positive effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash is stronger in financially constrained firms during the post-crisis period.

This paper has two important contributions to the literature as follows. First, we contribute to the literature of corporate cash holdings. While prior studies find a relationship between economic policy uncertainty and cash levels (Demir and Ersan, 2017; Phan et al., 2019) or the effect of firm-level uncertainty on value of cash (Im et al., 2017), we show how economic policy uncertainty as an institutional environment factor affects value of cash. Second, our research provides a contribution to the literature of financial crisis. The extant literature shows that a financial crisis changes corporate cash holdings (Arslan et al., 2006; Lian et al., 2011; Tran, 2019a), dividend policy (Al-Malkawi et al., 2014; Rhee and Park, 2018), the effects of shareholder rights and creditor rights on dividend policy Tran et al. (2017) and the effect of shareholder rights on cash holdings (Tran, 2020). In this paper, we document that economic policy uncertainty has opposite effects on value of cash before and after the global financial crisis.

The rest of this paper is structured as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature and develops research hypotheses. In Section 3, we design research models following prior studies. Section 4 presents data source and data description. Section 5 shows regression results, robustness checks and additional analysis. Section 6 concludes.

2. Literature review and hypothesis development

The extant literature shows that corporate cash holdings lead to both costs and benefits. Corporate cash holdings are opportunities for managers to expropriate shareholders. Firms need to accumulate cash due to their precautionary motive (Myers and Majluf, 1984; Ozkan and Ozkan, 2004; Phan et al., 2019). Firms hold cash a safety buffer that helps them size profitable investment projects and handle unpredictable contingencies. Bates et al. (2009) find that firms save more cash when facing riskier cash flows. Hugonnier et al. (2014) show that corporate cash holdings are positively related to the uncertainty of capital supply and firms with more cash are more likely to seize emerging investment opportunities. Almeida et al. (2004), Ferreira and Vilela (2004), Kim et al. (2011) also find empirical evidence for precautionary motive of cash holdings. On the other hand, corporate cash holdings lead to agency costs. According to agency theory, corporate managers tend to use cash to serve their own benefits at shareholders' expenses (Jensen, 1986; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007), Dittmar et al. (2003), Jebran et al. (2019), Kalcheva and Lins (2007), La Porta et al. (1998), Pinkowitz et al. (2006) find that weak corporate governance results in high levels of corporate cash holdings.

As a crucial government policy, economic policy generates uncertainty in business environment when it is made and implemented by government agencies. Many prior studies show that economic policy uncertainty determines firm performance and corporate financial decisions. Sum and Fanta (2012) find a long-run positive association between economic policy uncertainty and excess return volatility in the US from 1985 to 2011. Debata and Mahakud (2018) show that the effect of economic policy uncertainty on stock market liquidity is moderate in normal market conditions but it is strong during financial crises. Dash et al. (2021) also document a causal relationship between economic policy uncertainty and stock market liquidity. Besides, Hoque et al. (2019) find that global economic policy uncertainty has a negative impact on the overall stock market and geopolitical risk makes it stronger. Paule-Vianez et al. (2020) show that economic policy uncertainty has a greater effect on return and volatility during recession periods.

In addition, economic policy uncertainty influences a wide range of corporate financial decisions including corporate investment (Kang et al., 2014; Wang et al., 2014, 2017), capital structure Zhang et al. (2015), dividend policy (Attig et al., 2021) and corporate risk-taking (Tran, 2019b). Demir and Ersan (2017) investigate the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and corporate liquidity policy in BRIC countries during the period from 2006 to 2015 and find that firms prefer holding more cash when they face higher uncertainty. Phan et al. (2019) argue that economic policy uncertainty may affect corporate cash holdings in two mechanisms. First, following the real option hypothesis, firms tend to delay investment under high uncertainty and this leads to higher cash holdings. Second, this government policy uncertainty reduces asset returns and thus increases costs of external funds. When firms face high costs of external financing, they are motivated to reserve more cash in order to buffer against unexpected financial shocks and maintain their normal operation. Using a sample of 119,322 observations from 13,981 US firms between 1986 and 2015, they find that there is a positive relationship between economic policy uncertainty and cash reserves. Remarkably, their additional analysis shows that precautionary motive is more effective than investment delay in explaining this positive relationship. Moreover, Im et al. (2017) examine the effects of firm-specific uncertainty and its three components on value of cash in the US market. With a sample of 94,568 firm-years over the period from 1980 to 2015, they also document that firms with higher uncertainty have higher value of cash holdings. However, these prior studies have not fully addressed the effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash across countries.

Furthermore, the extant literature shows that as an exogenous shock, a financial crisis significantly influences corporate liquidity policy. Arslan et al. (2006) show that a financial crisis increases both corporate cash reserves and cash-cash flow sensitivity through its impact on firms' financial constraint. Consistently, Lian et al. (2011) argue that the global financial crisis makes capital markets become less efficient and bank credit dry up; therefore, precautionary motive of cash holdings become more important. Using a sample of 8,663 observations from 1,435 listed firms in China, they find that firms accumulate more cash during the crisis period. However, Tran (2019a) shows that the global financial crisis reduces corporate cash holdings in Vietnam. This can be explained that the amount of cash firms consume is higher than the amount they save due to external financial constraint. Moreover, Chang et al. (2017) also document that value of cash holdings are higher under the impact of the global financial crisis. Motivated by these prior studies, this paper investigates the effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash before and after the financial crisis.

Before the global financial crisis, the financial system operates normally and external funds are highly available to firms. Under this condition, corporate managers are more flexible to conduct corporate liquidity policy. When firms face high economic policy uncertainty, corporate managers may take this opportunity to expropriate shareholders by accumulating more cash (Jensen, 1986; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Recognizing managers' expropriation behavior and highly available external funds to firms, investors assign lower value to firms with higher cash levels. Attig et al. (2021) also find that firms pay dividends as a means to reduce agency costs of equity under high economic policy uncertainty. Drobetz et al. (2010) also show that information asymmetry negatively affects market value of corporate cash holdings. Consequently, we hypothesize that the effect of economic policy uncertainty on cash value is negative in the pre-crisis period.

H1.

Economic policy uncertainty is negatively related to value of cash during the pre-crisis period.

Nevertheless, after the global financial crisis breaks out, firms face severely external financial constraint (Duchin et al., 2010; Flannery et al., 2013; Lian et al., 2011; Roubini, 2007). Under this exogenous shock, high economic policy uncertainty reduces firms' access to credit and increases their costs of external financing more severely. Therefore, firms need more cash to seize emerging investment opportunities and handle unpredictable contingencies. Firms with low cash holdings may not survive through the crisis (Campello et al., 2011; Ivashina and Scharfstein, 2010). Although investors understand that corporate managers may take economic policy uncertainty to expropriate shareholders, they still value firms with more cash higher due to severe external financial constraint. Consequently, we hypothesize that high economic policy uncertainty increases value of cash during the post-crisis period.

H2.

Economic policy uncertainty is positively related to value of cash during the post-crisis period.

3. Research models

In line with prior studies (Drobetz et al., 2010; Frésard and Salva, 2010; Kyröläinen et al., 2013; Pinkowitz et al., 2006), we modify the valuation model of Fama and French (1998) to examine the effects of economic policy uncertainty on value cash as follows.

(1)MVt=α+β1EPU1t×EXCt+β2EXCt+β3EPU1t+β4ENt+β5dENt+β6dENt+1+β7dNAt+β8dNAt+1+β9RDt+β10dRDt+β11dRDt+1+β12INt+β13dINt+β14dINt+1+β15DVt+β16dDVt+β17dDVt+1+β18dMVt+ηC_E+πC_controlEXCt+ϕIndustrydummies+γYeardummies+ε

Where EPU1 is economic policy uncertainty calculated by the average of twelve monthly BBD indices within a fiscal year (Demir and Ersan, 2017). BBD indices are a news-based measure of uncertainty created by government economic policy. They are developed by Baker et al. (2016) and published at http://www.policyuncertainty.com. The original monthly BBD indices are large while the dependent variable is small. This results in small regression coefficients. Hence, before calculating EPU1, we rescale original BBD indices to have a shorter scale ranging from 0 to 100. Higher values of EPU1 indicate higher economic policy uncertainty. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value measured by year-end market capitalization plus book value of debt. EXC is excess cash measured by the difference between actual cash holdings and normal cash holdings predicted by the IV regression in accordance with Appendix 1. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except excess cash are deflated by net assets. In line with Kyröläinen et al. (2013), we employ a vector of country-specific control variables (C_control) including anti-self-dealing index (ASD), revised creditor right index (CRE), rule of law (ROL), private credit (PCRE), market capitalization (MCAP), GDP per capita (GCAP) and GDP growth rate (GGRO). Anti-self-dealing index is a proxy of shareholder protection developed by Djankov et al. (2008). Its higher values imply stronger shareholder rights. Revised creditor right index from Djankov et al. (2007) measures legal protection of creditors. Its higher values imply stronger creditor rights. Rule of law is “the average of the months of April and October of the monthly index” published in International Country Risk Guide between 1982 and 1995. This index ranges from 0 to 10 and its higher values represent more tradition of law and order. In addition, private credit is measured by domestic credit to private sector to GDP ratio. Market capitalization is total market capitalization to GDP ratio. GDP per capita is measured by the natural logarithm of GDP per capita. GDP growth rate is the annual growth of GDP. Macroeconomic information is annually published by World Bank.

Following Kyröläinen et al. (2013), Tran (2019b), we employ pooled OLS regression model to estimate Eqn (1) with two sub-samples of pre-crisis period 2004–2008 and post-crisis period 2009–2016 separately. Standard errors are clustered by firm. The interaction between economic policy uncertainty and excess cash is expected to be negative (positive) in the pre-crisis (post-crisis) period.

4. Research data

To construct the research sample, we use only choose 19 countries whose economic policy uncertainty is available at http://www.policyuncertainty.com. Accounting information of firms incorporated in these countries is collected from Compustat database. Following prior cross-country research (Kyröläinen et al., 2013; Thakur and Kannadhasan, 2019; Tran, 2019b), we eliminate the following firms and observations: (1) firms classified into utilities and financial sectors in accordance with SIC codes; (2) observations without consolidated financial reports; (3) firms with various issues of shares; (4) observations with abnormal information (i.e. negative values of total assets, net income and common equity; (5) observations with missing information and (6) firms contributing fewer than five observations in the research period. The final research sample consists of 103,474 observations from 11,000 unique firms between 2004 and 2016. Although our research sample ends in 2016, we use the data of 2017 to calculate the annual change in variable X in year t + 1(dXt + 1) as shown in Eqn (1). The year 2018 experiences the trade war between US and China is another exogenous shock in the macroeconomic environment. Data of the fiscal year 2019 has not been completely available in Compustat for many countries and it may be affected by the pandemic Covid-19 – a severe shock for the world economy. However, our research only focuses on how the global financial crisis determines the relationship between economic uncertainty and cash value. Therefore, we fail to include the data for the period 2018–2019 in our sample. We winsorize all firm-level variables at the 1st and the 99th percentile [1] to control outlier effects.

Table 1 describes our research sample. Panel A shows that firm value significantly varies from 0.438 to 12.695. Its mean and median are 1.671 and 1.176 respectively. Excess cash also fluctuates over a wide range between −3.866 and 1.784. Although the average of excess cash is negative (−0.098), the median value is positive (0.137). This implies that observations with positive excess cash constitute more than 50% of the research sample. In addition, Panel B reports the distribution of the research sample by year. We find that the annual number of firms increases from 2004 to 2012 and then declines slightly in the following years. Panel C illustrates that the largest industry is Manufacturing with 59,729 observations, followed by Service sector (16,777) and Transportation, communications (6,943). The smallest industry is Construction that contributes only 3,691 firm-years. Besides, Panel D shows that there is an unbalanced distribution of observations by across countries. The largest country is the US with 26,537 observations, followed by Japan (25,280) and China (11,804). These three largest countries account for 61.49% of firm-years in the research sample and they may drive our research results. Therefore, we also present results without them as robustness checks.

5. Research results

5.1 Economic policy uncertainty and value of cash during the pre-crisis and the post-crisis periods

Table 2 show regression results to analyze the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and value of cash during the pre-crisis and the post-crisis periods. We find that economic policy uncertainty is negatively related to value of excess cash in the pre-crisis period. This finding is consistent with Attig et al. (2021), Drobetz et al. (2010). The effect of economic policy uncertainty on cash value relies on investors' views on the role of cash holdings. If investors emphasize on the importance of cash when firms face higher costs of external financing due to high uncertainty, they value cash higher. However, when investors consider high economic policy uncertainty as an opportunity for corporate managers to save more cash for their overinvestment, they value cash lower. Before the global financial crisis, the financial system works normally and thus investors have high incentives to focus on agency cost of cash holdings more than the role of cash holdings in firms' survival and investment.

In addition, we find that economic policy uncertainty is positively associated with value of excess cash during the post-crisis period. In line with Arslan et al. (2006), Chang et al. (2017), Lian et al. (2011), under the impact of the global financial crisis, firms experience server external financial constraint and thus investors focus more on the role of cash reserves in firms' survival and investment.

5.2 Robustness checks

The distribution of our research data shows that the three largest countries including the US, Japan and China constitute 61.49% of observations. Therefore, we present all regression results for a reduced sample without them to ensure that these countries fail to drive our research findings. Table 3 reports that economic policy uncertainty still negatively (positively) affects value of excess cash during the pre-crisis (post-crisis) period.

Moreover, we also replace excess cash by cash level measured by cash holdings to net assets ratio and present regression results for this alternative measure as robustness checks. Table 4 shows that our research findings remain unchanged.

Furthermore, following Demir and Ersan (2017), Tran (2019b), we employ alternative measures of economic policy uncertainty as robustness tests. EPU2 is the weighted average of monthly BBD indices in a fiscal year. Those in the first (last) 6 months are assigned a weight of one (two). EPU3 is also the weighted average; however, but BBD indices from the first to the last quarter of a fiscal year are granted corresponding weights from 1 to 4. Regression results presented in Table 5 show consistent findings.

In addition, our research sample is unbalanced panel data; therefore, we also employ panel data regression methods including fixed effects and random effects as robustness checks. Panel data regression is able to control heterogeneity that is not performed by cross-sectional analysis and reduces the risk of biased results. Table 6 shows that our key findings are still stable in both panel data regression techniques.

5.3 The role of firm-level financial constraint in the post-crisis period

Almeida et al. (2004) find that financially constrained firms tend to save more cash. Chang et al. (2017) document that value of cash is higher in financially constrained firms under the impact of the global financial crisis. Therefore, we continue to investigate how firm-specific financial constraint influences the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and value of cash in the post-crisis period. An observation is defined as financially constrained (unconstrained) if it belongs to the country-year top (bottom) 30th percentile of Kaplan and Zingales (1997) index or Whited and Wu (2006) index or the country-year bottom (top) 30th percentile of firm size.

Table 7 reports regression results to analyze the effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash by financial constraint during the post-crisis period. We find that this positive effect is statistically and economically stronger in financially constrained firms. This finding supports the argument that investors more emphasize on the role of cash holdings in firms' survival and investment due to high external financial constraint in the post-crisis period. Financially constrained firms face much higher financial constraint; therefore, investors assign higher value to corporate cash holdings when they face high economic policy uncertainty.

6. Conclusion

Prior studies show that economic policy uncertainty positively affects corporate cash holdings but they have not fully addressed how economic policy uncertainty determines value of cash. Using a research sample of 103,474 firm-years from 19 countries during the period 2004–2016, we find that economic policy uncertainty is negatively (positively) related to value of cash in the pre-crisis (post-crisis) period. These findings imply that investors pay more attention to agency costs (precautionary motive and transaction motive) than precautionary motive and transaction motive (agency costs) of cash holdings in the pre-crisis (post-crisis) period. Moreover, we also document that the positive effect of economic policy uncertainty in the post-crisis period is stronger in financially constrained firms.

This paper contributes to the literature of corporate cash holdings and financial crisis. While prior studies focus on the effect of economic policy uncertainty on cash levels, we show that economic policy uncertainty also determines value of cash across countries. In addition, we extend the line of research on how a financial crisis affects corporate financial decisions by showing that the effect of economic policy uncertainty on cash value are different before and after the financial crisis. These understandings help investors in their investment decisions under normal economic conditions (before a financial crisis) and in the post-crisis period. Future research may investigate how the Covid-19 pandemic affects the relationship between economic policy uncertainty and value of cash.

Data description

Panel A. Firm-level data
VariablesMeanSD1st quartileMedian3rd quartileMinMax
MVi,t1.6711.6720.8981.1761.1760.43812.695
EXCi,t−0.0981.147−0.6640.1370.713−3.8661.784
LNCi,t−2.3701.191−2.991−2.186−1.546−6.372−0.271
CASi,t0.1580.1530.0500.1120.2130.0020.763
SGRi,t−20.1340.410−0.0290.0640.192−0.6192.769
SIZi,t12.8932.02211.62512.85914.1747.59717.871
CFi,t−0.0720.219−0.1240.0080.054−1.0680.215
NWCi,t0.0110.199−0.0790.0220.127−0.8890.464
CEXi,t0.0470.0520.0130.0300.0600.0000.289
LEVi,t0.5320.2700.3560.5170.6660.0741.891
ENi,t−0.0040.1880.0020.0310.065−1.2170.244
dENi,t0.0040.126−0.0180.0040.024−0.5670.632
dENi,t + 10.0090.123−0.0190.0040.026−0.4440.667
dNAt0.0320.175−0.0320.0310.106−0.7520.567
dNAt + 10.0630.225−0.0330.0290.112−0.4501.308
RDi,t0.0230.0630.0000.0000.0160.0000.427
dRDi,t0.0010.0140.0000.0000.0004−0.0700.074
dRDi,t + 10.0010.0140.0000.0000.0004−0.0700.081
INi,t0.0140.0210.0020.0080.0180.0000.142
dINi,t0.0000.008−0.0010.0000.002−0.0390.036
dINi,t + 10.1060.191−0.0010.0160.138−0.1010.886
DVi,t0.0130.0200.0000.0060.0170.0000.120
dDVi,t0.0010.0100.0000.0000.002−0.0450.048
dDVi,t + 10.0010.0110.0000.0000.002−0.0440.056
dMVi,t0.1941.054−0.1210.0440.289−3.0136.516
Panel B. Annual number of firms
YearNYearNYearNYearN
20045,67720087,87220129,23620168,023
20056,00220098,23820139,015
20067,04720108,70120148,698
20077,45120119,22520158,289
Panel C. Industry distribution
Industry2-Digit SICNIndustry2-Digit SICN
Mineral industries10–145,720Wholesale trade50–515,366
Construction industries15–173,691Retail trade52–595,253
Manufacturing20–3959,729Service industries≥7016,772
Transportation, communications40–486,943
Panel D. Country-level data
CountryNo. obsNo. firmsMVXCALCACAS
Australia4,1654891.849−0.531−2.5990.148
Brazil1,2111461.6680.024−2.4800.135
Canada4,6405331.787−0.633−2.8370.146
Chile540695.353−1.019−2.9960.072
China11,8041,3292.0910.079−2.0800.162
Spain782801.431−0.129−2.7790.095
France3,8353721.3820.111−2.3490.139
UK3,7534341.675−0.298−2.6830.119
Hong Kong843851.3510.215−2.0090.188
India8,4011,0941.516−1.099−3.2210.085
Ireland170221.7480.220−2.2650.170
Italy1,3261481.281−0.070−2.6190.107
Japan25,2802,2011.0700.239−2.0210.174
South Korea5,2835681.048−0.150−2.3590.134
Mexico525581.461−0.055−2.5840.099
Russia254422.623−0.494−2.8190.094
Singapore2,4723031.2050.058−2.0070.180
Sweden1,6532021.926−0.387−2.6080.126
USA26,5372,8252.207−0.003−2.3860.189

Note(s): Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EXC is excess cash. LNC is the natural logarithm of cash holdings to net assets ratio. CAS is cash holdings. SGR is sale growth. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except EXC, LNC and SGR are deflated by net assets

Economic policy uncertainty and value of cash during the pre-crisis and the post-crisis periods

VariablesPre-crisisPost-crisis
(1)(2)(1)(2)
Intercept−0.7679*** (−3.78)−0.7731*** (−3.18)1.4009*** (8.12)1.7236*** (8.57)
EPU1t × EXCi,t −0.0101*** (−6.49) 0.0016** (2.30)
EXCi,t0.1139*** (9.83)−0.0697 (−0.60)0.0778*** (6.68)0.5166*** (5.31)
EPU1t −0.0074*** (−2.70) 0.0034*** (4.04)
ENi,t−2.9430*** (−14.85)−2.9263*** (−14.79)−2.8533*** (−15.63)−2.8327*** (−15.50)
dENi,t1.3301*** (8.84)1.3178*** (8.76)1.0873*** (10.27)1.0744*** (10.13)
dENi,t + 1−0.5107*** (−3.36)−0.5044*** (−3.32)−0.3680*** (−2.98)−0.3697*** (−2.99)
dNAi,t1.0569*** (13.59)1.0832*** (13.93)0.8138*** (12.82)0.7960*** (12.51)
dNAi,t + 11.2445*** (20.15)1.2476*** (20.24)0.8700*** (16.25)0.8798*** (16.38)
RDi,t4.1138*** (8.54)4.0423*** (8.29)5.2713*** (13.25)5.2740*** (13.20)
dRDi,t3.9851*** (3.26)3.9071*** (3.19)6.2545*** (7.49)6.2472*** (7.48)
dRDi,t + 111.0283*** (10.64)10.6899*** (10.29)11.2295*** (13.06)11.2498*** (13.11)
INi,t14.3206*** (9.49)14.3703*** (9.53)11.8979*** (10.78)11.8808*** (10.68)
dINi,t−15.2841*** (−7.08)−15.0962*** (−6.98)−16.0610*** (−11.66)−16.0155*** (−11.61)
dINi,t + 1−0.5213*** (−6.43)−0.5201*** (−6.42)−0.0567 (−0.90)−0.1093* (−1.72)
DVi,t15.7008*** (18.14)15.6627*** (17.97)22.2930*** (23.64)22.0210*** (23.34)
dDVi,t0.1562 (0.15)0.3695 (0.35)−2.9837*** (−3.51)−2.8222*** (−3.30)
dDVi,t + 113.5334*** (12.13)13.7227*** (12.30)15.6708*** (17.58)15.6262*** (17.48)
dMVi,t−0.1129*** (−5.97)−0.1106*** (−5.84)0.0135 (0.66)0.0137 (0.66)
ASD0.7168*** (6.30)0.6296*** (5.58)0.8976*** (9.32)0.8525*** (9.11)
CRE−0.1087*** (−5.27)−0.1096*** (−5.11)−0.1080*** (−5.77)−0.0853*** (−4.50)
ROL0.0353 (1.06)0.0286 (0.83)0.0709*** (2.68)0.0337 (1.22)
PCREt−0.0046*** (−7.87)−0.0047*** (−7.87)−0.0014*** (−2.93)−0.0022*** (−4.56)
MCAPt0.0001 (0.33)0.0001 (0.43)−0.0002* (−1.71)−0.0002 (−1.56)
GCAPt0.1873*** (10.68)0.2144*** (10.13)−0.0614*** (−4.02)−0.0907*** (−5.18)
GGROt0.0609*** (8.90)0.0703*** (8.93)0.0206*** (4.64)0.0160*** (3.58)
ASD × EXCi,t −0.0359 (−0.42) 0.1087 (1.37)
CRE × EXCi,t 0.0200 (1.16) 0.0246 (1.41)
ROL × EXCi,t −0.0260 (−0.93) −0.0483** (−2.36)
PCREt × EXCi,t −0.0010*** (−2.61) −0.0011*** (−3.13)
MCAPt × EXCi,t 0.0002 (1.25) 0.0002** (2.29)
GCAPt × EXCi,t 0.0372*** (3.20) −0.0457*** (−4.52)
GGROt × EXCi,t −0.0005 (−0.12) −0.0077 (−3.21)
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
R20.39020.39270.28540.2880
F-statistics110.80***91.22***102.28***84.52***
Breusch-Pagan Chi-squared33,064.96***33,344.10***31,945.53***32,928.02***
N34,04934,04969,42569,425

Note(s): The dependent variable is MVt. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EPU1 is economic policy uncertainty. EXC is excess cash. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except EXC are deflated by net assets. ASD is anti-self-dealing index. CRE is revised creditor right index. ROL is rule of law. PCRE is private credit. MCAP is market capitalization. GCAP is GDP per capita. GGRO is GDP growth rate. * is significant at 10%. ** is significant at 5%. *** is significant at 1%. t-statistics are in parentheses

Robustness checks with the reduced sample

VariablesPre-crisisPost-crisis
(1)(2)(1)(2)
Intercept1.2425*** (4.81)1.4178*** (5.21)1.4706*** (6.58)2.3417*** (9.55)
EPU1t × EXCi,t −0.0122*** (−4.79) 0.0054*** (3.89)
EXCi,t0.1278*** (7.40)0.2248 (1.47)0.0592*** (3.18)0.9074*** (5.86)
EPU1t −0.0102** (−2.12) −0.0121*** (−6.14)
ENi,t−2.6538*** (−8.16)−2.6053*** (−8.00)−2.6765*** (−9.11)−2.6248*** (−8.95)
dENi,t0.9581*** (3.36)0.9346*** (3.28)1.0985*** (7.45)1.0750*** (7.32)
dENi,t + 1−0.6685*** (−2.57)−0.6575** (−2.52)−0.5362*** (−3.00)−0.5428*** (−3.03)
dNAi,t0.9570*** (8.10)0.9628*** (8.15)0.6806*** (7.34)0.6866*** (7.49)
dNAi,t + 10.8626*** (8.71)0.8515*** (8.64)0.6865*** (8.41)0.6925*** (8.58)
RDi,t3.3936*** (3.94)3.3162*** (3.76)5.9783*** (8.30)5.9152*** (8.19)
dRDi,t1.1584 (0.57)1.1948 (0.58)2.7091** (2.26)2.9749** (2.48)
dRDi,t + 19.2341*** (6.03)9.0433*** (5.89)9.1341*** (6.93)9.1362*** (6.93)
INi,t12.5423*** (4.67)12.5549*** (4.67)5.0765*** (3.48)5.7351*** (3.95)
dINi,t−21.1116*** (−5.11)−20.9247*** (−5.04)−10.0955*** (−5.71)−9.8230*** (−5.56)
dINi,t + 1−0.1411 (−1.08)−0.1450 (−1.10)−0.2479** (−2.49)−0.2733*** (−2.71)
DVi,t16.6435*** (13.81)16.7087*** (13.76)24.8128*** (18.26)24.4560*** (18.07)
dDVi,t−0.5826 (−0.39)−0.6645 (−0.44)−2.5125** (−2.16)−2.1892* (−1.91)
dDVi,t + 112.6141*** (8.09)12.5188*** (8.06)17.4153*** (14.37)17.2607*** (14.38)
dMVi,t−0.0254 (−0.56)−0.0233 (−0.52)0.0508 (1.35)0.0459 (1.24)
ASD0.6555*** (4.88)0.5254*** (4.06)−0.0949 (−0.76)0.2404* (1.94)
CRE−0.1251*** (−4.93)−0.1339*** (−4.93)0.0689** (2.10)−0.0480 (−1.44)
ROL−0.1489*** (−2.67)−0.1479** (−2.53)−0.2067*** (−5.66)−0.1962*** (−4.81)
PCREt0.0004 (0.45)0.0007 (0.81)−0.0052*** (−3.43)−0.0022* (−1.68)
MCAPt−0.0001 (−0.37)0.0000 (0.09)0.0002 (1.08)0.0001 (0.37)
GCAPt−0.0425* (−1.80)−0.0315 (−1.15)0.0025 (0.08)−0.0851*** (−2.92)
GGROt−0.0069 (−0.64)−0.0033 (−0.29)−0.0129* (−1.79)−0.0154** (−2.26)
ASD × EXCi,t 0.0271 (0.27) 0.2931*** (3.59)
CRE × EXCi,t −0.0137 (−0.66) −0.1137*** (−5.20)
ROL × EXCi,t 0.0184 (0.37) −0.0097 (−0.39)
PCREt × EXCi,t 0.0003 (0.40) 0.0072*** (5.46)
MCAPt × EXCi,t 0.0002 (1.56) −0.0006*** (−4.66)
GCAPt × EXCi,t −0.0016 (−0.09) −0.1718*** (−6.23)
GGROt × EXCi,t −0.0038 (−0.62) 0.0208*** (4.64)
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes
Year fixed effects Yes Yes
R20.28040.28410.19350.2075
F-statistics33.13***29.52***31.37***27.26***
Breusch-Pagan Chi-squared6,373.70***6,448.94***9,325.07***12,868.09***
N9,9309,93029,92329,923

Note(s): The dependent variable is MVt. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EPU1 is economic policy uncertainty. EXC is excess cash. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except EXC are deflated by net assets. ASD is anti-self-dealing index. CRE is revised creditor right index. ROL is rule of law. PCRE is private credit. MCAP is market capitalization. GCAP is GDP per capita. GGRO is GDP growth rate. * is significant at 10%. ** is significant at 5%. *** is significant at 1%. t-statistics are in parentheses

Robustness checks with cash level

VariablesPre-crisisPost-crisis
(1)(2)(1)(2)
Intercept−0.8788*** (−4.36)0.0467 (0.21)1.1102*** (6.52)0.7626*** (4.13)
EPU1t × CASi,t −0.0782*** (−5.01) 0.0166** (2.37)
CASi,t1.5273*** (11.06)−4.3714*** (−2.98)1.3109*** (12.66)7.6894*** (5.69)
EPU1t 0.0058* (1.73) −0.0012 (−0.87)
ENi,t−2.8072*** (−14.20)−2.7647*** (−14.00)−2.7396*** (−15.15)−2.7535*** (−15.22)
dENi,t1.2413*** (8.21)1.2184*** (8.04)1.0386*** (9.83)1.0260*** (9.76)
dENi,t + 1−0.4042*** (−2.66)−0.3917*** (−2.59)−0.2706** (−2.21)−0.2869** (−2.34)
dNAi,t1.1700*** (14.79)1.1827*** (15.03)0.9249*** (14.55)0.9341*** (14.73)
dNAi,t + 11.1328*** (18.27)1.1275*** (18.16)0.7753*** (14.23)0.7836*** (14.43)
RDi,t3.1174*** (6.04)3.1841*** (6.03)4.3938*** (10.58)4.5600*** (10.77)
dRDi,t3.9015*** (3.15)3.8017*** (3.08)6.3842*** (7.59)6.2738*** (7.51)
dRDi,t + 19.7002*** (9.23)8.7791*** (8.37)10.4447*** (12.05)10.6216*** (12.28)
INi,t16.2301*** (10.59)16.3395*** (10.69)13.6422*** (12.44)13.8701*** (12.63)
dINi,t−15.6201*** (−7.22)−15.6242*** (−7.22)−16.4708*** (−11.98)−16.2816*** (−11.94)
dINi,t + 1−0.3207*** (−4.05)−0.3265*** (−4.12)0.1396** (2.14)0.0842 (1.29)
DVi,t15.4345*** (17.87)15.4594*** (17.84)21.8440*** (23.38)21.5485*** (23.50)
dDVi,t−0.1205 (−0.12)−0.2352 (−0.23)−3.2416*** (−3.85)−3.1778*** (−3.79)
dDVi,t + 112.9624*** (11.67)13.1063*** (11.92)15.0488*** (17.14)14.7940*** (16.91)
dMVi,t−0.1087*** (−5.79)−0.1039*** (−5.55)0.0123 (0.60)0.0125 (0.61)
ASD0.5600*** (5.01)0.8737*** (6.09)0.8401*** (8.76)0.5579*** (3.94)
CRE−0.1120*** (−5.47)−0.1766*** (−6.01)−0.1045*** (−5.57)−0.0692** (−2.43)
ROL0.0215 (0.65)0.0536 (1.15)0.0743*** (2.84)0.0441 (1.22)
PCREt−0.0039*** (−6.85)−0.0017** (−2.34)−0.0011** (−2.40)−0.0013** (−2.04)
MCAPt0.0001 (0.42)0.0002 (1.16)−0.0002* (−1.93)0.0001 (0.31)
GCAPt0.1742*** (10.16)0.0629*** (2.75)−0.0604*** (−4.00)0.0118 (0.68)
GGROt0.0570*** (8.43)0.0128 (1.41)0.0202*** (4.59)0.0082 (1.63)
ASD × EXCi,t −2.7630*** (−2.87) 1.5501** (2.00)
CRE × EXCi,t 0.3902* (1.82) −0.1220 (−0.71)
ROL × EXCi,t −0.4344 (−1.53) 0.0331 (0.14)
PCREt × EXCi,t −0.0147*** (−3.42) −0.0033 (−0.97)
MCAPt × EXCi,t −0.0006 (−0.60) −0.0012* (−1.89)
GCAPt × EXCi,t 0.8209*** (5.74) −0.7007*** (−5.62)
GGROt × EXCi,t 0.3439*** (6.95) 0.0405** (2.00)
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes
Year fixed effects Yes Yes
R20.39980.40570.29270.2978
F-statistics111.86***95.77***103.54***87.46***
Breusch-Pagan Chi-squared37,059.57***37,588.59***34,537.10***35,337.27***
N34,04934,04969,42569,425

Note(s): The dependent variable is MVt. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EPU1 is economic policy uncertainty. CAS is cash holdings. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except CAS are deflated by net assets. ASD is anti-self-dealing index. CRE is revised creditor right index. ROL is rule of law. PCRE is private credit. MCAP is market capitalization. GCAP is GDP per capita. GGRO is GDP growth rate. * is significant at 10%. ** is significant at 5%. *** is significant at 1%. t-statistics are in parentheses

Robustness checks with alternative measures of economic policy uncertainty

VariablesPre-crisisPost-crisis
EP_uncertainty is EPU2EP_uncertainty is EPU3EP_uncertainty is EPU2EP_uncertainty is EPU3
Intercept−0.7487*** (−3.06)−0.7397*** (−3.04)1.7836*** (8.89)1.7265*** (8.59)
EP_uncertaintyt × EXCi,t−0.0087*** (−6.43)−0.0091*** (−6.47)0.0029*** (3.63)0.0013* (1.91)
EXCi,t−0.0599 (−0.50)−0.0425 (−0.36)0.4725*** (4.89)0.5299*** (5.45)
EP_uncertaintyt−0.0031 (−1.27)−0.0032 (−1.22)0.0021** (2.23)0.0034*** (4.07)
ENi,t−2.9303*** (−14.81)−2.9308*** (−14.81)−2.8302*** (−15.48)−2.8327*** (−15.49)
dENi,t1.3205*** (8.77)1.3206*** (8.77)1.0742*** (10.13)1.0743*** (10.13)
dENi,t + 1−0.5059*** (−3.33)−0.5060*** (−3.33)−0.3696*** (−2.99)−0.3698*** (−2.99)
dNAi,t1.0817*** (13.92)1.0818*** (13.92)0.7978*** (12.55)0.7962*** (12.52)
dNAi,t + 11.2501*** (20.27)1.2504*** (20.28)0.8797*** (16.38)0.8797*** (16.37)
RDi,t4.0421*** (8.28)4.0425*** (8.29)5.2861*** (13.24)5.2753*** (13.20)
dRDi,t3.9078*** (3.19)3.9055*** (3.19)6.2629*** (7.50)6.2464*** (7.48)
dRDi,t + 110.7147*** (10.31)10.7104*** (10.30)11.2443*** (13.10)11.2508*** (13.11)
INi,t14.3359*** (9.50)14.3360*** (9.49)11.9682*** (10.77)11.8894*** (10.70)
dINi,t−15.0583*** (−6.96)−15.0627*** (−6.96)−16.0101*** (−11.61)−16.0270*** (−11.62)
dINi,t + 1−0.5224*** (−6.44)−0.5221*** (−6.44)−0.1036 (−1.63)−0.1082* (−1.70)
DVi,t15.6800*** (17.98)15.6806*** (17.99)22.0104*** (23.33)22.0191*** (23.33)
dDVi,t0.3682 (0.35)0.3713 (0.35)−2.7972*** (−3.28)−2.8249*** (−3.31)
dDVi,t + 113.7416*** (12.32)13.7467*** (12.32)15.6480*** (17.51)15.6183*** (17.47)
dMVi,t−0.1117*** (−5.91)−0.1118*** (−5.92)0.0129 (0.62)0.0137 (0.66)
ASD0.6688*** (5.89)0.6713*** (5.90)0.8881*** (9.47)0.8552*** (9.15)
CRE−0.1071*** (−5.01)−0.1071*** (−5.01)−0.0942*** (−4.98)−0.0860*** (−4.54)
ROL0.0238 (0.69)0.0216 (0.63)0.0372 (1.34)0.0337 (1.22)
PCREt−0.0047*** (−7.94)−0.0047*** (−7.97)−0.0020*** (−4.16)−0.0022*** (−4.52)
MCAPt0.0000 (0.28)0.0000 (0.28)−0.0002 (−1.63)−0.0002 (−1.55)
GCAPt0.2058*** (9.85)0.2049*** (9.88)−0.0965*** (−5.52)−0.0910*** (−5.20)
GGROt0.0662***0.0660***0.0150***0.0162*** (3.61)
(8.48)(8.49)(3.34)
ASD × EXCi,t−0.0254 (−0.30)−0.0191 (−0.22)0.0984 (1.24)0.1156 (1.45)
CRE × EXCi,t0.0216 (1.26)0.0221 (1.29)0.0284* (1.65)0.0227 (1.29)
ROL × EXCi,t−0.0216 (−0.80)−0.0239 (−0.88)−0.0475** (−2.32)−0.0475** (−2.33)
PCREt × EXCi,t−0.0011*** (−2.76)−0.0011*** (−2.83)−0.0012*** (−3.40)−0.0011*** (−3.02)
MCAPt × EXCi,t0.0002 (1.24)0.0002 (1.20)0.0002** (2.35)0.0002** (2.27)
GCAPt × EXCi,t0.0351*** (3.01)0.0336*** (2.89)−0.0438*** (−4.38)−0.0467*** (−4.61)
GGROt × EXCi,t−0.0017 (−0.38)−0.0024 (−0.54)−0.0067*** (−2.78)−0.0079*** (−3.31)
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
R20.39250.39250.28800.2880
F-statistics91.15***91.11***84.61***84.55***
Breusch-Pagan Chi-squared33,288.96***33,279.44***32,952.45***32,942.90***
N34,04934,04969,42569,425

Note(s): The dependent variable is MVt. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EP_uncertainty is economic policy uncertainty. EPU2 and EPU3 are alternative measures of economic policy uncertainty. EXC is excess cash. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except EXC are deflated by net assets. ASD is anti-self-dealing index. CRE is revised creditor right index. ROL is rule of law. PCRE is private credit. MCAP is market capitalization. GCAP is GDP per capita. GGRO is GDP growth rate. * is significant at 10%. ** is significant at 5%. *** is significant at 1%. t-statistics are in parentheses

Robustness checks with panel data regression

VariablesFixed effectsRandom effects
Pre-crisisPost-crisisPre-crisisPost-crisis
Intercept−5.2584*** (−5.97)−0.3837 (−0.52)−1.2984*** (−5.74)1.6700*** (10.06)
EPU1t × CASi,t−0.0075*** (−4.33)0.0006** (2.23)−0.0081*** (−5.36)0.0004** (2.27)
CASi,t−0.0085*** (−3.79)−0.0028*** (−4.34)−0.0055*** (−2.77)−0.0015** (−2.23)
EPU1t−0.5432*** (−2.75)0.0487 (0.58)−0.2302* (−1.88)0.1382* (1.94)
ENi,t−1.5694*** (−5.81)−0.8716*** (−5.44)−2.0999*** (−10.56)−1.4244*** (−9.96)
dENi,t0.8115*** (5.25)0.4946*** (6.35)0.9522*** (6.98)0.6064*** (8.21)
dENi,t + 1−0.1983 (−1.36)0.1332 (1.39)−0.3701*** (−2.91)−0.0973 (−1.07)
dNAi,t0.3507*** (5.27)0.2750*** (5.90)0.6067*** (10.07)0.4190*** (9.60)
dNAi,t + 11.2894*** (20.32)1.1636*** (24.70)1.2662*** (23.64)1.1193*** (26.91)
RDi,t3.7630*** (3.96)4.6328*** (7.87)4.5417*** (8.43)5.7525*** (13.80)
dRDi,t1.8131* (1.83)2.0318*** (3.31)2.1347** (2.30)2.1624*** (3.63)
dRDi,t + 16.8916*** (6.72)7.3016*** (10.65)8.2718*** (9.89)8.3229*** (13.36)
INi,t11.0703*** (5.91)7.7414*** (6.44)13.9476*** (9.77)10.4764*** (10.54)
dINi,t−9.5792*** (−5.40)−8.2983*** (−7.75)−11.5644*** (−7.03)−10.2254*** (−10.18)
dINi,t + 1−0.6356*** (−4.15)−0.4322*** (−3.89)−0.5208*** (−5.54)−0.2286*** (−2.83)
DVi,t3.8434*** (2.99)10.5640*** (12.87)10.4084*** (11.54)13.6203*** (19.48)
dDVi,t2.8420*** (3.50)−1.3147** (−2.34)0.8017 (1.03)−2.1735*** (−4.09)
dDVi,t + 15.6033*** (6.40)7.8455*** (13.30)9.2963*** (11.75)9.5595*** (16.69)
dMVi,t−0.2787*** (−22.05)−0.2541*** (−21.15)−0.2459*** (−19.14)−0.2323*** (−19.21)
ASD 0.4270*** (3.56)1.4126*** (14.27)
CRE −0.0922*** (−4.05)−0.2053*** (−10.37)
ROL−0.0420 (−1.46)−0.0775*** (−3.61)−0.0086 (−0.30)−0.0085 (−0.39)
PCREt−0.0030*** (−2.66)0.0036*** (4.82)−0.0047*** (−8.60)0.0012*** (2.72)
MCAPt0.0017*** (5.48)0.0021*** (5.89)0.0009*** (4.27)−0.0002* (−1.87)
GCAPt0.6478*** (7.66)0.2834*** (4.91)0.2604*** (12.66)−0.0765*** (−5.19)
GGROt0.0875*** (10.31)0.0143*** (4.83)0.1036*** (13.98)0.0148*** (5.20)
ASD × EXCi,t0.1817 (1.17)0.0217 (0.26)0.0277 (0.27)0.0712 (1.01)
CRE × EXCi,t−0.0383 (−1.54)0.0142 (0.86)−0.0072 (−0.42)0.0136 (0.95)
ROL × EXCi,t−0.0202 (−0.94)0.0064 (0.41)−0.0298 (−1.42)0.0031 (0.21)
PCREt × EXCi,t0.0002 (0.35)−0.0010*** (−2.90)−0.0004 (−1.10)−0.0010*** (−3.36)
MCAPt × EXCi,t−0.0006** (−2.05)0.0002** (2.07)−0.0003 (−1.25)0.0002** (2.48)
GCAPt × EXCi,t0.0604*** (3.25)0.0035 (0.38)0.0439*** (3.57)−0.0088 (−1.12)
GGROt × EXCi,t0.0171*** (3.69)−0.0023 (−1.39)0.0105*** (2.61)−0.0026 (−1.62)
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
N34,04969,42534,04969,425

Note(s): The dependent variable is MVt. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EPU1 is economic policy uncertainty. CAS is cash holdings. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except CAS are deflated by net assets. ASD is anti-self-dealing index. CRE is revised creditor right index. ROL is rule of law. PCRE is private credit. MCAP is market capitalization. GCAP is GDP per capita. GGRO is GDP growth rate. * is significant at 10%. ** is significant at 5%. *** is significant at 1%. t-statistics are in parentheses

The effect of economic policy uncertainty on value of cash by financial constraint during the post-crisis period

VariablesKZ indexWW indexFirm size
LowHighLowHighLargeSmall
Intercept1.9086*** (5.73)1.0306*** (2.84)0.0020** (2.30)0.0070*** (3.72)1.8025*** (7.11)2.7450*** (6.00)
EPU1t × EXCi,t0.0034*** (2.79)0.0044*** (2.59)−0.0001 (−0.11)0.0070*** (3.25)0.0020** (2.28)0.0067*** (3.49)
EXCi,t0.0063 (0.03)0.4521** (2.56)1.5987** (2.24)−3.4905*** (−18.02)0.2455* (1.87)0.8797*** (4.47)
EPU1t−0.0004 (−0.22)0.0082*** (3.68)0.2870** (2.22)0.7752*** (4.02)−0.0012 (−1.13)0.0083*** (3.67)
ENi,t−1.0801*** (−3.22)−3.8750*** (−17.12)0.2413 (0.77)0.8446*** (6.55)4.1613*** (8.85)−3.4315*** (−17.32)
dENi,t1.2553*** (6.88)0.8960*** (5.39)1.8176*** (4.47)−1.0406*** (−7.32)−0.3075** (−2.17)0.8167*** (6.16)
dENi,t + 10.5536** (2.50)−1.0030*** (−5.45)0.6305*** (5.80)1.0187*** (9.35)3.0249*** (13.42)−1.0349*** (−7.17)
dNAi,t0.7796*** (6.48)0.7456*** (6.87)0.4886*** (4.99)1.2251*** (13.36)0.1219** (1.96)0.9174*** (8.19)
dNAi,t + 10.7684*** (9.04)1.2331*** (11.68)8.0070*** (10.11)3.7589*** (7.45)0.1969** (2.46)1.2011*** (12.76)
RDi,t5.6166*** (11.90)5.0257*** (6.94)9.0352*** (3.25)5.0033*** (4.92)5.8849*** (5.51)3.8438*** (7.33)
dRDi,t7.1493*** (6.23)3.0815** (1.98)15.0993*** (5.57)8.3691*** (8.07)7.6366*** (3.42)4.9940*** (4.91)
dRDi,t + 112.1243*** (11.40)9.0252*** (5.32)5.6439*** (3.59)17.2513*** (11.09)12.7415*** (5.40)8.3741*** (7.60)
INi,t17.5443*** (9.10)9.3041*** (5.80)−8.3035*** (−2.68)−17.8582*** (−9.20)5.3514*** (5.22)18.9171*** (11.37)
dINi,t−13.5644*** (−4.93)−16.0409*** (−8.03)0.0574 (0.80)−0.5025*** (−3.76)−4.1574** (−2.38)−18.6636*** (−9.21)
dINi,t + 1−0.1771* (−1.74)−0.3249*** (−2.94)19.6909*** (12.39)26.1928*** (10.38)0.2182*** (2.92)−0.4258** (−2.55)
DVi,t18.8544*** (16.29)53.9883*** (6.12)−0.9581 (−0.88)−8.3586*** (−3.42)14.8932*** (10.94)24.4272*** (12.70)
dDVi,t−0.0293 (−0.03)−16.0536*** (−4.26)14.1744*** (9.93)15.5222*** (7.69)−2.0077** (−2.11)−6.8930*** (−3.38)
dDVi,t + 114.4255*** (12.25)21.8134*** (6.39)−0.1347*** (−2.78)−0.0049 (−0.17)10.1555*** (8.51)16.3502*** (9.76)
dMVi,t−0.0221 (−0.85)−0.0102 (−0.26)0.2778* (1.92)1.6759*** (8.48)−0.1447*** (−3.13)−0.0258 (−1.00)
ASD1.1642*** (8.20)−0.0670 (−0.25)0.0400* (1.79)−0.2755*** (−6.32)0.1237 (0.75)1.8760*** (8.94)
CRE−0.1386*** (−5.15)0.0720 (1.17)−0.1365*** (−3.43)0.1842*** (2.75)0.0464** (2.08)−0.3074*** (−6.39)
ROL−0.0058 (−0.11)0.0341 (0.57)−0.0051*** (−9.54)0.0035*** (3.25)−0.0965*** (−2.82)0.1565** (2.30)
PCREt−0.0011 (−1.55)−0.0058*** (−3.70)0.0003 (0.99)−0.0009*** (−5.28)−0.0042*** (−7.36)0.0040*** (3.49)
MCAPt−0.0005*** (−4.52)0.0005* (1.89)−0.0918*** (−3.83)−0.1713*** (−4.91)0.0004 (1.06)−0.0012*** (−6.27)
GCAPt−0.1529*** (−5.18)−0.0192 (−0.50)−0.0155*** (−2.66)0.0374*** (3.87)−0.0556** (−2.19)−0.2339*** (−6.53)
GGROt0.0258*** (3.38)−0.0174 (−1.56)0.2011 (1.35)0.0841 (0.58)−0.0038 (−0.56)0.0380*** (4.05)
ASD × EXCi,t−0.1123 (−0.91)−0.0841 (−0.55)0.0184 (0.84)0.0257 (0.72)0.2919* (1.70)0.2064 (1.29)
CRE × EXCi,t0.1082*** (4.34)0.0499 (1.48)0.0289 (1.06)−0.1412*** (−2.87)0.0211 (0.96)−0.0004 (−0.01)
ROL × EXCi,t−0.0742* (−1.67)−0.1227*** (−2.81)−0.0007 (−1.76)−0.0002 (−0.26)0.0707*** (2.84)−0.1054 (−2.16)
PCREt × EXCi,t−0.0036*** (−5.85)−0.0014* (−1.97)−0.0001 (−0.30)0.0002 (1.37)−0.0011** (−2.56)−0.0001 (−0.09)
MCAPt × EXCi,t0.0002 (1.31)0.0003 (1.52)−0.0360** (−2.43)−0.0866*** (−4.22)−0.0002 (−0.80)0.0002 (0.93)
GCAPt × EXCi,t0.0362* (1.83)−0.0375*** (−2.00)−0.0084** (−2.40)−0.0032 (−0.63)−0.0353** (−2.28)−0.1002*** (−4.70)
GGROt × EXCi,t−0.0049 (−1.15)−0.0157*** (−3.08)2.2630*** (8.18)1.7347*** (4.75)−0.0128*** (−3.28)−0.0040 (−0.74)
Industry fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
R20.30890.32940.31070.35850.30080.36
N20,84621,00420,88520,91120,89720,897

Note(s): The dependent variable is MVt. Xt is the value of variable X in year t. dXt is the annual change in X in year t. dXt + 1 is the annual change in X in year t + 1. MV is market value. EPU1 is economic policy uncertainty. EXC is excess cash. EN is earnings before interest and extraordinary items. NA is net assets calculated by total assets minus total cash and short-term investment. RD is research and development expenditure. IN is interest expense. DV is cash dividend. All firm-level variables except EXC are deflated by net assets. ASD is anti-self-dealing index. CRE is revised creditor right index. ROL is rule of law. PCRE is private credit. MCAP is market capitalization. GCAP is GDP per capita. GGRO is GDP growth rate. * is significant at 10%. ** is significant at 5%. *** is significant at 1%. t-statistics are in parentheses

Note

1.

Our research findings remain stable with 3% and 5% of winsorization.

References

Al-Malkawi, H.A.N., Bhatti, M.I. and Magableh, S.I. (2014), “On the dividend smoothing, signaling and the global financial crisis”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 42, pp. 159-165.

Almeida, H., Campello, M. and Weisbach, M.S. (2004), “The cash flow sensitivity of cash”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 59 No. 4, pp. 1777-1804.

Arslan, Ö., Florackis, C. and Ozkan, A. (2006), “The role of cash holdings in reducing investment–cash flow sensitivity: Evidence from a financial crisis period in an emerging market”, Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 320-338.

Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O. and Zheng, X. (2021), “Dividends and economic policy uncertainty: international evidence”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 66, 101785.

Baker, S.R., Bloom, N. and Davis, S.J. (2016), “Measuring economic policy uncertainty*”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 131 No. 4, pp. 1593-1636.

Bates, T.W., Kahle, K.M. and Stulz, R.M. (2009), “Why do US firms hold so much more cash than they used to?”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 64 No. 5, pp. 1985-2021.

Campello, M., Giambona, E., Graham, J.R. and Harvey, C.R. (2011), “Liquidity management and corporate investment during a financial crisis”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 24 No. 6, pp. 1944-1979.

Chang, Y., Benson, K. and Faff, R. (2017), “Are excess cash holdings more valuable to firms in times of crisis? Financial constraints and governance matters”, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 45, pp. 157-173.

Dash, S.R., Maitra, D., Debata, B. and Mahakud, J. (2021), “Economic policy uncertainty and stock market liquidity: evidence from G7 countries”, International Review of Finance, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 611-626.

Debata, B. and Mahakud, J. (2018), “Economic policy uncertainty and stock market liquidity: does financial crisis make any difference?”, Journal of Financial Economic Policy, Vol. 10 No. 1, pp. 112-135.

Demir, E. and Ersan, O. (2017), “Economic policy uncertainty and cash holdings: evidence from BRIC countries”, Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 33, pp. 189-200.

Dittmar, A. and Mahrt-Smith, J. (2007), “Corporate governance and the value of cash holdings”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 83 No. 3, pp. 599-634.

Dittmar, A., Mahrt-Smith, J. and Servaes, H. (2003), “International corporate governance and corporate cash holdings”, Journal of Financial Quantitative analysisJournal of Financial, Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 111-133.

Djankov, S., McLiesh, C. and Shleifer, A. (2007), “Private credit in 129 countries”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 84 No. 2, pp. 299-329.

Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2008), “The law and economics of self-dealing”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 88 No. 3, pp. 430-465.

Drobetz, W., Grüninger, M.C. and Hirschvogl, S. (2010), “Information asymmetry and the value of cash”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 34 No. 9, pp. 2168-2184.

Duchin, R., Ozbas, O. and Sensoy, B.A. (2010), “Costly external finance, corporate investment, and the subprime mortgage credit crisis”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 97 No. 3, pp. 418-435.

Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1998), “Taxes, financing decisions, and firm value”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 53 No. 3, pp. 819-843.

Ferreira, M.A. and Vilela, A.S. (2004), “Why do firms hold cash? Evidence from EMU countries”, European Financial Management, Vol. 10 No. 2, pp. 295-319.

Flannery, M.J., Kwan, S.H. and Nimalendran, M. (2013), “The 2007–2009 financial crisis and bank opaqueness”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 22 No. 1, pp. 55-84.

Frésard, L. and Salva, C. (2010), “The value of excess cash and corporate governance: evidence from US cross-listings”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 98 No. 2, pp. 359-384.

Hoque, M.E., Soo Wah, L. and Zaidi, M.A.S. (2019), “Oil price shocks, global economic policy uncertainty, geopolitical risk, and stock price in Malaysia: factor augmented VAR approach”, Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, Vol. 32 No. 1, pp. 3700-3732.

Hugonnier, J., Malamud, S. and Morellec, E. (2014), “Capital supply uncertainty, cash holdings, and investment”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 28 No. 2, pp. 391-445.

Im, H.J., Park, H. and Zhao, G. (2017), “Uncertainty and the value of cash holdings”, Economics Letters, Vol. 155, pp. 43-48.

Ivashina, V. and Scharfstein, D. (2010), “Bank lending during the financial crisis of 2008”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 97 No. 3, pp. 319-338.

Jebran, K., Chen, S. and Tauni, M.Z. (2019), “Principal-principal conflicts and corporate cash holdings: evidence from China”, Research in International Business and Finance, Vol. 49, pp. 55-70.

Jensen, M.C. (1986), “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers”, American Economic Review, Vol. 76 No. 2, p. 323.

Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976), “Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 No. 4, pp. 305-360.

Kalcheva, I. and Lins, K.V. (2007), “International evidence on cash holdings and expected managerial agency problems”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 1087-1112.

Kang, W., Lee, K. and Ratti, R.A. (2014), “Economic policy uncertainty and firm-level investment”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 39, pp. 42-53.

Kaplan, S.N. and Zingales, L. (1997), “Do investment-cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112 No. 1, pp. 169-215.

Kim, Kim, H. and Woods, D. (2011), “Determinants of corporate cash-holding levels: an empirical examination of the restaurant industry”, International Journal of Hospitality Management, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 568-574.

Kyröläinen, P., Tan, I. and Karjalainen, P. (2013), “How creditor rights affect the value of cash: a cross-country study”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 22, pp. 278-298.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1998), “Law and finance”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106, p. 42.

Lian, Y., Sepehri, M. and Foley, M. (2011), “Corporate cash holdings and financial crisis: an empirical study of Chinese companies”, Eurasian Business Review, Vol. 1 No. 2, pp. 112-124.

Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N.S. (1984), “Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 187-221.

Ozkan, A. and Ozkan, N. (2004), “Corporate cash holdings: an empirical investigation of UK companies”, Journal of Banking Finance, Vol. 28 No. 9, pp. 2103-2134.

Paule-Vianez, J., Gómez-Martínez, R. and Prado-Román, C. (2020), “Effect of Economic and Monetary Policy Uncertainty on stock markets. Evidence on return, volatility and liquidity”, Economics Bulletin, Vol. 40 No. 2, pp. 1261-1271.

Phan, H.V., Nguyen, N.H., Nguyen, H.T. and Hegde, S. (2019), “Policy uncertainty and firm cash holdings”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 95, pp. 71-82.

Pinkowitz, L., Stulz, R. and Williamson, R. (2006), “Does the contribution of corporate cash holdings and dividends to firm value depend on governance? A cross‐country analysis”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 61 No. 6, pp. 2725-2751.

Rhee, K. and Park, K.S. (2018), “Changes in dividend smoothing after the financial crisis”, Economics Letters, Vol. 172, pp. 37-39.

Roubini, N. (2007), “Current market turmoil: non-priceable Knightian ‘uncertainty’ rather than priceable market ‘risk’”, Nouriel Roubini's Blog.

Sum, V. and Fanta, F. (2012), “Long-run relation and speed of adjustment of economic policy uncertainty and excess return volatility”, International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 102, pp. 6-12.

Thakur, B.P.S. and Kannadhasan, M. (2019), “Corruption and cash holdings: evidence from emerging market economies”, Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 38, pp. 1-17.

Tran, Q.T. (2019a), “Corporate cash holdings and financial crisis: new evidence from an emerging market”, Eurasian Business Review, Vol. 10 No. 2, pp. 271-285.

Tran, Q.T. (2019b), “Economic policy uncertainty and corporate risk-taking: International evidence”, Journal of Multinational Financial Management, Vols 52-53, 100605.

Tran, Q.T. (2020), “Financial crisis, shareholder protection and cash holdings”, Research in International Business and Finance, Vol. 52, 101131.

Tran, Q.T., Alphonse, P. and Nguyen, X.M. (2017), “Dividend policy: shareholder rights and creditor rights under the impact of the global financial crisis”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 64, pp. 502-512.

Wang, Y., Chen, C.R. and Huang, Y.S. (2014), “Economic policy uncertainty and corporate investment: evidence from China”, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 26, pp. 227-243.

Wang, Y., Wei, Y. and Song, F.M. (2017), “Uncertainty and corporate R&D investment: evidence from Chinese listed firms”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 47, pp. 176-200.

Whited, T.M. and Wu, G. (2006), “Financial constraints risk”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 19 No. 2, pp. 531-559.

Zhang, G., Han, J., Pan, Z. and Huang, H. (2015), “Economic policy uncertainty and capital structure choice: evidence from China”, Economic Systems, Vol. 39 No. 3, pp. 439-457.

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Thi Huong Dao, Tran Sy Nguyen, Thi Mai Nguyen and Tuan Duong Nguyen for their valuable contributions to this paper.

This research is funded by Foreign Trade University under research program number FTURP01-2020-07.

Corresponding author

Quoc Trung Tran can be contacted at: tranquoctrung.cs2@ftu.edu.vn; quoctrungftu@gmail.com

Related articles