Skip to main content
Log in

Input price discrimination and non-controlling vertical shareholding

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study how input price discrimination and non-controlling, vertical shareholding interact. We first discuss the implications of the invariance principle (Greenlee and Raskovich in Eur Econ Rev 50:1017–1041, 2006) for input price discrimination across independent downstream markets. We show that, in the short term, price discrimination based on non-controlling, backward shareholding is more likely to improve welfare than other forms of input price discrimination, because it results in a positive consumption reallocation effect. However, if the derived demand for the input is convex, and less so as output increases, input price discrimination is irrelevant in the long term, because the ownership structures that prevail under discriminatory and uniform input pricing yield the same market outcome. The main contribution of the paper is to show that input price discrimination matters, in the short and the long term, if downstream firms compete in prices. In particular, we find that input price discrimination improves welfare in the short term, for any given ownership structure, and in the long term, through its impact on shareholding.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, in particular, European Commission (2016) that stresses that “[economic theories of harm] describe situations where the acquisition of minority shareholdings allows companies to hamper competitors’ access to inputs—in case of partial backward integration—or customers in case of partial upward integration.”

  2. See Sect. 5.3 for a discussion.

  3. The assumption of linear prices is in line with most of the literature on input price discrimination since Katz (1987) and DeGraba (1990), with the notable exceptions of Inderst and Shaffer (2009) and Herweg and Müller (2014). Likewise, most of the literature on non-controlling vertical shareholding assumes linear input prices, although two-part tariffs have been discussed, in particular by Hunold and Stahl (2016) and Hunold (2020).

  4. Similar results are found in the literature on trade policy and the so-called “most-favored nation” clause. In particular, it was shown that, under Cournot competition with homogeneous products, importing countries impose higher tariffs on lower cost exporters (Choi 1995; Saggi 2004). Besides, in the input price discrimination literature, the case of Cournot competition with homogeneous products has been extended to situations where downstream firms differ in their ability to use the input provided by an upstream monopolist and in the cost of their other inputs (Yoshida 2000; Valletti 2003). Finally, the result that a monopolistic input provider discriminates against lower cost retailers can easily be extended to downstream price or quantity competition if products are imperfect substitutes and demand functions linear.

  5. Under cost-based retail price discrimination (or “differential pricing”), the sign of the reallocation effect depends on the pass-through rate from marginal cost to the equilibrium price (Chen and Schwartz 2015; Chen et al. 2019). Indeed, if some markets are more costly to serve than others, then discrimination unambiguously reallocates consumption from high-cost to low-cost markets. However, the latter have a higher markup if and only if the pass-through is lower than one. Likewise, if a monopolistic input provider serves downstream firms with different levels of marginal costs, the pass-through determines which downstream firm has a higher markup for all given set of input prices. Then, the curvature of the derived demand for the input determines the direction of the reallocation effect (Gaudin and Lestage 2021).

  6. Note that, under differential pricing in intermediate goods markets, the consumption reallocation effect is also positive if downstream firms sell a homogeneous product and compete à la Cournot ( Li 2017). It may also be positive if input providers discriminate by resale markets (Miklos-Thal and Shaffer 2019).

  7. Brito et al. (2019) show that partial horizontal shareholding can reduce competition “more than a monopoly”.

  8. By “effective input price”, we mean the price effectively paid by a downstream firm, given that it claims a share of the upstream profit. If the stated input price is w and a downstream firm owns a share \(\alpha \) of the input provider, then the effective input price is \((1-\alpha )w\).

  9. This assumption simplifies the analysis, but qualitatively similar results can be obtained if each downstream firm is owned by more than one shareholder.

  10. Result1-i. was already discussed by Greenlee and Raskovich (2006), along with the fact that shareholding has no incidence on the equilibrium under price or quantity competition with symmetric shares or linear demands. Flath (1989), reached a similar conclusion under Cournot competition and constant-elasticity demand.

  11. The existence of a positive reallocation effect is a distinctive, but not exclusive property of shareholding-based input price discrimination. In particular, Li (2017) shows that if input providers incur different costs to serves different downstream firms, input price discrimination also reallocates consumption in a welfare enhancing direction if downstream firms compete à la Cournot. The reallocation effect may also be positive if input providers discriminate by resale markets (Miklos-Thal and Shaffer 2019).

  12. Both decentralized, bilateral bargaining and centralized bargaining have been studied in the literature. See in particular Hunold and Stahl (2016) and Hunold (2020), where both cases are discussed. In our framework, centralized bargaining greatly simplifies the determination of the equilibrium ownership structures.

  13. Linear demands are adopted for the sake of tractability. As shown in the remainder to the paper, such model is rich enough to illustrate that: i. unlike the case of independent downstream markets, input price discrimination affects the long term market outcome when downstream firms compete in prices; ii. whether the regulator aims at maximizing consumer surplus or welfare matters; iii. whether firms compete in prices or quantities also matters.

  14. Unlike the case of independent markets, the reallocation effect is not always positive for any marginal increase in the degree of input price discrimination. However, the total reallocation effect induced by a shift from uniform to discriminatory input pricing is positive (see Sect. 7.1 of the Appendix).

  15. By contrast, in the case of quantity competition, quantities are strategic substitutes and total output decreases with input price discrimination (see Sect. 5.1).

  16. The case where \(\mu =0\), corresponds to independent downstream markets. Then, as shown in Sect. 3, input price discrimination leaves the total number of consumers unchanged if demand is linear.

  17. Assuming that a firm is controlled by the majority shareholder, 1/2 represents the highest ownership share that does not result in control of downstream firm 2 over the input provider.

  18. As in the case of independent markets, under quantity competition with linear demands function, total output remains constant, for equal, opposite sign variations of the effective input prices. Since quantities are strategic substitutes, a lower effective input price \({\widehat{w}}_{i}\) increases the demand of downstream firm i, but also reduces that of the other downstream firm. This opportunity cost is higher when \({\widehat{w}}_{1}\) decreases than when \({\widehat{w}}_{2}\) does. Indeed, the equilibrium effective input prices are such that, for all \(i\in \{1,2\}\),

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{u}}{\partial {\hat{w}}_{i}}=\frac{1}{1-\alpha _{i}}\left( q_{i}+\frac{\partial q_{i}}{\partial {\hat{w}}_{i}}{\hat{w}}_{i}\right) +\frac{1}{1-\alpha _{-i}}\frac{\partial q_{-i}}{\partial {\hat{w}}_{i}}{\hat{w}}_{-i}=0. \end{aligned}$$

    Since, \(0<\partial q_{1}/\partial {\hat{w}}_{2}=\partial q_{2}/\partial {\hat{w}}_{1}<-\partial q_{1}/\partial {\hat{w}}_{1}=-\partial q_{2}/\partial {\hat{w}}_{2}\), \(\alpha _{1}\le \alpha _{2}\) implies \({\widehat{w}}_{2}\le {\widehat{w}}_{1}.\) Therefore, in equilibrium, \({\widehat{w}}_{2}\le {\widehat{w}}_{1}\), which implies that \({\widehat{w}}_{1}\) raises more than \({\widehat{w}}_{2}\) falls, and that total output decreases as the degree of input price discrimination increases.

  19. See Gaudin and White (2021), for an example of such two-part tariffs that only extract a share of the buyer surplus.

References

  • Aguirre, I., Cowan, S., & Vickers, J. (2010). Monopoly price discrimination and demand curvature. The American Economic Review, 100, 1601–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar, J., Schmalz, M. C., & Tecu, I. (2018). Anticompetitive effects of common ownership. The Journal of Finance, 73, 1513–1565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brito, D., Cabral, L., & Vasconcelos, H. (2016). Competitive effects of partial control in an input supplier. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brito, D., Ribeiro, R., & Vasconcelos, H. (2019). Can partial horizontal ownership lessen competition more than a monopoly? Economics Letters, 176, 90–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., Li, J., & Schwartz, M. (2019). Competitive differential pricing. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Schwartz, M. (2015). Differential pricing when costs differ: A welfare analysis. The RAND Journal of Economics, 46, 442–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, F. K., & Wang, X. (1994). Adjusted concavity and the output effect under monopolistic price discrimination. Southern Economic Journal, 60, 1048–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. (1995). Optimal tariffs and the choice of technology Discriminatory tariffs vs. the ‘Most Favored Nation’ clause. Journal of International Economics, 38, 143–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, S. (2016). Welfare-increasing third-degree price discrimination. RAND Journal of Economics, 47, 326–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeGraba, P. (1990). Input market price discrimination and the choice of technology. The American Economic Review, 80, 1246–1253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dertwinkel-Kalt, M., Haucap, J., & Wey, C. (2015). Raising rivals’ cost through buyer power. Economics Letters, 126, 181–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission, E. C. (2014). Towards more effective EU merger control. White Paper.

  • European Commission, E. C. (2016). Support study for impact assessment concerning the review of Merger Regulation regarding minority shareholdings. Report.

  • Fiocco, R. (2016). The strategic value of partial vertical integration. European Economic Review, 89, 284–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flath, D. (1989). Vertical integration by means of shareholding interlocks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 7, 369–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foros, O., Kind, H. J., & Shaffer, G. (2011). Mergers and partial ownership. European Economic Review, 55, 916–926.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudin, G. (2018). Vertical bargaining and retail competition: What drives countervailing power? Economic Journal, 128, 2380–2413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudin, G., & Lestage, R. (2021). Input price discrimination, demand forms, and welfare. Journal of Industrial Economics (forthcoming).

  • Gaudin, G., & White, A. (2021). Vertical agreements and user access. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics (forthcoming).

  • Greenlee, P., & Raskovich, A. (2006). Partial vertical ownership. European Economic Review, 50, 1017–1041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herweg, F., & Müller, D. (2014). Price discrimination in input markets: Quantity discounts and private information. Economic Journal, 124, 776–804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunold, M. (2020). Non-discriminatory pricing, partial backward ownership, and entry deterrence. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 70, 102615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunold, M., & Shekhar, S. (2018). Supply chain innovations and partial ownership. DICE discussion paper, Vol. 281.

  • Hunold, M., & Stahl, K. (2016). Passive vertical integration and strategic delegation. The RAND Journal of Economics, 47, 891–913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Höffler, F., & Kranz, S. (2011). Legal unbundling can be a golden mean between vertical integration and ownership separation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29, 576–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderst, R., & Shaffer, G. (2009). Market power, price discrimination, and allocative efficiency in intermediate-goods markets. The RAND Journal of Economics, 40, 658–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderst, R., & Valletti, T. (2009). Price discrimination in input markets. The RAND Journal of Economics, 40, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. L. (1987). The welfare effects of third-degree price discrimination in intermediate good markets. The American Economic Review, 77, 154–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy, N., Spiegel, Y., & Gilo, D. (2018). Partial vertical integration, ownership structure, and foreclosure. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 10, 132–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y. (2014). A note on third degree price discrimination in intermediate good markets. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 62, 554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y. (2017). Differential pricing in intermediate good markets. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 65, 585–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., & Shuai, J. (2020). Input price discrimination with horizontal shareholding. New York: Mimeo.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Miklos-Thal, J., & Shaffer, G. (2019). Input price discrimination by resale market. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, D. P. (2014). The welfare effects of third-degree price discrimination in intermediate good markets: the case of bargaining. The RAND Journal of Economics, 45, 92–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, D. P., & Salop, S. C. (2000). Competitive effects of partial ownership: Financial interest and corporate control. Antitrust Law Journal, 67, 559–613.

    Google Scholar 

  • OFCOM. (2018) Progress on delivering a more independent Openreach. Update on the legal separation of Openreach. Implementation report.

  • Pigou, A. C. (1920). The economics of welfare. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1933). The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saggi, K. (2004). Tariffs and the most favored nation clause. Journal of International Economics, 63, 341–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, R. (1981). Output and welfare implications of monopolistic third-degree price discrimination. The American Economic Review, 71, 242–247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, M. (1990). Third-degree price discrimination and output: Generalizing a welfare result. The American Economic Review, 80, 1259–1262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shin, K. (2002). The treatment of market power in Korea. Review of Industrial Organization, 21, 113–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shubik, M., & Levitan, R. (1980). Market structure and behavior. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Spiegel, Y. (2013). Partial vertical integration and ownership structure. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletti, T. M. (2003). Input price discrimination with downstream Cournot competitors. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21, 969–988.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (1985). Price discrimination and social welfare. The American Economic Review, 75, 870–875.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoshida, Y. (2000). Third-degree price discrimination in input markets: Output and welfare. The American Economic Review, 90, 240–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Romain Lestage.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I thank the editor, Menahem Spiegel, and an anonymous referee for their helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to Takanori Adachi, Germain Gaudin, Jianpei Li, Youping Li, David Myatt, Peng Yuhan, as well as participants at the 2019 Asia Meeting of the Econometric Society and research seminars at East China University of Science and Technology, University of International Business and Economics, and Kwansei Gakuin University, for valuable remarks and discussions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix, we detail the cases of downstream price competition (Sect. 7.1 in Appendix) and quantity competition (Sect. 7.2 in Appendix).We also present the study of forward shareholding (Sect. 7.3 in Appendix). We consider imperfect product substitution, as modeled by Shubik and Levitan (1980). In this model, a representative consumer has quasi-linear utility

$$\begin{aligned} U=q_{1}+q_{2}-\frac{1}{1+\mu }\left( q_{1}^{2}+q_{2}^{2}+\frac{\mu }{2}\left( q_{1}+q_{2}\right) ^{2}\right) +I, \end{aligned}$$

where I is the consumption of other goods than those provided by downstream firms 1 and 2. Parameter \(\mu \in [0,\infty )\) describes the degree of product substitutability. If \(\mu =0\), then downstream firms operate in independent markets. If \(\mu \rightarrow \infty \), then they sell perfect substitutes.

1.1 Price competition

Maximization of the representative consumer’s utility function yields

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}=\left( 1-p_{i}-\mu \left( p_{i}-\left( p_{i}+p_{-i}\right) /2\right) \right) /2,\,\forall i\in \{1,2\}. \end{aligned}$$

Equilibrium downstream prices are

$$\begin{aligned} p_{i}= & {} (8+8(1-\alpha _{i})w_{i}+\mu ^{2}((8-8\alpha _{i}+\alpha _{-i})w_{i}+2(1+2\alpha _{i}-\alpha _{-i})w_{-i})\\&+\,2\mu (5+8(1-\alpha _{i})w_{i}+(1+2\alpha _{i}-\alpha _{-i})w_{-i}))/(16+32\mu +15\mu ^{2}) \end{aligned}$$

and equilibrium input prices satisfy \(q_{i}(w_{i},w_{-i})+w_{i}(\partial q_{i}/\partial w_{i})+w_{-i}(\partial q_{-i}/\partial w_{i})=0\).

If \(\alpha _{1}\le \alpha _{2}\), then \(w_{1}\le w_{2}\) at the unconstrained equilibrium. As in Sect. 3, we denote \(r\equiv w_{2}-w_{1}\) the constrained degree of input price discrimination. By total differentiation of the upstream firm’s first-order condition, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dw_{1}(r)}{dr}=-\frac{dw_{2}(r)}{dr}=\frac{16+6(6+\alpha _{1})\mu +(20+7\alpha _{1})\mu ^{2}-\alpha _{2}(16+34\mu +17\mu ^{2})}{(2(4+5\mu )(-4(1+\mu )+\alpha _{1}(2+\mu )+\alpha _{2}(2+\mu )))}<0. \end{aligned}$$

If follows that \(dq_{1}(r)/dr>0\) and \(dq_{2}(r)/dr<0\).

For all \(r\in [0,r^{*}]\), the total equilibrium output is

$$\begin{aligned} Q(r)=\frac{8(1+\mu )(4+5\mu )+(\alpha _{2}-\alpha _{1})\mu (2+\mu )(2+3\mu )r}{8(4+3\mu )(4+5\mu )}, \end{aligned}$$

which increases with r for all \(\alpha _{1}\le \alpha _{2}\): As the degree of input price discrimination increases, \(q_{1}(r)\) increases more than \(q_{2}(r)\) decreases, and total output increases.

Proof of Proposition 1

i. For all given ownership structure, the relationship between welfare and the degree of input price discrimination is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW(r)}{dr}=\underset{Output\,effect}{\underbrace{\frac{dU}{dq_{1}}\frac{dQ}{dr}}}\underset{Reallocation\,effect}{\underbrace{-\frac{dq_{2}}{dr}\left( \frac{\partial U}{\partial q_{1}}-\frac{\partial U}{\partial q_{2}}\right) }}, \end{aligned}$$

where the derivatives are evaluated at \(q_{1}(r),q_{2}(r)\). This mirrors Eq. (1), which was introduced to study the case of independent markets.

The first term on the RHS is positive, because of non-satiation and because total output increases with input price discrimination. Unlike the case of independent markets, a marginal increase in r does not always yield a positive reallocation effect. Indeed, \(\partial U/\partial q_{1}-\partial U/\partial q_{2}=2(q_{2}(r)-q_{2}(r))/(1+\mu )\) and \(q_{2}(r)-q_{1}(r)\ge 0\) iff r is low enough. However, it is just a matter of computation to show that \(\intop _{0}^{r^{*}}\left( \partial U/\partial q_{1}-\partial U/\partial q_{2}\right) dr>0\), which implies that the total reallocation effect induced by a shift from uniform to unconstrained discriminatory input pricing is positive. Therefore, \(W(r^{*})-W(0)>0\): discriminatory input pricing improves welfare for all given ownership structure.

ii. We just need to prove the existence of cases where discriminatory input pricing reduces consumer surplus. This is the case if \(\mu =0\), that is, for independent downstream markets: then, we find \(CS(r^{*})-CS(0)=-((\alpha _{2}-\alpha _{1})^{2}/(32(2-\alpha _{1}-\alpha _{2})^{2}))<0\). This also occurs for strictly positive values of \(\mu \), that is, if the downstream products are imperfect substitutes. For example, if \(\mu =1/2\) and \(\alpha _{1}=0\), we find

$$\begin{aligned}&CS(r^{*})-CS(0)\\&\quad = -\frac{15120\alpha _{2}^{2}(186316416-400473216\alpha _{2}+182031096\alpha _{2}^{2}+32045260\alpha _{2}^{3}-256725\alpha _{2}^{4})}{20449(12-5\alpha _{2})^{2}(20592-20592\alpha _{2}-35\alpha _{2}^{2})^{2}}\\&\quad <0, \end{aligned}$$

which is negative for all \(\alpha _{2}<1/2\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

We now study the impact of shareholding on total industry profit \(\pi \). We find that the derivative of \(\pi \) with respect to \(\alpha _{i}\) is zero if and only if \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\), both under uniform and discriminatory input pricing. Besides, at \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\), we find

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}\pi }{d\alpha _{i}^{2}} =-\frac{(1+\mu )^{2}(2+3\mu )}{(4+5\mu )^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+\mu ))^{2}}<0 \end{aligned}$$

in the former case and

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{d^{2}\pi }{d\alpha _{i}^{2}} =\frac{\mu (1+\mu )^{2}(2+3\mu )(\alpha _{i}(64+136\mu +78\mu ^{2}+11\mu ^{3})-2(32+84\mu +69\mu ^{2}+17\mu ^{3}))}{(4+3\mu )^{3}(4+5\mu )^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+\mu ))^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+3\mu ))}\\&\quad >0 \end{aligned}$$

in the latter. It follows that total industry profit is maximized at \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\) under uniform input pricing. By contrast, under discriminatory input pricing, it is minimized at \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\) and the more asymmetric the ownership structure, the higher the total industry profit. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

Like the derivatives of total industry profit, that of consumer surplus and welfare with respect to \(\alpha _{i}\) are zero if and only if \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\). At such symmetric ownership structure, we find, under uniform input pricing,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}CS}{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}=-\frac{2+\mu }{2+3\mu }\frac{d^{2}W}{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}=\frac{(1+\mu )(2+\mu )(2+3\mu )}{4(4+5\mu )^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+\mu ))^{2}}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Under discriminatory input pricing, we find

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}CS}{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}= & {} \frac{\mu (4+12\mu +11\mu ^{2}+3\mu ^{3})}{4(4+3\mu )^{3}(4+5\mu )^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+\mu ))^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+3\mu ))}\\&\times (-2(32+172\mu +327\mu ^{2}+267\mu ^{3}+80\mu ^{4})\\&+\,\alpha _{i}(64+312\mu +522\mu ^{2}+353\mu ^{3}+80\mu ^{4})))>0. \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}W}{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}= & {} \frac{\mu (2+5\mu +3\mu ^{2})(-2(192+840\mu +1438\mu ^{2}+1205\mu ^{3}+495\mu ^{4}+80\mu ^{5})}{4(4+3\mu )^{3}(4+5\mu )^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+\mu ))^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+3\mu ))}\\&+\,\frac{\alpha _{i}(384+1488\mu +2212\mu ^{2}+1584\mu ^{3}+557\mu ^{4}+80\mu ^{5}))}{4(4+3\mu )^{3}(4+5\mu )^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+\mu ))^{2}(-2(1+\mu )+\alpha _{i}(2+3\mu ))}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the more asymmetric the ownership structure, the higher the consumer surplus, under both uniform and discriminatory input pricing. In the latter case, this is also true for welfare. By contrast, under uniform input pricing, the more asymmetric the ownership structure, the higher welfare. \(\square \)

1.2 Quantity competition

We now consider that the downstream firms compete in quantities. The inverse demand derived from the representative consumer’s utility function is \(p_{i}=1-(2q_{i}+\mu Q)/(1+\mu )\forall i\in \{1,2\}\). Equilibrium quantities are

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}(w_{i},w_{-i})=\frac{(\mu +1)(2(\alpha _{i}-1)(\mu +2)w_{i}-\alpha _{-i}\mu {{w_{-i}}}+\mu w_{-i}+\mu +4)}{(\mu +4)(3\mu +4)} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} w_{i}(r)=\frac{8-\mu \left( (2+\alpha _{i}-3\alpha _{-i})r-2\right) -8(1-\alpha _{-i})r}{2(2-\alpha _{1}-\alpha _{2})(4+\mu )}, \end{aligned}$$

for all \(r\in [0,r^{*}]\). At the subgame perfect equilibrium, total output is

$$\begin{aligned} Q(r)=\frac{(1+\mu )(8+\mu (2+r\alpha _{1}-r\alpha _{2}))}{6\mu ^{2}+32\mu +32}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Lemma 1

The welfare effect of input price discrimination can be described as follows. On the one hand, total output decreases: \(dQ/dr\le 0.\) On the other hand, the consumption reallocation effect is positive, because \(q_{2}(r)-q_{1}(r)\ge 0\,\forall r\in [0,r^{*}]\). It is just a matter of computation to show that there exist a unique threshold \({\widetilde{\mu }}\) such that \(W(0)\le W(r^{*})\) if and only if \(\mu \le {\widetilde{\mu }}\). \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

We now turn to the relationship between total industry profit and welfare on the one hand, and ownership structure on the other hand. As in case of price competition, we find that the derivatives of total industry profit and welfare with respect to the ownership share \(\alpha _{i}\) are zero if and only if downstream firms own equal shares of the input provider. At \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\), we find

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}\pi }{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}=2\frac{d^{2}W}{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}=-\frac{1+\mu }{2(1-\alpha _{i})^{2}(4+\mu )^{2}}<0 \end{aligned}$$

in case of uniform input pricing, and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}\Pi }{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}=-\frac{\mu (32+76\mu +63\mu ^{2}+21\mu ^{3}+2\mu ^{4})}{2(1-\alpha _{i})^{2}(4+\mu )^{2}(4+3\mu )^{3}}<0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^{2}W}{d\alpha _{i}^{2}}=-\frac{\mu (96+236\mu +203\mu ^{2}+71\mu ^{3}+8\mu ^{4})}{2(1-\alpha _{i})^{2}(4+\mu )^{2}(4+3\mu )^{3}}<0 \end{aligned}$$

under discriminatory input pricing. If follows that total profit and welfare are maximized at \(\alpha _{1}=\alpha _{2}\) in both input pricing regimes. \(\square \)

1.3 Forward shareholding

Consider a market where an upstream monopolist owned by a single shareholder sells an input to two downstream firms, each of which is controlled by a majority shareholder, but also partially owned by the shareholder of the upstream firm. Managers of the upstream firm maximize shareholder value \(\Pi _{u}=\pi _{u}+\alpha _{1}\pi _{1}+\alpha _{2}\pi _{2}\). Those of downstream firm i maximize \(\Pi _{i}=(1-\alpha _{i})\pi _{i}\).

Then, the equilibrium quantities are

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}=\frac{(1+\mu )(8(1-w_{i})+2\mu (8w_{i}-w_{-i}-5)-\mu ^{2}(7w_{i}-2w_{-i}))}{32+64\mu +30\mu ^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

if downstream firms compete in prices and

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}=\frac{(1+\mu )(4(1-w_{i})+g(1-2w_{i}+w_{-i}))}{16+16\mu +3\mu ^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

if they compete in quantities. We derive the equilibrium input prices, for all \(w_{2}(r)=w_{1}(r)+r\) and \(r\in [0,r^{*}]\). Under price competition,

$$\begin{aligned} w_{1}(r)=\frac{(16+16\mu +3\mu ^{2})(r-1)+\alpha _{1}(2+\mu )(4+\mu +\mu r)-\alpha _{2}(2+\mu )(4r+2\mu r-4-\mu )}{(4+\mu )(-8-6\mu +\alpha _{1}(2+\mu )+\alpha _{2}(2+\mu ))} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} r^{*}=\frac{(\alpha _{1}-\alpha _{2})(8+6\mu +\mu ^{2})}{32+32\mu +6\mu ^{2}+2\alpha _{1}(-2+\alpha _{2})(2+\mu )^{2}-4\alpha _{2}(2+\mu )^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Under quantity competition,

$$\begin{aligned} w_{1}(r)= & {} ((16+32\mu +15\mu ^{2})((2+\mu )r-2)+2\alpha _{1}(2+\mu )(4+\mu ^{2}r+\mu (5+r))\\&-\,\alpha _{2}(2+\mu )(8(r-1)+7\mu ^{2}r\\&+\,2\mu (8r-5)))/((2+\mu )(4+5\mu )((2+\mu )(\alpha _{1}+\alpha _{2})-8-6\mu )) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} r^{*}= & {} \frac{(\alpha _{1}-\alpha _{2})(4+5\mu )}{16+32\mu +15\mu ^{2}-\alpha _{2}(8+16\mu +7\mu ^{2})+\alpha _{1}(-8-16\mu -7\mu ^{2}+\alpha _{2}(4+8\mu +3\mu ^{2}))}. \end{aligned}$$

Based on these results, it is just a matter of computation to show that, under both price and quantity competition, \(dQ(r)/dr>0\), \(q_{2}(r)-q_{1}(r)>0\), \(dq_{2}(r)/d(r)<0\), and, therefore, \(dW(r)/dr>0\). Likewise, \(d\pi /d\alpha _{i}>0\) and \(dW/d\alpha _{i}>0\), under both uniform and discriminatory input pricing, regardless of whether firms compete in prices or in quantities.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lestage, R. Input price discrimination and non-controlling vertical shareholding. J Regul Econ 59, 226–250 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-021-09431-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-021-09431-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation