Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of strategic agents in two-sided markets

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper introduces strategic agents into a two-sided market. We model strategic agents as advertisers who can invest in ad quality, which in turn affects readers, platforms and themselves. When platforms can choose prices on both the reader side and the advertiser side, strategic agents intensify competition, leading to lower prices and profits for the platforms. However, when prices on the reader side are restricted to be zero, equilibrium prices on the advertiser side can be higher or lower under strategic agents. We also investigate the interplay between strategic agents and platform asymmetry, and analyze platforms’ incentive to invest in content quality. Our results suggest that strategic agents increase the degree of platform asymmetry and make it harder for the disadvantaged platform to compete. However, strategic agents may raise or lower platforms’ incentive to invest in content quality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Caillaud and Jullien (2003), Armstrong (2006) and Choi (2006).

  2. The term “passive agents” has been used in the two-sided market literature. For example, in Hagiu and Halaburda (2014), passive agents are the agents who hold their expectation of total demand fixed, irrespective of platforms’ price choices. This differs from our setting where agents (advertisers) are passive when they do not make strategic decisions such as ad quality choice.

  3. “How Much Does TV Commercial Production Cost?”, Kelly McCaughey, August 8, 2016, http://www.greyskyfilms.com/tv-commercial-production-cost/. Accessed on February 4, 2021.

  4. “How Much Does Television Advertising Really Cost?,” by Nancy Wagner, accessed on January 25, 2017. See also Frederiksen (2020). Note that these dollar figures are ad production costs, which are typically fixed costs associated with developing the creative ideas and executing the ideas in ads. They differ from ad distribution costs which are the variable costs advertisers pay to platforms for distributing ads. Higher quality ads (which cost more to produce) are more likely to be placed on national media which also charge more for ad distribution.

  5. We also explore how strategic agents potentially affect the estimation of group externality parameters (see Appendix A). Our results suggest that the econometric model will differ qualitatively from the one under passive agents. To obtain proper estimates, one generally needs to be informed of advertisers’ incentive to investment in ad quality (the cost and benefit) and recover the equilibrium ad quality. Similar issues have been raised in other settings, especially when applying results in one-sided markets to two-sided markets. See, for example, Genakos and Valletti (2011), Behringer and Filistrucchi (2015).

  6. In Section 4.4, we also explore platforms’ content quality choice and compare the equilibria content quality under passive and strategic agents respectively.

  7. This is also assumed in various other studies. See Anderson and Jullien (2015) for a survey of this literature. Note that while advertisers may have different valuations for reaching viewers, each viewer values all advertisers the same. In contrasts, in our model, a viewer values different ads differently, depending on the quality of these ads.

  8. Sometimes this is the only “price” a reader has to pay, i.e., when \(p_i=0\). We analyze this situation in Section 4.1.

  9. These simplifying assumptions help keep the analysis tractable, especially in the case of strategic agents. Our objective is to illustrate that, even in our simple model, having strategic agents can change the results qualitatively.

  10. This is consistent with the fact that consumers find it less annoying to view high quality ads. For example, it is well known that many viewers enjoy superbowl ads, which have higher quality. Nettles (2018) shows that “consumers hate bad ads ... but they don’t really mind the good ones.” Similarly, Chen and Liu (forthcoming) assume that higher ad production cost results in higher ad quality, which in turn reduces consumers’ nuisance costs of watching the ad.

  11. Alternatively, one may think that \(\kappa\) enters into the utility function additively with \(\rho\), for example, \(f(\rho ,\kappa ,N_1^r)=(\rho +\kappa )N_1^r\). Similarly for the entry of \(\kappa\) into reader utilities. We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this alternative, and consider this case in Section 4.2.

  12. This can potentially explain the observation that political views of the media and of the advertisers (akin to x in our model) do not necessarily influence the quality of ads.

  13. We also check the second-order conditions. Normalizing \(t=\frac{1}{2}\), we find that SOCs are satisfied if and only if \(\lambda ^2+\lambda \gamma \rho +\gamma \rho ^3-4\gamma \lambda ^2\rho >0\) and \(-4\lambda ^2-4\lambda \gamma \rho +4\gamma ^2\lambda ^2-4\gamma ^2\lambda \rho +8\gamma \lambda ^2\rho +\gamma ^2\rho ^2-2\gamma \rho ^3+4\rho ^2\lambda ^2+ 4\rho ^3\lambda +\rho ^4<0\). Both inequalities are satisfied if \(|\gamma |\) and \(|\rho |\) are not too large.

  14. To see this, we consider a hypothetical situation where advertiser’s ad quality affects their own utilities but not readers’ utilities. We normalize \(t=\frac{1}{2}\) and show that equilibrium prices are then \(p_1 = -1/2\rho ^2-\rho +1/2\) and \(a_1 = 1/2-\gamma\). Note that own derivatives are still zero, since only group externality parameter of the same side enters into an agent’s utility function. However, \(\rho\) now enters into \(p_1\) nonlinearly, because \(\rho\) enters into \(u_i^a\) expressions nonlinearly.

  15. We thank an anonymous reviewer for pointing us to several of these new directions.

  16. SOC is also simplified. Rather than the 2-by-2 Hessian matrix (with respect to \(p_i\) and \(a_i\)) to be negative definite, we only need \(\frac{\partial ^2 \pi _i}{\partial a_i^2}<0\).

  17. Relative to the extensive literature on symmetric platforms, studies of asymmetric platforms have been relatively scarce. Exceptions include Caillaud and Jullien (2003), Gabszewicz and Wauthy (2014), Halaburda and Yehezkel (2019) and Chatterjee and Zhou (forthcoming).

  18. We select 3 values for \(\lambda\): 2, 10 or 50, and 3 values of \(\delta\): \(\frac{1}{100}\), \(\frac{1}{20}\) or \(\frac{1}{5}\). This leads to 9 combinations. For each combination, we plot \(\pi _1^{straegic}-\pi _1^{passive}\) as a function of \(\gamma\) and \(\rho\). The 3D plots show that \(\pi _1^{straegic}-\pi _1^{passive}<0\) always holds.

  19. This is in similar spirit as the findings in Bernhardt et al. (2007). They show that firms’ incentive to invest in product-customization capabilities depend on the degree of ex-ante brand name effects (horizontal competition).

  20. Similar conditions are needed to ensure SOCs are satisfied, for example \(\gamma\) and \(\rho\) should be small in magnitude. In addition, we want \(\mu\) to be not too small, so as to curb platforms’ incentive to increase q significantly in deviation and drive the other platform out of market on either side.

  21. This largely follows the approach in Kaiser and Wright (2006). For the econometric model in equation (A.1) and (A.2) to be defined, there needs to be variation across the platforms, in particular, \(N_1^r\ne N_2^r\). In contrast, in the theory model, with platform symmetry (no disturbance), the equilibrium always has \(N_1^r=N_2^r=\frac{1}{2}\) and \(N_1^a=N_2^a=\frac{1}{2}\). Also note that prices and sales on the right hand side are likely to be endogenous. Kaiser and Wright propose instrument variables to solve this problem.

References

  • Adachi T, Tremblay M (2020) Business-to-business bargaining in two-sided markets. Eur Econ Rev 130:103591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson S, Coate S (2005) Market provision of broadcasting: a welfare analysis. Rev Econ Studies 72(4):947–972

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson S, Jullien B (2015) The advertising-financed business model in two-sided media markets. Handbook of media economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 41–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Argentesi E, Filistrucchi L (2007) Estimating market power in a two-sided market: the case of newspapers. J Appl Econ 22(7):1247–1266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong M (2006) Competition in two-sided markets. Rand J Econ 37(3):668–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Athey S, Calvano E, Gans J (2013) The impact of the internet on advertising markets for news media. Working paper

  • Behringer S, Filistrucchi L (2015) Areeda-Turner in two-sided markets. Rev Ind Organ 46:287–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhardt D, Liu Q, Serfes K (2007) Product customization. Eur Econ Rev 51:1396–1422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caillaud B, Jullien B (2003) Chicken and egg: competition among intermediation service providers. Rand J Econ 34:309–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee P, Zhou B. Sponsored content advertising in a two-sided market. Management Science (forthcoming)

  • Chen Y, Liu Q. Signaling through advertising when ad can be blocked. Marketing Science forthcoming)

  • Choi J (2006) Broadcast competition and advertising with free entry: subscription vs. free-to-air. Inf Econ Policy 18:181–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi J, Jeon D-S (2021) A leverage theory of tying in two-sided markets with nonnegative price constraints. Am Econ J: Microecon 13(1):283–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederiksen L (2020) What is the cost of video Production for the web? Hinge Marketing July 6, 2020

  • Gabszewicz J, Wauthy X (2014) Vertical product differentiation and two-sided markets. Econ Lett 123(1):58–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genakos C, Valletti T (2011) Testing the ‘waterbed’ effect in mobile telephony. J Eur Econ Assoc 9(6):1114–1142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner T, Sahm M (2018) How effective are advertising bans? On demand for quality in two-sided media markets. Inf Econ Policy 43:48–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagiu A (2011) Quantity vs. quality: exclusion by platforms with network effects. Working Paper

  • Hagiu A, Halaburda H (2014) Information and two-sided platform profits. Int J Ind Organ 34:25–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagiu A, Lee R (2011) Exclusivity and control. J Econ Manag Strat 20(3):679–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halaburda H, Yehezkel Y (2019) Focality advantage in platform competition. J Econ Manag Strat 28(1):49–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser U, Song M (2009) Do media consumers really dislike advertising? an empirical assessment of the role of advertising in print media markets. Int J Ind Organ 27(2):292–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser U, Wright J (2006) Price structure in two-sided markets: evidence from the magazine industry. Int J Ind Organ 24:1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind H, Nilssen T, Sorgard L (2007) Competition for viewers and advertisers in a TV oligopoly. J Media Econ 20(3):211–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind H, Nilssen T, Sorgard L (2016) Inter-firm price coordination in a two-sided market. Int J Ind Organ 44:101–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nettles L (2018) New data on why people hate ads: too many, too intrusive, too creepy. VIEO Design, September 6, 2018

  • Peitz M, Valletti TM (2008) Content and advertising in the media: pay-tv versus free-to-air. Int J Ind Organ 26(4):949–965

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reisinger M (2012) Platform competition for advertisers and users in media markets. Int J Ind Organ 30:243–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilbur K (2008) A two-sided, empirical model of television advertising and viewing markets. Market Sci 27(3):356–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilbur K, Xu L, Kempe D (2013) Correcting audience externalities in television advertising. Market Sci 32(6):892–912

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

We would like to thank the Editor and two anonymous referees whose comments helped improve this paper substantially. We also want to thank Thomas Jeitschko, Georgia Kosmopoulou and Ken Wilbur for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Qihong Liu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendices

Estimating group externality parameters

We start with the benchmark passive agents model. Recall that equations (1) and (2) in the main text characterize the marginal advertiser and marginal reader respectively. Let \(n_1^a=\frac{N_1^a}{N_1^a+N_2^a}\) and \(n_1^r=\frac{N_1^r}{N_1^r+N_2^r}\). Since \(N_1^j+N_2^j=1\) (unit mass of agents on either side), we have \(n_i^j=N_i^j\). Then

$$\begin{aligned} n_1^a= & {} \frac{1}{2t}\left[ t + \rho (N_1^r- N_2^r) -(a_1-a_2)\right] , \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned} n_1^r= & {} \frac{1}{2t}\left[ t + \gamma (N_1^a- N_2^a)-(p_1-p_2)\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

With data on sales \(N_i^j\), market share \(n_i^j\) and prices (\(p_i\) and \(a_i\)), equations (A.1) and (A.2) can be used to estimate group externality parameters \(\rho\) and \(\gamma\) respectively.Footnote 21

Next, we move on to the case of strategic agents. Recall that equations (7) and (9) characterize the advertiser and reader utilities, and equations (8) and (10) report the marginal advertiser \(x^a\) and marginal reader \(x^r\) respectively. Since \(N_1^j+N_2^j=1\), we have \(x^j=n_1^j\). Then

$$\begin{aligned} n_1^a= & {} \frac{1}{2t}[ t + \rho (N_1^r-N_2^r)+ \underbrace{\frac{\rho ^2}{2\lambda } \left[ \left( N_1^r\right) ^2 - \left( N_2^r\right) ^2\right] }_{\text{Endogenous ad quality effect}} -(a_1-a_2)], \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)
$$\begin{aligned} n_1^r= & {} \frac{1}{2t}[t + \gamma (N_1^a - N_2^a)- \underbrace{\frac{\gamma \cdot \rho }{\lambda } \cdot (N_1^r \cdot N_1^a - N_2^r \cdot N_2^a)}_{\text{Endogenous ad quality effect}} - (p_1-p_2)]. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

Different from equation (A.1) in the benchmark model, in equation (A.3), \(n_1^a\) is now linear-quadratic (rather than linear) in \(N_i^r\). This can also be seen with general \(f(\rho ,\kappa _i,N_i^r)\) and \(c(\kappa )\). \(\kappa ^*\) in general will be a function of \(N_i^r\). Once the \(\kappa _i^*\) value is substituted, \(n_i^a\) will not be linear in \(N_i^r\) anymore. In addition, \(\rho\) appears twice in equation (A.3), including in the form of \(\frac{\rho ^2}{2}\). Note that the endogenous ad quality term disappears in the limiting case of \(\lambda \rightarrow +\infty\). Similarly, equation (A.4) differs from (A.2) in the benchmark model. Combining results for both the advertiser and reader sides, we have the following proposition.

Proposition A1

(Estimating group externality parameters) Ignoring advertisers’ strategic investment decisions will lead to wrong econometric models for estimating the group externality parameters on both the advertiser and reader sides.

Intuitively, when ad quality affects the reader and advertiser side, one needs to know the cost and benefit of having higher quality ad to the advertiser, in order to recover the equilibrium ad quality. One can then substitute the optimal ad quality to obtain the revised econometric model such as (A.3) and (A.4) for estimation. In our specific model, given equations (A.3) and (A.4), one needs to construct additional explanatory variables \((N_1^r)^2-(N_2^r)^2\) and \(N_1^r \cdot N_1^a - N_2^r \cdot N_2^a\). Together with \(N_1^r-N_2^r\) and \(N_1^a-N_2^a\), which are also used under passive agents model, we have 4 explanatory variables and in turn 4 coefficients (after normalizing \(t=\frac{1}{2}\) so \(\frac{1}{2t}=1\)):

$$\begin{aligned} Coeff_1 = \rho , \quad Coeff_2 = \frac{\rho ^2}{2\lambda }, \quad Coeff_3 = \gamma ,\quad Coeff_4 = -\frac{\gamma \cdot \rho }{\lambda }. \end{aligned}$$

The first two coefficients come from equation (A.3) while the last two come from equation (A.4). However, there are only 3 model primitives to be estimated: \(\gamma\), \(\rho\) and \(\lambda\). Thus the econometric model is over-identified. In fact, there is a constraint linking the 4 coefficients in the form of \(\frac{Coeff_2}{Coeff_1}=-\frac{1}{2}\cdot \frac{Coeff_4}{\cdot Coeff_3}\). This constraint needs to be imposed in the estimation.

Proof of propositions

Proof of Proposition 1

Recall that the marginal advertiser and reader are,

$$\begin{aligned} x^a= & {} \frac{1}{2t}\left[ t + \rho (N_1^r-N_2^r)+ \frac{\rho ^2}{2 \lambda } \left[ \left( N_1^r\right) ^2 - \left( N_2^r\right) ^2\right] -(a_1-a_2)\right] ,\\ x^r= & {} \frac{1}{2t}\left[ t + \gamma (N_1^a - N_2^a)- \frac{\gamma \cdot \rho }{\lambda } \cdot (N_1^r \cdot N_1^a - N_2^r \cdot N_2^a) - (p_1-p_2)\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(N_1^j=x^j\) and \(N_2^j=1-x^j\), \(j=a,r\). Substituting them into the \(x^a\) and \(x^r\) expressions above, we can solve the stand-alone \(N_i^j\). We then substitute \(N_i^j\) into platform i’s profit maximization problem,

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{p_i, a_i} \quad \pi _i = (p_i- f_r) \cdot N_i^r + (a_i-f_a) \cdot N_i^a,\quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

Solving firms’ FOCs, we can obtain the equilibrium prices,

$$\begin{aligned} p_i=t-\rho +\frac{1}{2} \frac{\rho }{\lambda } (\gamma -\rho )+f_r,\quad a_i=t-\gamma +\frac{1}{2} \frac{\rho \gamma }{\lambda }+f_a, \end{aligned}$$

In the equilibrium, each platform earns a profit of

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i=t+\frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma \rho }{\lambda }-\frac{1}{2}\gamma -\frac{1}{2}\rho -\frac{1}{4}\frac{\rho ^2}{\lambda } \quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

In the symmetric equilibrium, \(N_i^r=\frac{1}{2}\) and all advertisers choose \(\kappa ^*=\frac{\rho }{2\lambda }\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

(i) Recall that equilibrium prices in the benchmark passive agents model and the strategic agents model are,

$$\begin{aligned} p_i^{passive}= & {} t-\rho +f_r,\quad a_i^{passive}=t-\gamma +f_a,\\ p_i^{strategic}= & {} t-\rho +\frac{1}{2} \rho (\gamma -\rho )+f_r,\quad a_i^{strategic}=t-\gamma +\frac{1}{2} \rho \gamma +f_a. \end{aligned}$$

It is easy to see that

$$\begin{aligned} p_i^{strategic} - p_i^{passive} = \frac{1}{2} \rho (\gamma -\rho )< 0,\quad a_i^{strategic} - a_i^{passive} = \frac{1}{2} \rho \gamma < 0, \end{aligned}$$

because \(\gamma <0\) and \(\rho >0\). That is, equilibrium prices on both sides are lower under strategic agents relative to the benchmark case.

(ii) With lower prices on both sides of the market, advertisers and readers must be better of at the cost of platforms. In addition, higher ad quality further benefits the advertisers and readers. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 3

We start with same platform profit functions as when platforms are free to chooses both \(p_i\) and \(a_i\). We then substitute \(p_i=0\), and take derivative with respect to \(a_i\) only to solve for equilibrium \(a_i\). This is done for passive agents and strategic agents respectively.

(i) Under passive agents, solving the FOC (\(\frac{\partial \pi _i}{\partial a_i}=0\)), we can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} a_i=\frac{1}{2}+2\gamma (f_r-\rho )+f_a, \quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

Platform i’s profit (\(i=1,2\)) is

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i= & {} (0-f_r)\cdot \frac{1}{2} + (a_i-f_a)\cdot \frac{1}{2}\\= & {} \frac{1}{4}+\gamma (f_r-\rho )-\frac{1}{2}f_r. \end{aligned}$$

(ii) Under strategic agents, solving the FOC leads to

$$\begin{aligned} a_i= & {} \frac{(4(f_r-\rho )\gamma +1)\lambda ^2 -\rho \gamma (2f_r-1)\lambda + \gamma \rho ^3}{2\lambda (\lambda + \gamma \rho )} + f_a,\\ \pi _i= & {} \frac{(4(f_r-\rho )\gamma +1)\lambda ^2 -\rho \gamma (2f_r-1)\lambda + \gamma \rho ^3}{4\lambda (\lambda + \gamma \rho )} -\frac{1}{2}f_r , \quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

(iii) It suffices to show that \(a_i\) can go up or down when \(f_r=0\). When \(f_r=0\), it can be shown that

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta a_i\equiv a_i^{strategic}-a_i^{passive}= \frac{1}{2}\frac{\gamma \rho ^2(\rho +4\lambda \gamma )}{\lambda (\lambda +\gamma \rho )}. \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(\lambda +\gamma \rho >0\) is required for SOC to hold, but \(\rho +4\lambda \gamma\) can be positive or negative. With \(\gamma <0\), \(\Delta a_i>0\) if and only if \(\rho +4\lambda \gamma <0\). SOCs are satisfied if \(|\gamma |\) and \(\rho\) are sufficiently small. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4

Having an alternative form of strategic agents has no impact on the passive agents model. For strategic agents, recall that \(\kappa _i^*=\frac{N_i^r}{\lambda }\). Substituting it into advertiser and reader utility functions, and solving for marginal advertiser and marginal reader, we can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} x^a= & {} \frac{1}{2} + \rho (N_1^r-N_2^r)+ \frac{1}{2\lambda } \left[ \left( N_1^r\right) ^2 - \left( N_2^r\right) ^2\right] -(a_1-a_2),\\ x^r= & {} \frac{1}{2} + \gamma (N_1^a - N_2^a)- \frac{1}{\lambda } \cdot (N_1^r \cdot N_1^a - N_2^r \cdot N_2^a) - (p_1-p_2). \end{aligned}$$

Using the fact that \(N_1^j=x^j\) and \(N_2^j=1-N_1^j\), \(j=r,a\), we can solve the stand-alone \(x^r\) and \(x^a\), and in turn platform profit \(\pi _i\). Next, we proceed to solve for the equilibrium, depending on whether prices on the reader side are restricted to be zero.

(i) Case 1: Platforms are free to choose prices on both sides.

Platform i solve the following problem,

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{p_i,a_i} \quad \pi _i=(a_i-f_a)N_i^a + (p_i-f_r)N_i^r,\quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

Solving the FOCs, we can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} p_i=\frac{1}{2}-\rho -\frac{1}{\lambda }+f_r,\quad a_i=\frac{1}{2}-\gamma -\frac{1}{2\lambda }+f_a. \end{aligned}$$

Recall the following equilibrium prices from the corresponding passive agents model,

$$\begin{aligned} p_i=\frac{1}{2}-\rho +f_r,\quad a_i=\frac{1}{2}-\gamma +f_a. \end{aligned}$$

It is straightforward to verify that both \(p_i\) and \(a_i\) are lower under strategic agents, relative to the prices under passive agents.

(ii) Case 2: Zero prices on the reader side

Now platform i solve the following problem,

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{p_i=0,a_i} \quad \pi _i=(a_i-f_a)N_i^a + (p_i-f_r)N_i^r,\quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

Solving the FOCs, we can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} a_i=\left[ \frac{1}{2}+2\gamma (f_r-\rho )+f_a \right] + \frac{1}{2}\frac{(-2\gamma -2\rho -4\gamma \rho )\lambda -1}{\lambda (\lambda -1)} \end{aligned}$$

Recall the following equilibrium prices from the corresponding passive agents model,

$$\begin{aligned} a_i=\frac{1}{2}+2\gamma (f_r-\rho )+f_a, \quad i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$

Then

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta a_i=a_i^{strategic}-a_i^{passive}=\frac{1}{2} \frac{(-2\gamma -2\rho -4\gamma \rho )\lambda -1}{\lambda (\lambda -1)}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\Delta a_i\) can take either sign depending on the values of \(\gamma\), \(\rho\) and \(\lambda\). For example if \(\gamma =0\), \(\rho =0\) and \(\lambda =2\), then \(\Delta a_i= -0.25\). However, if \(\gamma =-0.2\), \(\rho =0\) and \(\lambda =10\), then \(\Delta a_i= 0.16\). \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, Q., Nedelescu, D. & Gu, J. The impact of strategic agents in two-sided markets. J Econ 134, 195–218 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00753-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00753-9

Keywords

JEL Classification Codes

Navigation