1 Introduction

Education expenditures, allocation between tiers of education and source of financing vary considerably over the world, even among OECD countries. These differences have important consequences for the quality and equity of the education system.Footnote 1

Table 2 (in Appendix 1) summarises differences in education expenditures, composition, and funding source by reporting average values over the period 2010–2017 for 32 OECD countries.Footnote 2In the period considered, spending on education as a share of GDP was, on average, slightly above 5%, varying from less than 4% (Czech Republic, Greece, Italy, Hungary and Slovakia) to more than 6% (Canada, Denmark, New Zealand, Norway, UK and USA).There is, however, great variability in the distribution of expenditures between tiers of education; countries such as the US, Chile and Canada allocate around 40% of education spending to the tertiary level while others (Greece, Slovenia and Italy) less than 25%.Footnote 3 Regarding the source of financing, non-tertiary education is mainly public in most countries (90% on average), but private financing of tertiary education varies considerably across countries (33% on average, ranging from 4% in Finland to more than 60% in Chile, Japan, UK and USA). Looking at public spending, the greater share is allocated to non-tertiary education, on average, 3.3% of GDP compared to 1% of GDP to tertiary education. To compare the allocation of public spending between tiers of education across countries, we have computed the ratio of a country’s public spending on tertiary to basic with the OECD average (see last column of Table 2). A value of the index greater (lower) than one indicates that the country’s public education spending is unbalanced towards tertiary (basic) education.

In this paper, we argue that countries’ differences in total public spending and its allocation between basic and tertiary education are the result of political decisions involving groups with conflicting preferences. To study these preferences, we provide a simple model of hierarchical education that considers two dimensions of heterogeneity among agents: income and education.

Standard redistributive arguments suggest that the impact of income on preferences for public education spending should be negative.Footnote 4 However, children from low socio-economic status have lower enrolment rates at increasing levels of education and thus they benefit less from spending on tertiary education.Footnote 5 This evidence has been explained by the role of parental income and education in the children’s human-capital production function. Parents contribute directly by financing the purchase of ‘inputs’ in the production of children’s human capital, such as books and other education resources, so wealthier parents spend more on their children education. As for parental education, Glomm and Ravikumar (1992, 2003) argue that a sufficiently high elasticity of parental human capital in the learning technology might be responsible for low intergenerational mobility in education. Along the same line, Cohen (1987) and Keane and Wolpin (2001) argue that class differential in education attainment might be due to the fact that more educated parents attribute greater importance to education and as a result children of highly educated parents put more effort during their schooling.Footnote 6 In addition, class differential in education attainments might also derive from social status differences in the ‘take-up’ of available opportunities.Footnote 7

Another factor, related to the socioeconomic status of the household, that might affect children’s probability of enrolling in higher education, is the prospect of being allocated into high skill jobs. If children from disadvantaged households anticipate that they have lower chances of being employed into better paying jobs, they perceive lower benefit from higher education (see Bernasconi and Profeta 2012; Gradstein 2019). In countries where education-based meritocracy is low, we therefore expect that parents from lower socioeconomic status tend to attach less importance to education.Footnote 8 The same argument applies to the social inclusiveness of the education system.Footnote 9 In education systems featuring low inclusiveness, children’s education attainments strongly depend on social background. This means that children from disadvantaged environments do not entirely reap the advantages of public funding of higher education; thus, we expect these households to be less in favour of tertiary education spending.Footnote 10

Aiming to capture the above features, which we believe shape individual preferences for public education budget and for its allocation between different stages of education, we develop a simple model of hierarchical education. The model integrates public expenditure with private education decisions, by allowing parents to top up public expenditure in advanced education with private transfers. Households consist of one parent and one child. Parents, who are differentiated according to an exogenously given level of human capital and income, care about household’s consumption and their children’s human capital. Children get educated in a hierarchical schooling system that features two levels of education: the lower level (K-12) is mandatory and funded exclusively by the government; the higher level (tertiary education), whose access is not universal, is publicly funded, although affluent parents can top up with private transfers. We assume that access to tertiary education depends on parental human capital. The degree of such dependence—to which hereafter we refer as intergenerational persistence in education- is determined by a variety of elements which in part can be country-specific.Finally, we assume that the public budget is entirely allocated to education and it is financed through income tax collection.

We identify four groups of households with conflicting preferences over the the size of the public education budget and its allocation. The intensity of the conflict among the groups is related to income inequality and to the degree of intergenerational persistence in education.

In equilibrium, the size of the budget allocated to education (and therefore the income tax) and the expenditure allocation among different tiers of education, depend on which group of households is in power and on country-specific features such as income inequality and the intergenerational persistence in education. We show that if the interests of low-educated households prevail, the equilibrium features a low level of public spending, unbalanced towards basic education, the more so the higher is the intergenerational persistence in education. By contrast, if the interests that predominate are those of highly educated households, whose income is lower than mean income, then, in equilibrium, public spending is relatively high. In both cases, the size of private expenditure in tertiary education is positively related to income inequality. Finally, if the political power is in the hands of rich and well-educated households, the equilibrium is similar to the one associated to the predominance of low-educated agents, and it is characterised by low public spending, unbalanced towards basic education, while advanced education is mainly financed by private sources.Footnote 11 If, instead, private options were not available, or not sufficiently developed, rich and well-educated households would support a relatively high public spending, unbalanced towards tertiary education.

After conceptualising different political equilibria, we turn to the data to explore similarities and differences between education systems in 32 OECD countries. Our aim is to establish if distinctive ‘education regimes’, akin to those identified in the theoretical analysis, could be discerned. To this purpose, we run a cluster analysis based on four key dimensions: inequality in the distribution of income; intergenerational persistence in education; share of graduates in the adult population; education expenditure (private and public) and its composition between tiers. Five clusters emerge from the analysis and narratives of one country exemplifying each cluster are presented. To each of these exemplifying countries, we associate a political equilibrium identified in the theoretical analysis. Our main finding is that a high intergenerational persistence in education might foster the establishment of education regimes in which the size and the allocation of the public budget among different tiers of education prevent a stable and significant increase in educational upward mobility, thus plunging the country in a ‘low education’ trap.

The contribution of this paper is relevant for political and theoretical reasons. On the political side, given the important involvement of governments in the education sector, understanding the political economy constraints of public education policy is crucial. Theoretically, our paper helps explaining the documented differences in education expenditures across OECD countries and why some countries, like Italy, seem to remain stuck in a ‘low education’ trap.

The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 briefly discusses the related literature. Section 3 illustrates the theoretical model. Section 4 contains the cluster analysis. Section 5 concludes and highlights some policy implications.

2 Related Literature

This paper relates to the theoretical literature on the political economy of education funding (Glomm et al. 2011). Investigating the political economy constraints of public education policy is crucial to understand the variation of public education expenditures across countries. The literature on education mainly treats basic and tertiary education symmetrically, or simply assumes a single type of education. More recently, some contributions have considered the hierarchical nature of education through an explicit two-stage technology and have analysed the preferences for the two tiers of education in a political economy perspective (Blankenau et al. 2007; Viaene and Zilcha 2013; Naito and Nishida 2017).Footnote 12 Our contribution is related to this strand of the literature. In these models, the level of human capital produced in the last stage of education is either fixed or depends on the amount of government expenditure. In the first case, the government can only choose to subsidize part of the cost of higher education, thus affecting its private cost but not its quality (that in these models is exogenous). By contrast, in our contribution, the human capital produced in the last stage of education depends on privately and publicly provided (monetary) inputs, which justifies our assumption of perfect substitutability.Footnote 13 Specifically, we assume that parents can top up public expenditure in advanced education with private transfers. Another important difference between our contribution and the bulk of the literature on the political economy of public education spending is that we analyse a two-dimensional political economy model and consider income and human capital as two different dimensions of heterogeneity.Footnote 14Thus, conflicting interests are not only between rich and poor families over the size of the public education budget, but also between highly educated families who enrol their children in university and those who do not. In this framework, we explicitly model partisan preferences for public spending in basic and tertiary education and investigate the impact of countries’ features such as income inequality and the intergenerational persistence in education on these preferences. We are thus able to identify different political equilibria and relate them to different ‘education regimes’.

This paper is also broadly related to the literature that, following a comparative approach, studies the typologies of welfare states and the ‘varieties of capitalism’. Research in this field has focused on how welfare regimes might be conceptualised, concentrating on social transfer payments as opposed to services. However, the latter, and in particular education, are a fundamental component of the welfare state. This paper adds to this literature by focusing on how different ‘education regimes’ might be rationalised. Along this line of research, West and Nikolai (2013) have addressed the relationship between ‘education regimes’ and the welfare state.Footnote 15 They have clustered 14 OECD countries (all European apart from US) according to education spending variables and other variables related to the characteristics of the education system. They have identified four clusters or ‘education regimes’, which roughly overlap with the European welfare regimes identified by Esping-Andersen (1990) and subsequent studies (Nordic, Anglo-Saxon, Continental and Mediterranean).Footnote 16 By contrast, we run a cluster analysis over 32 OECD countries considering, in addition to education spending variables, also income inequality, intergenerational education persistence, and the share of graduates in the adult population. We identify five clusters. Two of them—the one including Nordic European countries and that including mostly English-speaking countries—detect ‘education regimes’ which ‘overlap’ with the welfare regimes, respectively Social-Democratic and Liberal, identified by Esping-Andersen (1990). However, we are not able to recognise, among European countries, the Continental and Mediterranean clusters. Rather, we clearly single out a cluster of low spending countries (Italy, Hungary, Slovakia, Czech Republic and Greece) whose ‘education regimes’ recall the political equilibrium in which the interests of low-educated households prevail. This cluster is characterised by high values of intergenerational persistence in education. It is worth noting that this feature is shared with another clear-cut cluster identified by our analysis: the one including three emerging countries (Turkey, Mexico and Chile), though, in this case, the ‘education regime’ features a higher level of public spending biased towards tertiary education. Given the high intergenerational persistence in education, this last ‘education regime’ appears to favour the interests of rich and well-educated households, whose offspring are more likely to reap the benefits of public education spending biased towards tertiary education. Our expectation is that in both ‘education regimes’ the size of the public education budget and its allocation between different tiers will prevent a stable and significant increase of educational upward mobility.

3 The Model

In the economy, there is a continuum of households of measure one; this implies that per capita values coincide with total values. A household consists of one parent and one child. Parents are heterogeneous along two dimensions: income and human capital. Let indexes j and i identify, respectively, parent’s income and education. Income \({y}_{j}\), is distributed in the parent population according to a given distribution function with mean y. Parent’s human capital can take two values: i = G, if the parent has graduated from university, and i = NG if the parent has not obtained a university degree. Parents maximise an expected utility function defined over household consumption and human capital accumulated by the offspring.

Children’s human capital depends on public and private expenditures on education.Footnote 17 Children are educated in a hierarchical schooling system in which basic education might be followed by tertiary education. Basic education is publicly financed, while tertiary education is the result of public spending and parents’ educational transfer.

Human capital formation is modelled as a two-stage process. The first stage (basic education)—corresponding to primary and secondary education—is mandatory. We denote by B public expenditures in basic education. Access to the second stage (tertiary education) requires the successful completion of basic education. Public tertiary education spending is denoted by T and it is the same for all children accessing university. Each parent can top up public tertiary expenditure with private expenditure \({T}_{ij}\) where the indexes i and j identify, respectively, parent’s education and income.Footnote 18

Each child accumulates human capital according to the following production function:

$$ h_{ij} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {B^{\alpha } \left( {T_{ij} + T} \right) } \hfill & {if\;tertiary \;education\; is \;completed} \hfill \\ {B^{\alpha } } \hfill & {otherwise} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

Note that we allow for the possibility that the effectiveness of the two tiers of education differ and, by taking the elasticity of human capital w.r.t tertiary education spending as numeraire, \(\alpha \) measures the benefits of basic education relative to tertiary. If higher education spending is more effective than basic education spending, then \(0<\alpha <1.\)

The probability of entering university is not the same for all children. We assume that children whose parent has a university degree access university with probability \({p}_{G}\), while, if the parent has not graduated from university, this probability is \({p}_{NG}\), with \({0<p}_{NG}<{p}_{G}<1\).Footnote 19

The ratio \(\frac{{p}_{G}}{{p}_{NG}}\) can be interpreted as an indicator of the intergenerational persistence in education: the closer this ratio is to one, the less access to tertiary education depends on parents’ education.

We assume that human capital acquisition in higher education depends on total public spending regardless of the number of advanced students. Indeed, empirical studies show that class size has little effect on students’ achievements in higher education (Naito and Nishida 2017). Moreover, there is a wide consensus that there are considerable economies of scale in the production of teaching and research at tertiary level, even larger in the production of supportive services, like libraries and administrative services.Footnote 20

Total public education expenditures are financed by a proportional income tax (\(\tau \)), thus the government budget constraint can be written as:

$$B+T=\tau y$$
(1)

where \(y\) is the average income in the parents’ population.

We assume that the household utility function is logarithmic in consumption and child’s human capital, with the parameter \(\gamma \) measuring parent’s altruismFootnote 21:

$${U}_{ij}=ln{c}_{ij}+\gamma ln{h}_{ij}$$
(2)

Utility is maximised under the household budget constraint and the non-negativity constraints:

$${c}_{ij}+{T}_{ij}=\left(1-\tau \right){y}_{j}$$
(3)
$${T}_{ij}, {c}_{ij}\ge 0$$
(4)

In Appendix 2, we find the household optimal choices of consumption and private investment in tertiary education \(({c}_{ij}^{*}, {T}_{ij}^{*})\). In case of an interior solution (\({T}_{ij}>0\)),

$${c}_{ij}^{*}=\frac{\left(1-\tau \right){y}_{j}+T}{1+\gamma {p}_{i}}$$
$${T}_{ij}^{*}=\frac{\gamma {p}_{i}\left(1-\tau \right){y}_{j}-T}{1+\gamma {p}_{i}}$$

Two results are worth noting: first, as income increases, private expenditure in (tertiary) education rises; second, graduate parents spend more than non-graduate parents do.

3.1 Preferences for Public Education and Political Equilibrium

To derive preferences for public education expenditures, write the household indirect utility as a function of the Government’s choice variablesFootnote 22:

$${W}_{ij}\left(\tau ,T\right)=ln{c}_{ij}^{*}+\alpha \gamma ln\left(\tau y-T\right)+\gamma {p}_{ij}ln\left({T}_{ij}^{*}+T\right)$$
(5)

Substituting the optimal choices of consumption and private investment in tertiary education \(({c}_{ij}^{*}, {T}_{ij}^{*})\), in Appendix 2, we obtain households’ policy preferences, which are shown in the table below.

Table 1 summarises demand for public education spending by households’ socio-economic status. If education policy is interpreted as the (equilibrium) result of an electoral competition then, the policy outcome depends on which group is the most powerful, i.e. on the identity of the pivotal voter. In our framework, there are four possible outcomes, each characterised by the prevalence of one group of households. In what follows, we consider each one of them and discuss the likelihood of its occurrence.

Table 1 Households’ policy preferences for tertiary and total public education, as shares of GDP

Beforehand, note that the equilibrium share of basic education, which is obtained residually \(\left(\frac{{B}^{*}}{y}={\tau }^{*}-\frac{{T}^{*}}{y}\right)\), increases with the elasticity of human capital w.r.t to basic education (\(\alpha \)), which is a measure of the benefits from basic education. Similarly, the equilibrium share of tertiary education, if positive, increases with the probability to enter university (\({p}_{i})\). These parameters are, at least partially, country-specific being related to the productive and social structure of the economy.

First, consider the case in which the pivotal voter’s income is below average income; namely, the two outcomes in the first column of Table 1.Footnote 23 Comparing these two outcomes, we see that if \({p}_{G}={p}_{NG}\) they coincide. Otherwise, total public education spending and the share of tertiary education are higher if households with graduate parents prevail (i.e. if the equilibrium is the one in the second row).Footnote 24 This is more likely to happen if the share of graduates in the adult population is high. This is summarised in the following results.

Result 1

If the pivotal voter’s income is lower than mean income, then total public spending and the tertiary share are higher if the pivotal voter is a graduate.

Result 2

If the pivotal voter’s income is lower than mean income, then, public education spending is unbalanced towards tertiary (basic) education if \({p}_{i}>\alpha \) (if \({p}_{i}<\alpha \)).

Note also that in these equilibria, low-income households (i.e. those with \({y}_{j}<y\)) do not invest in private education, while high-income households spend an amount \({T}_{ij}^{*}=\frac{{p}_{i}\left({y}_{j}-y\right)}{({p}_{i}+\alpha +\frac{1}{\gamma })(1+\gamma {p}_{i})}\) on tertiary education (see Appendix 2).

Next consider a setting in which the pivotal voter’s income is above average income. In this case, the outcome would be one of the two equilibria shown in the second column of Table 1. We have the following

Result 3

If the pivotal voter is rich, then total public spending is low and unbalanced towards basic education.

In these equilibria, there is no public tertiary education and each household is willing to invest privately in tertiary education an amount \({T}_{ij}^{*}=\frac{\gamma {p}_{i}\left(1-\tau \right){y}_{j}}{1+\gamma {p}_{i}}\) (see Appendix 2).

Comparing the two equilibria in the second column, we see that total public education spending is even lower if households with graduate parents prevail. The reason is that high-income households prefer a low public budget, devoted to basic education, and privately invest in tertiary education, the more so the higher is their probability to enter tertiary education (\({p}_{i}\)).

In each of the above equilibria, private spending increases with the income share of the rich. Thus, our model predicts a positive relationship between income inequality and private education spending. This is summarised in the following results.

Result 4

Private spending in tertiary education increases with income inequality.

Finally, suppose that there is no possibility to top up public education expenditure with private expenditures. This could happen if, for example, there are too few potential students and, due to high fixed costs, it is not convenient to start a for-profit university. In this case, preferences are as shown in the first column of Table 1 for all households, independently of their income. This suggests that if the rich do not have the opportunity to substitute public education with private education, they would support public spending.

Result 5

If there is no private tertiary education, then (also) the rich support tertiary public education. In this case, if the pivotal voter is rich and well educated and if \({p}_{G}>\alpha \), spending is unbalanced towards tertiary education.

To interpret countries’ public education spending and its composition as the outcome of a political equilibrium, in the next section, we perform a cluster analysis for OECD countries and use the results of our model to interpret the clusters.

4 Cluster Analysis

In this section, we report the result of a cluster analysis performed over 32 OECD countries. To cluster the countries, we use the following education expenditure variables (averaged over the period 2010–2017)Footnote 25: public tertiary (TerPub), public basic (BasPub), total private (TotPriv) and total public (TotPub), all computed as share of GDP. Furthermore, we consider income inequality, an index of the intergenerational persistence in education and the share of graduates in the population.In our model income inequality is positively related to private education spending, while the index of intergenerational persistence in education proxies the gap between the probability of entering university of children from low social status relative to children from high social status. More precisely, a higher intergenerational educational persistence is associated with lower \({p}_{NG}\) relative to \({p}_{G}\). Finally, we consider the share of graduates and we expect that the higher is this share, the higher is the graduates’ political weight and therefore the higher the probability that their interest would prevail in equilibrium. To measure income inequality, we use the GINI index of disposable income; to assess the intergenerational persistence in education, we take the variable COR, which measures the correlation between the years spent in education by parents and the years spent by the child; higher COR indicates higher intergenerational persistence in education.Footnote 26 The SHARE of graduates in the adult population refers to the population aged 25–64 who have completed tertiary education. To limit the problem of reverse causality and to strengthen our interpretation of the results in terms of the effects of COR, GINI and SHARE on the demand for public and private education, we consider values of GINI, COR and SHARE that precede the observed values of education expenditures (for GINI and SHARE, we take the 2010 values and for COR, we refer to the 1980 cohort).Footnote 27

To perform the cluster analysis, we use the standardised values of the seven variables (see Table 4 in Appendix 3). The standardisation allows each variable to contribute equally to the definition of the clusters by eliminating distortions coming from the fact that variables with a large range are given more weight in defining a cluster solution than those with a small range (Afifi et al. 2019).

We first run a principal component analysis on the standardised variables. As shown in Table 5 in Appendix 3, the first three components explain 85% of the variance. Each component captures a specific dimension of the variability in the data set. The first component (PC1) has a large positive association with TotPub and it is negatively correlated with GINI and COR. We interpret this component as capturing the ‘egalitarian society’ dimension: a country scoring high in this dimension exhibits a low redistributive conflict, a quite mobile society (low intergenerational persistence in education) and high public spending. The second component (PC2) has a large positive association with TotPriv, GINI and SHARE. We interpret this component as capturing the ‘market-based society’ dimension: a country scoring high in this dimension exhibits a strong redistributive conflict, high private education expenditure and low public spending, especially in the tertiary segment. The third component (PC3) is positively correlated with GINI, COR and TerPub. We interpret this component as capturing the ‘élitarian society’ dimension: high values along this dimension indicate high income inequality, high intergenerational persistence in education and a public spending biased towards tertiary education. We call it ‘élitarian’ because a country scoring high in this dimension uses public spending in education mainly to benefit the privileged élite.

The position of each country along the three principal components (Fig. 1)Footnote 28 and the hierarchical tree-diagram (Fig. 2), resulting from the cluster analysis based on these principal components, identify five groups of countries at the dissimilarity level shown by the red line.Footnote 29Footnote 30

Fig. 1
figure 1

Countries’ position in the three-dimensional space (PC1, PC2, PC3)

Fig. 2
figure 2

Dendrogram

Group 1 (Austria, Belgium, Island, Sweden, Denmark, Norway, Finland) contains countries that score very high in the first component (‘egalitarian society’ dimension) and have a negative or very low score in the second and in the third components (‘market-based society’ and ‘élitarian society’ dimensions). In these countries, education expenditures are high in both education tiers and almost entirely publicly funded; the correlation between parents and children’s years of education is low (apart from Austria and Belgium) and there is a high share of graduates in the population. These societies display a low level of redistributive conflict (low income inequality), and a high degree of social mobility (low intergenerational persistence in education). These facts are consistent with a political equilibrium in which public spending in education is high and education funding from private sources is insignificant. The identity of the pivotal voter is not important given the low level of conflicts, although the high share of graduates in the adult population strengthen the probability that the pivotal voter be highly educated and explains the bias towards public spending in tertiary education. This ‘low conflict’ equilibrium is well suited to describe the situation observed in Denmark where the GINI index is 0.25, COR is 0.17 and the SHARE of graduates in the adult population is 33% (see Table 4). Public education spending in Denmark is 6.13% of GDP. Private spending is almost insignificant (0.19%) and public expenditure is biased towards tertiary education (our tertiary bias index scores 1.18).Footnote 31

Group 2 (Australia, UK, Israel, USA, Canada, New Zealand, Japan) contains countries characterised by high values of the second component (‘market-based society’ dimension). In these countries, education expenditures are high, but a relevant share of tertiary education spending is financed by private funds. As an example of this group, consider the US. In the US, a high share of graduates (42%) boosts demand for education and accordingly, total spending is high. Income inequality is relatively high (the GINI index is 0.38) and, in line with our model’s results, a relevant share of education is privately funded (1.98% of GDP). This expenditure is concentrated at the tertiary level. Public spending in education is relatively low (4.3% of GDP) and unbalanced towards basic education (our tertiary bias index scores 0.93). This can be taken as an example of an ‘ends-against-the-middle’ type of equilibrium. When private options for advanced education are available, the interests of low and high social status households might converge. The political equilibrium in this case features low public spending, unbalanced towards basic education, with a high share of advanced education financed by private sources.

Group 3 (Czech Republic, Slovakia, Greece, Italy, Hungary) includes countries with negative scores along all the three dimensions. These countries spend on education a small share of their GDP, mainly concentrated on basic education. They are all characterised by a high COR value indicating a high intergenerational persistence in education. In Italy, for example, the average share of GDP devoted to education in the period 2010–2017 is 3.85% (3.4% from public funding), one of the lowest value among OECD countries; education spending is mainly public, and it is unbalanced towards basic education (our tertiary bias index scores 0.68). According to our model, low spending on both education tiers should be the outcome if the pivotal voter is non-graduate and if the intergenerational persistence in education is high. Indeed, in Italy, children’s access to tertiary education is highly dependent on parents’ education (COR = 0.45) and the share of graduates in the population in 2010 was the lowest among OECD countries (14.8%), consistent with the hypothesis that the pivotal voter represents the interest of the non-graduated population.

Group 4 (Chile, Mexico, Turkey) contains countries that score high in the third component ‘élitarian society’ dimension) and very low in the first component (‘egalitarian society’ dimension). As an example of this group, we consider Turkey.Footnote 32 In the early 2000s, Turkey was among low spending countries, but, in the last decade, the country seems to have undergone a rapid change; public spending on education as a share of GDP increased by 24% between 2010 and 2017 (mostly concentrated on tertiary education), bringing Turkey, for the first time, above the OECD average (5.4% in Turkey in 2017 compared to the OECD average of 4.9%).Footnote 33 Income inequality is high (GINI = 0.42) as it is the intergenerational persistence in education (COR = 0.51). Public education spending is unbalanced towards tertiary education (our tertiary bias index scores 1.67). In a context of high income inequality and high intergenerational persistence in education, public spending in education is regressive rather than progressive.Footnote 34 The interests represented are therefore those of a rich and well-educated élite. Thus, we interpret Turkey’s situation as the equilibrium outcome obtained when the political power is in the hands of the rich and well educated, but a private supply of tertiary education is absent or not yet fully developed.

Finally, group 5 contains countries that apparently are quite different: Central European (The Netherlands and Deutschland), Eastern European (Poland, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia) and Mediterranean (Portugal, Spain, France). They all present a negative score in the second component, consistent with the observation that in these countries education is mainly public. The absolute value of the score along the two other dimensions is always quite small suggesting that these countries are less egalitarian than countries in group one, although definitely not élitarian. Excluding Portugal, the SHARE of graduates in 2010 was similar to countries in group 1, but the GINI index was relatively higher. The COR value was around the OECD average for most of the countries in the group. As exemplifying country, we take France. In terms of average total spending, over the period considered the proportion of French GDP allocated to education was slightly above the OECD average (5.2% versus 5.1%). Public expenditure as a percentage of GDP was above the OECD average (4.6% of GDP versus 4.3%) and balanced between the two education tiers (our tertiary bias index scores 1.06). The share of GDP allocated to private expenditure was instead below the average (0.6% versus 0.8%). The GINI index (0.30%), COR (0.39) and SHARE (29%) are in line with the OECD average. We interpret this outcome as a political equilibrium similar to the one in Denmark, but less extreme. The political conflict along the income and the education dimensions, measured respectively by the GINI index and COR, are higher relative to Denmark. Also, the share of graduates in the French population is lower than in the Danish population. The observed equilibrium is consistent with a low-educated and low-income pivotal voter. The higher public education expenditure observed, especially in the tertiary level, is consistent with a COR index remarkably lower than in countries of Group 3. French society appears more mobile than the Italian, and we argue that this explains the greater demand for education in France.

4.1 Discussion and Policy Implication: Italy

Italy is somehow a puzzle. Notwithstanding its tradition and its level of development, it spends very little on education, particularly at the advanced level. Several reasons can be put forward to explain such situation; here we highlight the role played by the intergenerational persistence in education. In this respect, it is interesting to compare Italy to Portugal. In the last decade, in Portugal the share of young adults (25–34 years old) who have attained a tertiary education has increased by fifty percent reaching 37.4% in 2019.Footnote 35 By comparison, in Italy, where the share of graduates in the population was similar to Portugal in 2010 (14.8%), the share of graduates in the young population in 2019 is only 27.7%. Comparing overall education expenditures in the two countries, reveals that average total education expenditure in the period 2010–2017 in Portugal was 5.3% of GDP (4.3% from public funding) while in Italy it amounted to 3.9% of GDP (3.4% from public funding). In the last two decades, the most dynamic component of education expenditures in Portugal has been tertiary education, which was below 1% of GDP in 2000 and it has increased by more than 30% since then, reaching 1.3% of GDP in 2019. In the same period, tertiary spending over GDP in Italy has remained below 1%. To interpret this impressive divarication using a political economy key, firstly, notice that in 2010 the index of intergenerational persistence in education was lower in Portugal than in Italy (0.40 compared to 0.45). To this respect, note that in all countries included in the group of low spenders (group 3), the children’s level of education is highly correlated to the parents’ education level. In our interpretation, this factor reduces the demand for advanced education from low-educated households. Since the pivotal voter is likely to belong to this majoritarian group, a high education spending equilibrium cannot emerge. In turn, this prevents the share of graduates in the adult population from growing, and this increases the probability to remain stuck in a low education spending equilibrium. Unlike other examples,Footnote 36 the 2006 Italian reform that has raised mandatory education to 10 years does not seem to have been effective in increasing education expenditures, particularly for tertiary education, nor the number of graduates.Footnote 37 In our opinion what is needed is a radical reform of secondary education, which should reduce early tracking and school segregation by neighborhood and by school programs, emphasising comprehensiveness as opposed to vocational orientation.

5 Concluding Remarks

This paper documents differences in education systems across OECD arguing that the education system observed in a country is the result of a complex interaction between preferences for education and political competition, both of which depend on the characteristics of the underlying conflict of interest. To analyse this issue, we build a model that emphasises the role of households’ income and education heterogeneity. It also relates households’ preferences to country-level characteristics such as income inequality and intergenerational persistence in education. Based on our model’s results and on the empirical evidence presented, the main policy message of our analysis is that the call for an increase of public education expenditures to favour equality of opportunities, might not receive political support. Although low social status households are the segment of population that should strive more to increase equality of opportunities, they might oppose an increase in the level of education expenditure, especially at tertiary level. This position might obtain the political support of the richer segment of population interested in reducing the public budget in favour of private expenditures. The likelihood of this event is greater in countries where the share of population with tertiary education is low and the intergenerational persistence in education is high, like in Italy. The great dependence of the access to tertiary education on parental social status prevents the majority of low-educated agents from supporting an increase in public education spending, especially at tertiary level. In this respect, reforms of the education system, directed at promoting equity and inclusiveness in education and thus at lowering the degree of intergenerational persistence in education, are needed.