Skip to main content
Log in

Pricing commodity-linked bonds with stochastic convenience yield, interest rate and counterparty credit risk: application of Mellin transform methods

  • Published:
Review of Derivatives Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the effects of the spot underlying commodity price, stochastic convenience yield, interest rate and counterparty credit risk on the pricing of the commodity-linked bonds. The stochastic factors or state variables in the model are the spot price of the underlying commodity follows geometrical Brownian motion process with a stochastic drift, the net convenience yield and the short-term interest rate are formulated as a mean-reverting Ornstein–Uhlenbeck stochastic process and the value of the firm issuing the bonds follows a geometrical Brownian motion process. Furthermore, we develop the two- and three-factor(I, II) pricing models for valuing the commodity-linked bonds. Closed-form pricing formulas of the commodity-linked bonds are derived based on the Mellin transform techniques, which are simply provided with standard (bivariate) normal cumulative distribution function so that the pricing and hedging of the commodity-linked bonds can be computed very accurately and rapidly. At last, numerical analysis compares the results of this four pricing models with realistic parameter values and demonstrates how the spot underlying commodity price, convenience yield, interest rate and counterparty credit risk affect the values of the commodity-linked bonds.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Schwartz (1997) states that the positive correlation between changes in the spot price underlying commodity and changes in the convenience yield of the underlying commodity is induced by the level of inventories. When inventories of the underlying commodity decrease, the spot price should increase since the underlying commodity is scarce and the convenience yield should also increase since futures prices will not increase as much as the spot price, and vice versa when inventories increase.

  2. Expressing convenience yield as a fraction of the commodity price, i.e. convenince \(\hbox {yield}=\delta S_{t}\), see Brennan and Schwartz (1985).

  3. See Brennan (1991) and Brennan and Schwartz (1985).

  4. Gibson and Schwartz (1990) show that the assumption of constant convenience yield is very restrictive.

  5. Empirical studies find that the convenience yield should be specified by a mean-reverting process, for example, see Fama and French (1988) and Brennan (1991).

  6. Since convenience yield risk cannot be hedged, the market price of convenience yield risk has to be incorporated in the risk neutral process of convenience yield.

  7. See Gibson and Schwartz (1990) and Hilliard and Reis (1998).

  8. Notice that the result has a little discrepancy with these Miura and Yamauchi (1998) display in their Fig. 2. They just suggest that a smaller level of \(\kappa \) makes the bond prices higher than that of a larger level of \(\kappa \).

References

  • Almansour, A. (2016). Convenience yield in commodity price modeling: A regime switching approach. Energy Economics, 53, 238–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjerksund, P. (1991). Contingent claims evaluation when the convenience yield is stochastic: Analytical results. Working paper, Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration.

  • Black, F., & Cox, J. C. (1976). Valuing corporate securities: Some effects of bond indenture provisions. Journal of Finance, 31(2), 351–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, F. S. , & Scholes, M. S. (1973). The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 637–654.

  • Brennan, M. J. (1991). The price of convenience and valuation of commodity contingent claims. In D. Lund & B. Oksendal (Eds.), Stochastic models and option values. North Holland.

  • Brennan, M. J., & Schwartz, E. S. (1985). Evaluating natural resource investments. Journal of Business, 58(2), 135–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr, P. (1987). A note on the pricing of commodity$\copyright $Linked bonds. Journal of Finance, 42(4), 1071–1076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chance, D. M. (1990). Default risk and the duration of zero coupon bonds. Journal of Finance, 45(1), 265–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, H. (2010). Macroeconomic conditions and the puzzles of credit spreads and capital structure. Journal of Finance, 65(6), 2171–2212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. C., & Ross, S. A. (1976). The valuation of options for alternative stochastic processes. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(1), 145–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdelyi, A., Magnus,W., Oberhettinger, F., & Tricomi, F. G. (1954). Tables of integral transforms. McGraw-Hill Book Company, Incorporated.

  • Ewald, C. O., Zhang, A., & Zong, Z. (2019). On the calibration of the Schwartz two-factor model to WTI crude oil options and the extended Kalman filter. Annals of Operations Research, 282, 119–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1987). Commodity futures prices: Some evidence on forecast power, premiums, and the theory of storage. Journal of Business, 60(1), 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1988) Business cycles and the behavior of metals prices. Journal of Finance, 43(5), 1075–1093.

  • Gibson, R., & Schwartz, E. S. (1990). Stochastic convenience yield and the pricing of oil contingent claims. Journal of Finance, 45(3), 959–976.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilliard, J. E., & Reis, J. (1998). Valuation of commodity futures and options under stochastic convenience yields, interest rates, and jump diffusions in the spot. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 33(1), 61–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hung, M. W., & Liu, Y. H. (2005). Pricing vulnerable options in incomplete markets. Journal of Futures Markets, 25(2), 135–170.

  • Ingersoll, J. E. (1982). The pricing of commodity-linked bonds: Discussion. Journal of Finance, 37(2), 540–541.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeon, J., & Kim, G. (2019). Pricing of vulnerable options with early counterparty credit risk. The North American journal of Economics and Finance, 47(1), 645–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, H., & Stulz, R. (1987). The pricing of options with default risk. Journal of Finance, 42(2), 267–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1939). Speculation and economic stability. Review of Economic Studies, 7(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, P. (1996). Pricing black-scholes options with correlated credit risk. Journal of Banking & Finance, 20(7), 1211–1229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, P., & Inglis, M. (1999). Valuation of European options subject to financial distress and interest rate risk. Journal of Derivatives, 6(3), 284–287.

  • Klein, P., & Inglis, M. (2001). Pricing vulnerable European options when the option’s payoff can increase the risk of financial distress. Journal of Banking & Finance, 25(5), 993–1012.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai, A. N., & Mellios, C. (2016). Valuation of commodity derivatives with an unobservable convenience yield. Computers & Operations Research, 66(2), 402–414.

  • Lee, C. J. (1981). The pricing of corporate debt: A note. Journal of Finance, 36(5), 1187–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, T. R., & Rodrigo, M. R. (2017). Alternative results for option pricing and implied volatility in jump-diffusion models using Mellin transforms. European Journal of Applied Mathematics, 28(5), 1–38.

  • Liao, S. L., & Huang, H. H. (2005). Pricing black-scholes options with correlated interest rate risk and credit risk: An extension. Quantitative Finance, 5(5), 443–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, Z., Ma, C., & Wu, Z. (2020). Closed-form analytical solutions for options on agricultural futures with seasonality and stochastic convenience yield. Chaos Solitons & Fractals, 137, 109849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mellios, C., Six, P., & Lai, A. N. (2016). Dynamic speculation and hedging in commodity futures markets with a stochastic convenience yield. European Journal of Operational Research., 250(2), 493–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1973). Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4(1), 141–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1974). On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance, 29(2), 449–470.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miltersen, K. R., & Schwartz, E. S. (1998). Pricing of options on commodity futures with stochastic term structures of convenience yields and interest rates. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 33(1), 33–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miura, R., & Yamauchi, H. (1998). The pricing formula for commodity-linked bonds with stochastic convenience yields and default risk. Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, 5(2), 129–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niu, H., & Wang, D. (2015). Pricing vulnerable options with correlated jump-diffusion processes depending on various states of the economy. Quantitative Finance, 16(7), 1129–1145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panini, R., & Srivastav, R. (2004). Option pricing with Mellin transnforms. Mathematical & Computer Modelling, 40(1), 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R., & Mundial, B.(1988). Pricing commodity bonds using Binomial option pricing. International Economics Department, The World Bank.

  • Schoene, M. F., & Spinler, S. (2017). A four-factor stochastic volatility model of commodity prices. Review of Derivatives Research, 20(2), 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, E., & Smith, J. E. (2000). Short-term variations and long-term dynamics in commodity prices. Management Science, 46(7), 893–911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, E. S. (1982). The pricing of commodity-linked bonds. Journal of Finance, 37(2), 525–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, E. S. (1997). The stochastic behavior of commodity prices: Implications for valuation and hedging. Journal of Finance, 52(3), 923–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sneddon, I. N. (1972). The use of integral transforms. McGraw-Hill.

  • Vasicek, O. (1977). An equilibrium characterization of the term structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(2), 177–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X., Song, S., & Wang, Y. (2017). The valuation of power exchange options with counterparty risk and jump risk. Journal of Futures Markets, 37(5), 499–521.

  • Yan, X. (2002). Valuation of commodity derivatives in a new multi-factor model. Review of Derivatives Research, 5(3), 251–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoon, J. H., & Kim, J. H. (2015). The pricing of vulnerable options with double Mellin transforms. Journal of Mathematical Analysis & Applications, 422(2), 838–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundations of China (Nos. 71431008 and 71790593), National Natural Science Innovation Research Group of China (No. 71521061), the Hunan Provincial Science & Technology Department of China (No. 2018GK1020), the China Scholarship Council (CSC, File No. 201608440451), the social science and humanity on Young Fund of the Ministry of Education, China (No. 15YJC790074) and the Natural Science Foundation of Guangdong Province, China (Nos. 2014A030310305 and 2020A1515010863).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zonggang Ma.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Review of the Mellin transform

To obtain help in solving the PDE (11), (28) and (46) with given terminal condition, we first summarize the definition and some basic properties of without proof for readers who are unfamiliar with the double Mellin transforms. The interested reader can refer to Erdelyi et al. (1954) and Sneddon (1972) as well.

Definition 1

(Definition of the Mellin transform and inverse transform) The Mellin transform \(\hat{g}(\omega )\) of a complex-valued function g(x) defined over positive reals is

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {M}_{x}[g(x);\omega ]:=\hat{g}(\omega )=\int _{0}^{\infty }g(x)x^{\omega -1}dx, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\omega \) is complex number. Then the function g(x) can be recovered from its Mellin transform by the inverse Mellin transformation formula

$$\begin{aligned} g(x):=\mathcal {M}_{x}^{-1}[\hat{g}(\omega )]=\frac{1}{2\pi i}\int _{c-i\infty }^{c+i\infty }\hat{g}(\omega )x^{-\omega }d\omega , \end{aligned}$$

with \(a<Re(\omega )\) and \(a<c_{1}<b\) exist.

Definition 2

(Definition of the double Mellin transform and inverse transform) The double Mellin transform \(\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})\) of a complex-valued function g(xy) defined over positive reals is

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {M}_{x,y}[g(x,y);\omega _{1},\omega _{2}]:=\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})=\int _{0}^{\infty }\int _{0}^{\infty }g(x,y)x^{\omega _{1}-1}y^{\omega _{2}-1}dxdy, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\omega _{1}\) and \(\omega _{2}\) are complex numbers. Then the function g(xy) can be recovered from its Mellin transform by the inverse Mellin transformation formula

$$\begin{aligned} g(x,y):=\mathcal {M}_{x,y}^{-1}[\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})]=\frac{1}{(2\pi i)^{2}}\int _{c_{1}-i\infty }^{c_{1}+i\infty }\int _{c_{2}-i\infty }^{c_{2}+i\infty }\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})x^{-\omega _{1}}y^{-\omega _{2}}d\omega _{1}d\omega _{2}, \end{aligned}$$

with \(a<Re(\omega _{1}), Re(\omega _{2})<b\) and \(a<c_{1},c_{2}<b\) exist.

Proposition 1

(Basic properties of the Mellin transform) Suppose that there exists a double Mellin transform of f(xy). Then the following relations hold:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {M}_{x,y}\left( x\frac{\partial ^{2}}{\partial x }f(x,y);\omega _{1},\omega _{2}\right)&=-\omega _{1}\hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2}),\\ \mathcal {M}_{x,y}\left( y\frac{\partial ^{2}}{\partial y }f(x,y);\omega _{1},\omega _{2}\right)&=-\omega _{2}\hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2}),\\ \mathcal {M}_{x,y}\left( xy\frac{\partial ^{2}}{\partial x \partial y}f(x,y);\omega _{1},\omega _{2}\right)&=\omega _{1}\omega _{2}\hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2}),\\ \mathcal {M}_{x,y}\left( x^{2}\frac{\partial ^{2}}{\partial x^{2}}f(x,y);\omega _{1},\omega _{2}\right)&=\omega _{1}(\omega _{1}+1) \hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2}),\\ \mathcal {M}_{x,y}\left( y^{2}\frac{\partial ^{2}}{\partial y^{2}}f(x,y);\omega _{1},\omega _{2}\right)&=\omega _{2}(\omega _{2}+1) \hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2}). \end{aligned}$$

Proposition 2

(Convolution of the Mellin transform) Let f(x) and g(x) be locally integrable functions on positive reals. \(\hat{f}(\omega )\) and \(\hat{g}(\omega )\) are two Mellin transforms of the functions f(x) and g(x), respectively. Then, the Mellin convolution is given by the inverse Mellin transform of \(\hat{f}(\omega _{1})\hat{g}(\omega _{1})\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} f(x)\vee g(x):&=\frac{1}{2\pi i}\int _{c-i\infty }^{c+i\infty }\hat{f}(\omega )\hat{g}(\omega )x^{-\omega }d\omega \\&=\int _{0}^{\infty }f\left( \frac{x}{\omega }\right) g(x)\frac{d\omega }{\omega }. \end{aligned}$$

Proposition 3

(Convolution of the double Mellin transform) Let f(xy) and g(xy) be locally integrable functions on positive reals. \(\hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})\) and \(\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})\) are two double Mellin transforms of the functions f(xy) and g(xy), respectively. Then, the double Mellin convolution is given by the inverse Mellin transform of \(\hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} f(x,y)\vee g(x,y):&=\frac{1}{(2\pi i)^{2}}\int _{c_{1}-i\infty }^{c_{1}+i\infty }\int _{c_{2}-i\infty }^{c_{2}+i\infty }\hat{f}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})\hat{g}(\omega _{1},\omega _{2})x^{-\omega _{1}}y^{-\omega _{2}}d\omega _{1}d\omega _{2}\\&=\int _{0}^{\infty }\int _{0}^{\infty }f(\frac{x}{\omega _{1}},\frac{y}{\omega _{2}})g(x,y)\frac{d\omega _{1}}{\omega _{1}}\frac{d\omega _{2}}{\omega _{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Proposition 4

(Inverse Mellin transform of exponential function) Given complex numbers \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \) with \(Re(\alpha )\ge 0\), let \(f(x)=\frac{1}{2\pi i}\int _{c-i\infty }^{c+i\infty }\hat{f}(s)x^{-s}ds\), where \(\hat{f}(s)=e^{\alpha (s+\beta )^{2}}\). Then

$$\begin{aligned} f(x)=\frac{1}{2\sqrt{\pi \alpha }}x^{\beta }e^{-\frac{(\ln x)^{2}}{4\alpha }} \end{aligned}$$

holds.

Proof of Theorem 3.1

Proof

First of all, let \(x=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{u}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\). By applying the change of variable from u to x , Eq. 20 becomes

$$\begin{aligned} B(\tau ,S,\delta )&=-\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int _{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}^{-\infty }(Se^{-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x}+F-K)e^{c^{*}-\frac{1}{2}x^{2}+\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}x}dx\nonumber \\&\quad -\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int _{\infty }^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}Fe^{c^{*}-\frac{1}{2}x^{2}+\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}x}dx\nonumber \\&=\frac{S}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{-\infty }e^{-\frac{1}{2}\left( x+\frac{2E(\tau )-G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right) ^{2}+E(\tau )-G_{2}(\tau )-\tau r}dx+\frac{F-K}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{-\infty }\nonumber \\&\qquad e^{-\frac{1}{2}\left( x-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right) ^{2}-\tau r}dx+\frac{F}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int _{\frac{\ln (\frac{S}{K})}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}^{\infty }e^{-\frac{1}{2}\left( x-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right) ^{2}-\tau r}dx\nonumber \\&=P(\tau ,\delta )S\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{-\infty }e^{-\frac{1}{2}(x+\frac{2E(\tau )-G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}})^{2}}dx-e^{-\tau r}K\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{-\infty }\nonumber \\&\qquad e^{-\frac{1}{2}\left( x-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right) ^{2}}dx+e^{-\tau r}F. \end{aligned}$$
(48)

Here

$$\begin{aligned} P(\tau ,\delta )&=e^{E(\tau )-G_{2}(\tau )-\tau r}\\&=e^{\left( \theta ^{*}+\gamma _{1}-\frac{\sigma _{\delta }^{2}}{2\kappa ^{2}}\right) (H(\tau )-\tau )-\frac{\sigma _{\delta }^{2}}{4\kappa }H^{2}(\tau )-\delta H(\tau )}\\&=A(\tau )\exp (-\delta H(\tau )), \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} A(\tau )&=\exp \left\{ \left( \theta ^{*}+\gamma _{1}-\frac{\sigma _{\delta }^{2}}{2\kappa ^{2}}\right) (H(\tau )-\tau )-\frac{\sigma _{\delta }^{2}}{4\kappa }H^{2}(\tau )\right\} \\ H(\tau )&=\frac{1-e^{-\kappa \tau }}{\kappa }. \end{aligned}$$

Then, \(B(S,\tau )\) is given by the formula

$$\begin{aligned} B(S,\tau )&=P(\tau ,\delta )S\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{-\infty }e^{-\frac{1}{2}(x'_{1})^{2}}dx-e^{- r\tau }K\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{-\infty }\nonumber \\&\qquad e^{-\frac{1}{2}(x'_{2})^{2}}dx+e^{-r\tau }F\nonumber \\&=P(\tau ,\delta )S\mathcal {N}(d_{1})-e^{-r\tau }K\mathcal {N}(d_{2})+e^{-r\tau }F, \end{aligned}$$
(49)

where \(d_{1}\) and \(d_{2}\) are given by

$$\begin{aligned} d_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +r\tau +\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(t)dt+\ln (P(\delta ,\tau ))}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\\ d_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +r\tau -\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(t)dt+\ln (P(\delta ,\tau ))}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 4.1

Proof

For \(\tau >0\), because \(E(\tau )>0\), so the inequality \(G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}>0\Leftrightarrow 4E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )>G^{2}(\tau )\). And \(E(\tau )=\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(t)dt\) and \(G_{1}(\tau )=\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\tau =\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\sigma _{v}^{2}dt\). From the Cauchy–Schwartz inequality, we have

$$\begin{aligned} 4E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )&=\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(t)dt\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\tau =\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\sigma _{v}^{2}dt\\&\ge \left( \int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }_{s}(t)\sigma _{v}dt\right) ^{2}\\&=\left( \int ^{\tau }_{0}\sqrt{\sigma _{v}^{2}(\sigma _{s}^{2}-2\rho _{s\delta }\sigma _{s}\sigma _{\delta }H(t)+\sigma ^{2}_{\delta }H^{2}(t))}dt\right) ^{2}, \end{aligned}$$

and we also know \(G(\tau )=\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}\tau -\gamma _{2}(\tau -H(\tau ))=\int ^{\tau }_{0}\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\rho _{\delta v}\sigma _{\delta }\sigma _{v}H(t)dt\). Therefore \(4E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )>G^{2}(\tau )\) is satisfied if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \nabla&=\sigma _{v}^{2}\left( \sigma _{s}^{2}-2\rho _{s\delta }\sigma _{s}\sigma _{\delta }H(t)+\sigma ^{2}_{\delta }H^{2}(t))-(\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\rho _{\delta v}\sigma _{\delta }\sigma _{v}H(t)\right) ^{2}\\&=\sigma _{v}^{2}\left[ (1-\rho _{\delta v}^{2})\sigma _{\delta }^{2}H^{2}(t)+2(\rho _{sv}\rho _{\delta v}-\rho _{s\delta })\sigma _{s}\sigma _{\delta }H(t)+(1-\rho _{sv}^{2})\sigma _{s}^{2}\right] >0. \end{aligned}$$

If we consider \(\nabla \) as a quadratic equation of \(\sigma _{\delta }H(t)\), then \(\nabla >0\) is satisfied if and only if \(\sigma _{v}^{2}>0\), \(1-\rho _{\delta v}^{2}>0\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta&=(2(\rho _{sv}\rho _{\delta v}-\rho _{s\delta })\sigma _{s})^{2}-4(1-\rho _{\delta v}^{2})(1-\rho _{sv}^{2})\sigma _{s}^{2}\\&=4\sigma _{s}^{2}\left[ \rho _{sv}^{2}+\rho _{\delta v}^{2}+\rho _{s\delta }^{2}-2\rho _{sv}\rho _{\delta v}\rho _{s\delta }-1\right] <0 \end{aligned}$$

are satisfied. Because \(\sigma _{v}^{2}>0\) for \(\tau >0\) is satisfied, and according to conditions (25), the two later conditions are obviously true. Consequently, \(G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}>0\) has been verified. \(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 4.1

Proof

First of all, let \(y=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{w}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}\) and \(\rho =\frac{G(\tau )}{2\sqrt{E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )}}\). By applying the change of variables from u and w to x and y, \(I_{B}^{1}(t,S,V,\delta )\) of Eq. 41 becomes

$$\begin{aligned}&I_{B}^{1}(t,S,V,\delta )=\frac{1}{2\pi }\sqrt{\frac{G_{1}(\tau )}{{G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln (\frac{S}{K})}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}} e^{\eta }\exp \left\{ -\frac{(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )(G_{2}(\tau )-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x)}{2E(\tau )})^{2}}{4(G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )})}\right\} \nonumber \\&\qquad (Se^{-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x}+F-K)\exp \Bigg \{\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )(G_{2}(\tau )-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x)}{2E(\tau )})}{2(G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )})}\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}x\Bigg \}e^{-\frac{1}{2}x^{2}}e^{-\frac{G_{1}(\tau )y^{2}}{2\left( G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}\right) }}dxdy\nonumber \\&=\frac{S}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}} \int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}}\exp \Bigg \{\eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) -\Bigg [\sqrt{2E(\tau )}-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) \frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})} \Bigg ]x +\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) }{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{\rho xy}{(1-\rho ^{2})}-\frac{(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\Bigg \}dxdy\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{F-K}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}} \int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}}\exp \Bigg \{\eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) -\Bigg [\frac{(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\quad \cdot \frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\Bigg ]x+\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}+\frac{\rho xy}{(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\quad -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\Bigg \}dxdy. \end{aligned}$$
(50)

To evaluate the first term in Eq. 50, we introduce an auxiliary function

$$\begin{aligned}&I_{B}^{10}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )=\frac{S}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln (\frac{S}{K})}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln (\frac{V}{D^{*}})}{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}} \exp \left\{ \eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) -\left[ \sqrt{2E(\tau )}-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right. \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad +\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) \frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})} \right] x+\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\quad \left. +\frac{\rho xy}{(1-\rho ^{2})}-\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right\} dxdy. \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Then the exponent of the integrand of Eq. 51 can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} M_{1}-\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}[(x+a_{1})^{2}+(y+b_{1})^{2}]+\frac{\rho }{1-\rho ^{2}}(x+a_{1})(y+b_{1}), \end{aligned}$$

where \(a_{1}\), \(b_{1}\) and \( M_{1}\) are given by

$$\begin{aligned} a_{1}&=\frac{2E(\tau )-G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}},\\ b_{1}&=\frac{G(\tau )-G_{1}(\tau )-G_{3}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}},\\ M_{1}&=\eta -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}+\frac{a_{1}^{2}+b^{2}_{1}}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}-\frac{\rho a_{1}b_{1}}{1-\rho ^{2}}\\&=E(\tau )-G_{2}(\tau )-\tau r\\&=\ln (P(\delta , \tau )). \end{aligned}$$

Similarly, to evaluate the second term in Eq. 50, we introduce an auxiliary function

$$\begin{aligned} I_{B}^{11}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )&=\frac{F-K}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2B_{1}(\tau )}}} \exp \left\{ \eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) -\left[ \frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) }{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right. \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad \cdot \frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right] x+\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}+\frac{\rho xy}{2E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\quad \left. -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right\} dxdy. \end{aligned}$$
(52)

Then the exponent of the integrand of Eq. 52 can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} M_{2}-\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}[(x+a_{2})^{2}+(y+b_{2})^{2}]+\frac{\rho }{1-\rho ^{2}}(x+a_{2})(y+b_{2}), \end{aligned}$$

where \(a_{2}\), \(b_{2}\) and \( M_{2}\) are given by

$$\begin{aligned} a_{2}&=-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}},\\ b_{2}&=-\frac{G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}},\\ M_{2}&=\eta -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}+\frac{a_{2}^{2}+b^{2}_{2}}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}-\frac{\rho a_{2}b_{2}}{1-\rho ^{2}}\\&=-\tau r. \end{aligned}$$

Then, \(I_{B}^{1}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\) is given by the formula

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{lll} I_{B}^{1}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )&{}= P(\delta ,\tau )S\frac{1}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int _{-\infty }^{a'_{1}}\int _{-\infty }^{a'_{2}}e^{-\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x_{1}^{'2}-2\rho x'_{1}y'_{1}+y_{1}^{'2})}dx'_{1}dy'_{1}\\ &{}\qquad +e^{-r\tau }(F-K)\frac{1}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int _{-\infty }^{b'_{1}}\int _{-\infty }^{b'_{2}}e^{-\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x_{2}^{'2}-2\rho x'_{2}y'_{2}+y_{2}^{'2})}dx'_{2}dy'_{2}\\ &{}=P(\delta ,\tau )S\mathcal {N}_{2}(a'_{1},b'_{1},\rho )+e^{-r\tau }(F-K)\mathcal {N}_{2}(a'_{2},b'_{2},\rho ), \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(53)

where

$$\begin{aligned} a'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P(\delta ,\tau )+\tau r+\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\\ b'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}-\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau +\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\gamma _{2}(\tau -H(\tau ))}{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }},\\ a'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P(\delta ,\tau )+\tau r-\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\\ b'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}-\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau }{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }}. \end{aligned}$$

As with the same procedure for \(I_{B}^{1}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\), then \(I_{B}^{2}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\), \(I_{B}^{3}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\) and \(I_{B}^{4}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\) of Eq. 41 are given respectively,

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{lll} I_{B}^{2}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )&{}=\frac{F}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int ^{\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2B_{1}(\tau )}}} \exp \left\{ \eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) -\left[ \frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) }{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right. \right. \\ &{}\left. \quad \cdot \frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}-\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right] x+\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}+\frac{\rho xy}{2E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\\ &{}\left. \quad -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right\} dxdy\\ &{}=e^{-r\tau }F\mathcal {N}_{2}(-c'_{2},d'_{2},-\rho ), \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(54)

where

$$\begin{aligned} c'_{2}&=a'_{2}, d'_{2}=b'_{2}. I_{B}^{3}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}\frac{1}{2\pi }\sqrt{\frac{G_{1}(\tau )}{{G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln (\frac{S}{K})}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}}_{\infty } \exp \left\{ -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )(G_{2}(\tau )-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x)}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4\left( G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}\right) }\right\} \nonumber \\&\qquad e^{\eta -\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}y}\left( Se^{-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x}+F-K\right) \exp \Bigg \{\frac{y\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )(G_{2}(\tau )-\sqrt{2E(\tau )}x)}{2E(\tau )})}{2\left( G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )}\right) }\nonumber \\&\qquad +\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}x\Bigg \}e^{-\frac{1}{2}x^{2}}e^{-\frac{G_{1}(\tau )y^{2}}{2(G_{1}(\tau )-\frac{G^{2}(\tau )}{4E(\tau )})}}dxdy\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}S\frac{1}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{\frac{\ln (\frac{V}{D^{*}})}{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}}_{\infty } \exp \Bigg \{\eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) -\Bigg [\sqrt{2E(\tau )}\nonumber \\&\qquad -\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}+ \frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) \frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})} \Bigg ]x+[\frac{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\qquad -\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}]y+\frac{\rho xy}{2E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}-\frac{(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\Bigg \}dxdy\nonumber \\&\qquad +\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}\frac{F-K}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int ^{-\infty }_{\frac{\ln (\frac{S}{K})}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}}_{\infty } \exp \left\{ \eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) +\left[ \frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right. \right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \left. -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) }{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\right] x+\left[ \frac{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \left. \left. -\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}\right] y+\frac{\rho xy}{2E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}-\frac{(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\right\} dxdy\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}(P'(\delta ,\tau )Se^{(r+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v})\tau }\mathcal {N}_{2}(e'_{1},-f'_{1},-\rho )\nonumber \\&\qquad +e^{-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}\tau }(F-K)\mathcal {N}_{2}(e'_{2},-f'_{2},-\rho )), \end{aligned}$$
(55)

where

$$\begin{aligned} P'(\delta ,\tau )&=A'(\tau )\exp (-\delta H(\tau )), \nonumber \\ A'(\tau )&=\exp \left\{ \left( \theta ^{*}+\gamma _{1}+\gamma _{2}-\frac{\sigma _{\delta }^{2}}{2\kappa ^{2}}\right) (H(\tau )-\tau )-\frac{\sigma _{\delta }^{2}}{4\kappa }H^{2}(\tau )\right\} ,\nonumber \\ e'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P'(\delta ,\tau )+\tau r+\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}\tau }{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\nonumber \\ f'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau +\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\gamma _{2}(\tau -H(\tau ))}{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }},\nonumber \\ e'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P'(\delta ,\tau )+\tau r-\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}\tau }{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\nonumber \\ f'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau }{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }}. \nonumber \\ I_{B}^{4}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )&=\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}\frac{F}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) }{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}}_{\infty }\int ^{\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) }{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}}}_{\infty } \exp \Bigg \{\eta -\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}+y^{2}) +\Bigg [\frac{G_{2}(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\nonumber \\&\quad -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) }{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\frac{G(\tau )}{\sqrt{2E(\tau )}}\Bigg ]x+[\frac{\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}(G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )})}{2G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\nonumber \\&\quad -\sqrt{2G_{1}(\tau )}]y+\frac{\rho xy}{2E(\tau )G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})} -\frac{\left( G_{1}(\tau )+G_{3}(\tau )-\frac{G(\tau )G_{2}(\tau )}{2E(\tau )}\right) ^{2}}{4G_{1}(\tau )(1-\rho ^{2})}\Bigg \}dxdy\nonumber \\&=\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}e^{-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}\tau }F\mathcal {N}_{2}(-g'_{2},-h'_{2},\rho ), \end{aligned}$$
(56)

where

$$\begin{aligned} g'_{2}=e'_{2},h'_{2}=f'_{2}. \end{aligned}$$

Finally, we can recombine \(I_{B}^{1}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\), \(I_{B}^{2}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\), \(I_{B}^{3}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\) and \(I_{B}^{4}(\tau ,S,V,\delta )\) in the following formula:

$$\begin{aligned} B(S,V,\delta ,\tau )&=P(\delta ,\tau )S\mathcal {N}_{2}(a'_{1},b'_{1},\rho )+e^{-r\tau }(F-K)\mathcal {N}_{2}(a'_{2},b'_{2},\rho )\nonumber \\&\quad +\,e^{-r\tau }F\mathcal {N}_{2}(-c'_{2},d'_{2},-\rho )\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}(P'(\delta ,\tau )Se^{(r-\lambda _{1}\sigma _{v}+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v})\tau }\mathcal {N}_{2}(e'_{1},-f'_{1},-\rho )\nonumber \\&\quad +\,e^{-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}\tau }(F-K)\mathcal {N}_{2}(e'_{2},-f'_{2},-\rho ))\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\frac{(1-\alpha )V}{D}e^{-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}\tau }F\mathcal {N}_{2}(-g'_{2},-h'_{2},\rho ), \end{aligned}$$
(57)

where \(\mathcal {N}_{2}\) is the standard bivariate normal cumulative distribution as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {N}_{2}(a,b,\rho )=\frac{1}{2\pi \sqrt{1-\rho ^{2}}}\int _{-\infty }^{a}\int _{-\infty }^{b}e^{-\frac{1}{2(1-\rho ^{2})}(x^{2}-2\rho xy+y^{2})}dxdy, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \rho&=\frac{(\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\gamma _{2})\tau +\gamma _{2}H(\tau )}{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds\tau }},\\ a'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P(\delta ,\tau )+r\tau +\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\\ b'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\gamma _{2}-\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau +\gamma _{2}H(\tau )}{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }},\\ a'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P(\delta ,\tau )+r\tau -\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(S)dS}},\\ b'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}-\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau }{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }},\\ e'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P'(\delta ,\tau )+(r+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v})\tau +\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\\ f'_{1}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v}-\gamma _{2}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau +\gamma _{2}H(\tau )}{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }},\\ e'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{S}{K}\right) +\ln P'(\delta ,\tau )+ (r+\rho _{sv}\sigma _{s}\sigma _{v})\tau -\frac{1}{2}\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}{\sqrt{\int ^{\tau }_{0}\hat{\sigma }^{2}_{s}(s)ds}},\\ f'_{2}&=\frac{\ln \left( \frac{V}{D^{*}}\right) +\left( r-\lambda _{v}\sigma _{v}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{v}^{2}\right) \tau }{\sigma _{v}\sqrt{\tau }},\\ c'_{2}&=a'_{2}, d'_{2}=b'_{2},g'_{2}=e'_{2},h'_{2}=f'_{2}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ma, Z., Ma, C. & Wu, Z. Pricing commodity-linked bonds with stochastic convenience yield, interest rate and counterparty credit risk: application of Mellin transform methods. Rev Deriv Res 25, 47–91 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11147-021-09181-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11147-021-09181-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation