Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Secular satiation

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Satiation of need is generally ignored by growth theory. I study a model where consumers may be satiated in any given good but new goods may be introduced. A social planner will never elect a trajectory with long-run satiation. Instead, he will introduce enough new goods to avoid such a situation. In contrast, the decentralized equilibrium may involve long run satiation. This, despite that the social costs of innovation are second order compared to their social benefits. Multiple equilibria may arise: depending on expectations, the economy may then converge to a satiated steady state or a non satiated one. In the latter equilibrium, capital and the number of varieties are larger than in the former, while consumption of each good is lower. This multiplicity comes from the following strategic complementarity: when people expect more varieties to be introduced in the future, this raises their marginal utility of future consumption, inducing them to save more. In turn, higher savings reduces interest rates, which boosts the rate of innovation. When TFP grows exogenously and labor supply is endogenized, the satiated equilibrium generically survives. For some parametrer values, its growth rate is positive while labor supply declines over time to zero. Its growth rate is then lower than that of the non satiated equilibrium. Hence, the economy may either coordinate on a high leisure, low growth, satiated "leisure society" or a low leisure, high growth, non satiated "consumption society".

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Dixit and Stiglitz (1977), Romer (1990), Aghion and Howitt (1992) and Grossman and Helpman (1991)

  2. In an Appendix available from the author, I discuss the consequences of consumer heterogeneity. It is shown that the results do not necessarily depend on all agents being satiated. For example, if some consumers have access to financial markets but others not, the trajectories with satiation survive, with essentially the same aggregate properties but along them financially constrained households are never satiated.

  3. Such a line of explanation has been so far overlooked by the literature, which has mostly focused on explaining greater leisure in Europe by taxation or labor market institutions (Prescott 2004; Alesina et al. 2005)

  4. Moneta and Chai (2014) estimate cross-sectional Engel curves and find that they reach a maximum in many instances. This may be just due to substitution, as in the case of inferior goods with an interior mode–although such a mechanism is not incompatible with satiation. For some goods the Engel curve flattens out rather than having a strict mode, which is perhaps a stronger sign of satation.

    If utility is smooth, one cannot be satiated in one good unless one is satiated in all other goods. This is what occurs in this paper’s model. However, if utility has a kink at the satiation point, this no longer holds: one may be at the satiation point for some goods but not others, hence under satiation Engel curves have maxima for some goods but not all goods.

    Gallouj and Weinstein (1997) document how the mode for some goods has disappeared over time. For "leisure services", they ascribe it to innovation. This is consistent with the mechanism analyzed in this paper: Innovation may endogenously lift consumers out of satiation by broadening product variety in a given sector.

  5. As an example, Gordon (2012) lists six "headwind" factors that will slow down US economic growth, none of them coming from consumer demand.

    An early neo-classical analysis of satiation includes Stent and Roy Webb (1975) who, building on Fisk’s (1971) concept of "subsistence affluence", study a neo-classical partial equilibrium model of rural Papua New Guinean households which allows for satiation.

    It is interesting to note that this stream of research considers satiation as more relevant for poor countries than for rich countries, thus echoing Malthus’s famous quote that "The savage would slumber for ever under his tree unless he were roused from his torpor by the cravings of hunger or the pinchings of cold, and the exertions that he makes to avoid these evils, by procuring food, and building himself a covering, are the exercises which form and keep in motion his faculties, which otherwise would sink into listless inactivity."

    The brief analysis in Sect. 4.3 of this paper suggests that the "Zen road to affluence", to use the term coined by Sahlins (1974), is a mixed blessing: the economy may be stuck at a low accumulation, low development trap. Admittedly this is not an issue for such authors, who consider or rather assume that this situation is desirable since consumers are at their bliss point. This however ignores the possibility of growth through the extensive margin of introducing new products, which is this paper’s key focus

  6. Aoki and Yoshikawa (2002) study a growth model with "saturation of demand" in each good and horizontal innovation. In their model, which is in the fashion of Young’s (1991) model of product life cycle, bounds to demand do not come from satiation and horizontal innovation is assumed to be entirely exogenous. Accordingly, none of the results and welfare analysis studied here hold.

  7. Saturation of demand for existing goods, and the implied need to reallocate R and D effort towards new goods, plays an important role in Pasinetti’s (1981) theory of structural change.

    See Andersen (1998) for an evolutionary learning model, based on Pasinetti’s ideas.

  8. Rodbertus (1898), considers that the cause of overproduction crises lies in the fact that the rich are satiated and fail to spend enough of their income on existing goods. He argues that the existence of luxury goods only partly alleviates the problem, while rechanneling the surplus of production to productive investment in existing goods makes the overproduction problem worse in the long run. This is reminiscent of the results in Propositions 1 and 3 below.

  9. At some level of abstraction, however, one can always interpret the introduction of new goods as implying a change in the consumers’ preferences. For horizontal innovation, the formalism of new growth theory does not allow to distinguish between the preferences for new products being genuine versus artificially created.

  10. His paper is related to this one in that he also studies the implications of bounds on consumption, which come from the fact that consumption takes time.

  11. Because the goods are symmetrical, the preceding section’s model is the same as this one with \(N=1,\) provided innovation does not occur.

  12. In Propositions 3 and 4 I only focus on the regimes that are most relevant. For example, if \(\beta C_{MGR}<N_{0}<N_{S},\) implying in particular \(K_{S}> {\hat{K}}>K_{MGR}\), and \(\rho >\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }\) for \(K_{0}<\hat{ K}\) the economy follows a standard Ramsey path with no innovation and convergence of the capital stock to \(K_{MGR}.\)

    For the sake of brevity and simplicity, I do not discuss the case where the economy starts with more capital than in steady state.

  13. In the absence of innovation, the capital accumulation process would continue as in the scenarios described in Proposition 1, B, (i) and C, (i). That is, the capital stock would converge to the equivalent of \(K_{S2},\) which is the greater solution to \(N_{0}=\beta (A{\hat{K}}^{\alpha }-\delta {\hat{K}}).\) But this capital stock is on the right side of the Golden Rule, i.e. is such that \(r(K)<0<\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta },\) implying that innovation kicks in before that level is reached and maintains the capital stock at a level equal to \(K_{S}\) forever.

  14. On Fig. 2 it has been assumed that \(K_{S}<K_{MGR},\) i.e. \(\rho <\frac{ \gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }.\) As a result the condition \(N_{0}<\beta C_{MGR}\) is automatically satisfied since \(N_{0}<N_{S}\) and \(N_{S}<\beta C_{MGR}.\)

  15. If \(\rho >\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta },\) then unless initial capital is large enough relative to \(K_{MGR},\) the economy converges to a modified Golden Rule steady state without innovation as long as \(N_{0}>\beta C_{MGR},\) otherwise Proposition 3 applies.

  16. If \(\rho <\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }\) then \(K_{S}<K_{MGR}\) and \(N_{S}<\beta C_{MGR},\) implying that if \(N_{0}<N_{S}\) then \(N_{0}<\beta C_{MGR},\) so that a trajectory in some regime of Proposition 3 exists for an initial capital lower than \(K_{S}.\)

  17. In that respect, horizontal innovation is very different from vertical innovation. The latter raises the future physical amount of goods available to the economy, and interest rates must be higher for consumers to absorb those goods. In contrast, horizontal innovation raises the marginal utility of future consumption, which makes it more valuable to save at any given interest rate.

  18. This accumulation process in anticipation of a future wave of innovation is reminiscent of Greenwood and Yorukoglu’s (1994) analysis of the IT revolution. The convergence path highlighted here has two phases: a capital accumulation phase and an innovation phase. If the contribution of innovation is mismeasured, the second phase may be wrongly interpreted as a ‘slump’.

  19. In both regimes the long-run consumption level of each good is independent of A,  being pinned down in one case at the satiation level and in the other by the free entry condition in R and D together with the Keynes-Ramsey determination of the equilibrium real interest rate.

  20. Thus, in Regimes I and III, a "vertical" innovation, i.e. an increase in TFP, triggers a phase of capital accumulation boosted by higher savings, followed by a halt to capital accumulation and a phase of horizontal innovation. This bears some similarities to Schumpeterian long waves such as those analyzed by Aghion et al. (2014).

  21. This is also true, asymptotically, of a trajectory which converges to satiation in the long-run as in Proposition 9, even though in this case \(\rho\) clearly has an effect on transitional dynamics.

  22. The condition \(g_{A}<(1-\alpha )\rho\) is the standard one that is needed for a Ramsey MGR BGP to deliver summable utility. However if \(\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\left( \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }+\delta (1-\alpha )\right) <(1-\alpha )\rho\) and \(\rho >\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta },\) then a BGP cannot be constructed for \(\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\left( \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }+\delta (1-\alpha )\right)<g_{A}<(1-\alpha )\rho .\)

  23. For \(\rho<\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }<3\rho ,\) the upper-bound for \(g_{A}\) in Proposition 8 exceeds the lower bound for \(g_{A}\) in Proposition 10, while the condition \(\rho <\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }\) also holds. Hence there exists a nonempty interval of values of \(g_{A}\) for which both types of equilibria coexist. Furthermore, the expressions for \(g_{LS}\) and \(g_{CS}\) imply that \(g_{LS}<g_{CS}\) iff \(\frac{g_{A}}{1-\alpha }<\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }-\rho ,\) which holds by (19).

  24. Gali (1999), Basu et al. (2006).

  25. The linearized system around \(K=K_{MGR}\), \(c=\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\) is

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{dt}\left( \begin{array}{c} dC \\ dK \end{array} \right) =M\left( \begin{array}{c} dC \\ dK \end{array} \right) , \end{aligned}$$

    where

    $$\begin{aligned} M=\left[ \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{} \left( \frac{1}{\beta }-\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\right) r^{\prime }(K) \\ -N_{0} &{} \rho \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$

    The eigen values are solution to

    $$\begin{aligned} X^{2}-\rho X-b=0, \end{aligned}$$

    where \(b=-N_{0}\left( \frac{1}{\beta }-\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\right) r^{\prime }(K)>0.\) Therefore one is positive and the other is negative.

References

  • Abel, A. B., Mankiw, N. G., Summers, L., & Zeckhauser, R. (1989) Assessing dynamic efficiency: Theory and evidence Review of Economic Studies, 56(1), 1–19.

  • Acemoglu, Daron. (2002). Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies, 69(4), 781–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (2009). Introduction to modern economic growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Akcigit, U., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth. Through Creative Destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Akcigit, U., Howitt, P. (2014). What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory? In Handbook of Economic Growth (Vol. 2, pp. 515–563). Elsevier.

  • Alesina, A. F., Glaeser, E. L., & Sacerdote, B. (2005). Work and leisure in the U.S. and Europe: Why so different?, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

  • Andersen, Esben Sloth (1998), Escaping satiation in an evolutionary model of structural economic dynamics, DRUID Working paper No 98-9

  • Aoki, Masanao, & Yoshikawa, Hiroshi. (2002). Demand saturation-creation and economic growth. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 48, 127–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu, Susanto, Fernald, John G., & Kimball, Miles S. (2006). Are technology improvements contractionary? American Economic Review, 96(5), 1418–1448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, William, Blackman, Sue Anne, & Batey., & Wolff, Edward. . (1985). Unbalanced growth revisited: Asymptotic stagnancy and new evidence. American Economic Review, 75(4), 806–817.

  • Benhabib, Jess, & Bisin, Alberto (2002). Advertising, Mass Consumption and Capitalism, New York University Working Paper

  • Büskens, Christof, & Maurer, Helmut. (2000). SQP-methods for solving optimal control problems with control and state constraints: Adjoint variables, sensitivity analysis and real-time control. Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics, 120(1–2), 85–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, Giacomo. (2018). Time-poor, working, super-rich. European Economic Review, 101, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, Avinash, & Stiglitz, Joseph. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review, 67(3), 297–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Echevarria, Cristina. (1997). Changes in sectoral composition associated with economic growth. International Economic Review, 38(2), 431–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisk, E. K. (1971). Labour absorption capacity of subsistence agriculture. Economic Record, 47, 366–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foellmi, Reto, & Zweimüller, Josef. (2006). Income distribution and demand-induced innovation. Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 187–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foellmi, Reto, & Zweimüller, Josef. (2008). Structural change, Engel’s consumption cycles and Kaldor’s facts of economic growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(2), 1317–1328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, John Kenneth. (1958). The affluent society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gali, J. (1999). Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations? American Economic Review, 89(1), 249–271.

  • Gallouj, F., & Weinstein, O. (1997). Innovation in services. Research Policy, 26, 537–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, Robert J. (2012), Is US economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds, CEPR Policy Insight, 63, September.

  • Greenwood, J., & Yorukoglu, M. (1997). 1974, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 46(1) 49–95.

  • Grossman, Gene M., & Helpman, Elhanan. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, Fred. (1995). Social limits to growth. London: Routledge, revised edition.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1930). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren, reprinted in John Maynard Keynes, Essays in Persuasion (pp. 358–373). New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 1963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laitner, John. (2000). Structural change and economic growth. Review of Economic Studies, 67(3), 545–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, M. J. (Ed.). (2000). The consumer society reader. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T. (1798). An essay on the principle of population, as it affects the future improvement of society, with remarks on the speculations of Mr. Godwin, M. Condorcet, and other writers. London: J. Johnson.

  • Kiminori, Matsuyama. (2002). The rise of mass consumption societies. Journal of Political Economy, 110(5), 1035–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moneta, Alessio, & Chai, Andreas. (2014). The evolutions of Engel curves and its implications for structural change. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38(4), 895–923.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ngai, R., & Christopher, P. (2007). Structural change in a multisector model of growth. American Economic Review, 97(1), 429–443.

  • Pasinetti, Luigi. (1981). Structural change and economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E. C. (2004). Why Do Americans work so much more than Europeans? Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 28(1), 2–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodbertus, Karl. (1898). Overproduction and crises. London: Swan Sonnenschein and co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5).

  • Sahlins, M. (1974). Stone age economics. London: Tavistock.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, Gilles. (2006). Distribution and growth in an economy with limited needs: Variable markups and the end of work. Economic Journal, 116, 382–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schor, Juliet. (1995). A new analytic basis for: An economic critique of consumer society. The Newsletter of PEGS, 5(1), 7–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schor, Juliet. (1998). The overspent American: Why we want what we don’t need. New York: Harper and Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1939). Business cycles. Historical and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process: A Theoretical.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, Tibor. (1976). The Joyless Economy: An Inquiry into Human Satisfaction and Consumer Dissatisfaction. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stent, W. R., & Roy Webb, L. (1975). Subsistence affluence and market economy in Papua New Guinea. Economic Record, 51, 522–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, Thorstein. (1973). The theory of the leisure class: An economic study of institutions. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt, Ulrich. (2001). Learning to consume - A theory of wants and the growth of demand. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(1), 23–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, Alwyn. (1991). Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of international trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 369–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gilles Saint-Paul.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This research has benefitted from financial support from CEPREMAP and the PjSE Ecole Universitaire de Recherche under grant ANR-17-EURE-0001. I am grateful to Florin Bilbiie, Rachel Ngai, and participants to seminars in EUI, Florence, IMT, Lucca, The Structural change workshop, Cagliari, and the CEPR Macroeconomics and Growth program for helpful discussions.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

Since utility does not satisfy the Inada conditions at \(C=0,\) the nonnegativity constraint \(C\ge 0\) has to be imposed. Consequently, the Hamiltonian is (see for example Büskens and Maurer (2000))

$$\begin{aligned} H(C_{t},K_{t},\lambda _{t},\mu _{t},t)=u(C_{t})e^{-\rho t}+\lambda _{t}e^{-\rho t}(AK_{t}^{\alpha }-C_{t}-\delta K_{t})+\mu _{t}e^{-\rho t}C_{t}. \end{aligned}$$

The FOCs are

$$\begin{aligned} u^{\prime }(C_{t})= & {} \lambda _{t}-\mu _{t} \nonumber \\ -{\dot{\lambda }}_{t}+\rho \lambda _{t}= & {} \lambda _{t}r(K_{t}) \nonumber \\ \mu _{t}C_{t}= & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Therefore, either \(\mu _{t}=0\) and \(C_{t}\ge 0,\) implying that \(u^{\prime }(C_{t})=\lambda _{t},\) i.e. \(C_{t}=\frac{1-\lambda _{t}}{\beta },\) or \(\mu _{t}\ge 0\) and \(C_{t}=0,\) implying that \(1=u^{\prime }(0)\le \lambda _{t}.\) This proves that \(C_{t}=\max (\frac{1-\lambda _{t}}{\beta },0),\) while (20) clearly coincides with (5). \(\square\)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 1

A. Remember that \(C^{*}=\max _{K}AK^{\alpha }-\delta K.\) Therefore if \(1/\beta >C^{*}\) the equation \(AK^{\alpha }-\delta K=1/\beta\) has no solution and the only steady states are non satiated. Consequently, \(K=K_{MGR \text { }}\) in steady state.

B. (i). Assume \(C_{t}=1/\beta\) throughout. Then \({\dot{K}}_{t}=AK^{\alpha }-\delta K-1/\beta .\) Over \((K_{S1},K_{S2}],\) \({\dot{K}}>0,\) so that K clearly converges to \(K_{S2}.\) Furthermore, this trajectory is optimal as it delivers the maximum possible utility level.

(ii) By (5), the consumer is either always satiated or never satiated. Since K would become equal to zero in finite time if he were always satiated, the consumer is never satiated. Assume the economy converges to a satiated steady state, implying \(\lim _{t\rightharpoonup \infty }K=K_{S,i}.\) Since \(K_{S2}>K_{S1}>K_{MGR},\) for some T and \(t>T,\) \(K>K_{MGR}.\) Then \({\dot{C}}<0\) for \(t>T,\) which contradicts the fact that \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }C=1/\beta .\) Therefore the economy converges to a non satiated steady state, implying \(\lim K=K_{MGR}.\)

C. (i) Same proof as B (i)

(ii) Again the consumer is never satiated. Assume the economy converges to a non satiated steady state. Then \(\lim _{t\rightharpoonup \infty }K=K_{MGR}.\) Since \(K_{MGR}>K_{S1},\) for some T and \(t>T,\) \(K_{S2}>K>K_{S1}.\) Let \(t_{0}>T.\) Consider the following deviation \({\tilde{C}}_{t}\) from the actual trajectory: \({\tilde{C}}_{t}=C_{t},\) \(t<t_{0},\) \({\tilde{C}}_{t}=1/\beta ,\) \(t\ge t_{0}.\) Then the corresponding capital stock \({\tilde{K}}_{t}\) is such that \({\tilde{K}}_{t}=K_{t},\) \(t<t_{0}.\) Therefore \(K_{S2}>K_{t_{0}}>K_{S1}.\) Clearly, then \(\lim {\tilde{K}}=K_{S2}.\) Hence the deviation is feasible. Furthermore, as \(C_{t}<1/\beta\) throughout, \({\tilde{C}}_{t}>C_{t}\) for \(t\ge t_{0}.\) It follows that the deviation delivers a strictly higher utility level than the initial trajectory, which therefore cannot be optimal. Consequently, the economy necessarily converges to a satiated steady state. \(\square\)

[Observe that, as in the standard case with a single steady state, one can show that the economy necessarily converges to a steady state. To see this, note that \(\lambda\) is monotonic throughout. If not, there exists t such that \({\dot{\lambda }}_{t}=0,\) implying \(K_{t}=K_{MGR},\) unless \(\lambda =0,\) in which case \(C=1/\beta\) throughout and convergence is straightforward. If \(C_{t}=C_{MGR},\) this is clearly a steady state. If \(C_{t}>C_{MGR},\) \({\dot{K}} <0\) locally, implying that for \(s>t,\) \({\dot{\lambda }}_{s}<0,\) \({\dot{C}}_{s}>0\) and therefore \({\dot{K}}_{s}<0.\) Since furthermore \({\dot{K}}_{s}<AK_{s}^{\alpha }-\delta K_{s}-C_{t}<AK_{MGR}^{\alpha }-\delta K_{MGR}-C_{t}=C_{MGR}-C_{t}<0,\) K becomes equal to zero in finite time, which is impossible. If \(C_{t}<C_{MGR},\) \({\dot{K}}>0\) locally, so that for \(s>t,\) \({\dot{\lambda }}_{s}>0,\) \({\dot{K}}_{s}>0,\) \({\dot{C}}_{s}\le 0.\) This cannot be optimal since one could instead choose \(C=C_{MGR}\) over \([t,\infty )\) and get a higher utility.

Since \(\lambda\) is monotonic, C converges monotonically to a limit \(C_{\infty }.\) Finally, one can show that K is monotonic too at least for t greater than some T. Assume to fix ideas that C is nondecreasing. Assume there exists t such that \({\dot{K}}_{t}=0.\) (Otherwise K is clearly monotonic). Then by continuity \({\dot{K}}_{s}\le 0\) for \(s\in [t,t+\varepsilon ]\) and \(\varepsilon >0\) not too large. Since \({\dot{K}}\) is continuous, one can never have \({\dot{K}}_{s}>0\) for \(s>t.\) Indeed, let \(s_{\max }=\max \{u<s,{\dot{K}}_{u}\le 0\}\). One must have \(s_{\max }<s.\) On the other hand, for some \(\varepsilon >0\) small enough \({\dot{K}}_{s_{\max }+\varepsilon }\le 0,\) a contradiction. Therefore \({\dot{K}}\le 0,\) implying K is nonincreasing throughout. Hence K is eventually monotonic in all cases. Since K is bounded, K has a limit.]

1.3 Proof of Proposition 2

The Hamiltonian is given by

$$H = \left( {C_{t} - \beta \frac{{C_{t}^{2} }}{{2N_{t} }}} \right)e^{{ - \rho t}} + \lambda _{t} e^{{ - \rho t}} (AK_{t}^{\alpha } - C_{t} - \delta K_{t} - R_{t} ) + \varepsilon _{t} e^{{ - \rho t}} \gamma R_{t} + \mu _{t} e^{{ - \rho t}} C_{t}$$

The representative consumer maximizes H subject to \(R_{t}\ge 0\) and \(C_{t}\ge 0.\) Let \(c_{t}=C_{t}/N_{t},\) \(r(K)=\alpha AK^{\alpha -1}-\delta .\) Using the same steps as in the proof of Lemma 1 to eliminate \(\mu _{t},\) the first order conditions are

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}= & {} \max \left( 0,\frac{1-\lambda _{t}}{\beta }\right) \\ -{\dot{\lambda }}_{t}+\rho \lambda _{t}= & {} \lambda _{t}r(K_{t}); \\ \lambda _{t}\ge & {} \gamma \varepsilon _{t}\text { and }\left( \lambda _{t}-\gamma \varepsilon _{t}\right) R_{t}=0; \\ -{\dot{\varepsilon }}_{t}+\rho \varepsilon _{t}= & {} \frac{\beta c_{t}^{2}}{2}. \end{aligned}$$

Consider any steady state. Then either \(\lambda >\gamma \varepsilon\) or \(\lambda =\gamma \varepsilon .\)

Assume \(\lambda >\gamma \varepsilon .\) Since \(\varepsilon \ge 0\), \(\lambda >0.\) Therefore, the steady state is non satiated. Then clearly \(\rho =r(K),\) implying \(K=K_{MGR}.\) Since \({\dot{K}}={\dot{N}}=0,\) it must be that \(C=C_{MGR}.\) In particular, \(c=C/N>0,\) so that \(\lambda =1-\beta c.\) Since \(\rho \varepsilon =\frac{\beta c^{2}}{2},\) \(\lambda =1-\beta c\) and \(\lambda >\gamma \varepsilon ,\) it must be that \(\rho (1-\beta c)>\frac{\gamma \beta c^{2}}{2},\) or equivalently \(c<c^{*}.\) Therefore \(N=C/c=C_{MGR}/c>C_{MGR}/c^{*}=N^{*}.\)

Assume \(\lambda =\gamma \varepsilon .\) Since \(\rho \varepsilon =\beta c^{2}/2,\) one cannot have \(c=0.\) Otherwise one would have \(\lambda =\varepsilon =0,\) implying \(c=1/\beta ,\) a contradiction. Therefore \(c>0,\) implying \(\varepsilon >0\) and therefore \(\lambda >0\) and satiation cannot hold. Again \(\rho =r(K),\) \(K=K_{MGR}\) and \(C=C_{MGR}.\) Since \(\lambda =1-\beta c=\gamma \varepsilon =\gamma \beta c^{2}/(2\rho ),\) \(c=c^{*}\) and \(N=C_{MGR}/c^{*}=N^{*}.\) \(\square\)

1.4 The problem with no price cap

Assume output is the numéraire. Let \(p_{it}\) be the price of good i at date t. At date t the demand for good i must be solution to the following problem

$$\begin{aligned}&\max \int _{0}^{N_{t}}u(c_{it})di, \\&s.t.\int _{0}^{N_{t}}p_{it}c_{it} \le S_{t}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(S_{t}\) is the consumer’s total spending at date t. While \(S_{t}\) is endogenous, its optimal level does not change when an infinitesimal producer changes its price, since such a change only has negligible effects on the consumer’s budget constraint. Therefore, \(S_{t}\) is treated as given by the producer of good i when setting \(p_{i}.\)

The solution to this problem is

$$\begin{aligned} c_{it}=\frac{1-\lambda _{t}p_{it}}{\beta }, \end{aligned}$$

where the Lagrange multiplier is

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{t}=\max \left( \frac{\int _{0}^{1}p_{it}di-\beta S_{t}}{ \int _{0}^{1}p_{it}^{2}di},0\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Each individual monopoly sets its price \(p_{it}\) so as to solve

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{p_{it}}\pi (p_{it},\lambda _{t})=\frac{1-\lambda _{t}p_{it}}{\beta } (p_{it}-1). \end{aligned}$$

Again, \(\lambda\) is treated as fixed by the firm, since the firm is infinitesimal. Clearly, if \(\lambda =0,\) the optimal price is infinite, for all i. But this contradicts the fact that if all prices are above \(\beta S_{t},\lambda >0.\) Therefore, one must have \(\lambda >0\) in equilibrium, implying satiation does not arise. The optimal price is the same across all firms and equal to

$$\begin{aligned} p_{it}=p_{t}=\frac{1+\lambda }{2\lambda } \end{aligned}$$

In such a setting, one can compute steady states and compare it with the first best characterized in Proposition 2.

In steady state, p is constant, and the consumer’s problem is the same as in Sect. 3.3.Therefore the same Euler equation holds, and since there is no satiation, \(r=\rho ,\) \(K=K_{MGR}\) and \(C=C_{MGR}.\)

In the innovation regime, the steady state is characterized by the following three conditions

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda p= & {} 1-\beta c \\ p= & {} \frac{1+\lambda }{2\lambda } \\ V= & {} \frac{\pi }{\rho }=\frac{(p-1)c}{\rho }=\frac{1}{\gamma }. \end{aligned}$$

The last expression is the zero profit condition for innovation.

Solving for c,  we find that it is the unique solution to

$$\begin{aligned} \beta c^{2}=\frac{\rho (1-2\beta c)}{\gamma }. \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Comparing with (10), we find that this steady state has a lower c than in the first best. Since in both cases C is the same and equal to \(C_{MGR}\), it follows that N is larger in the decentralized equilibrium.

While even at the monopoly price innovators only appropriate a fraction of the social surplus of their invention, at the same time monopoly pricing distorts the price of consumption goods upwards. Markets convey the wrong signal that the opportunity cost of one unit of output in terms of final consumption goods is \(1/p<1,\) whereas it should be equal to 1. This tends to generate too much innovation. While under Dixit and Stiglitz preferences the two effects exactly cancel each other (Dixit and Stiglitz 1977), here the latter effect dominates.

1.5 Proof of Proposition 3

A. We first construct a trajectory such that \(R=0,\) \(N=N_{0},\) and \(c=1/\beta .\) Along this trajectory, the law of motion for K is

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}_{t}=AK_{t}^{\alpha }-\frac{N_{0}}{\beta }-\delta K_{t}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(K_{0}>{\hat{K}},\) one has \({\dot{K}}>0\) throughout and the trajectory converges to \({\tilde{K}},\) which is the larger solution to \(N_{0}=\beta (AK^{\alpha }-\delta K).\) In particular, \(r({\tilde{K}})<0,\) implying \(\tilde{K }>K_{S}.\) Let T be the date at which, along this trajectory, \(K_{t}=K_{S}.\)

Our equilibrium trajectory coincides with that trajectory for \(t\le T.\) Thereafter, we assume that \(c_{t}=1/\beta ,\) \(K_{t}=K_{S},\) and therefore

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{N}}_{t}=\gamma \left( AK_{S}^{\alpha }-\frac{N_{t}}{\beta }-\delta K_{S}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, N converges monotonically to \(N_{S}>N_{0}.\)

We now show that this trajectory satisfies all the equilibrium conditions.

First, the Euler condition (14) is always satisfied since \({\dot{c}}=0\) and \(c=1/\beta .\) The law of motion (6) is also satisfied. For \(t\ge T,\) we have that \(r_{t}=r(K_{S})=\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }\) and \(\pi _{t}=(\mu -1)/\beta .\) Therefore, from (11), \(V_{t}=1/\gamma .\) The economy is in the innovation regime, consistent with our assumption that \({\dot{N}}>0.\) For \(t<T,\) integrating (11) yields

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}=\int _{t}^{T}\frac{\mu -1}{\beta }e^{-\int _{t}^{s}r_{u}du}ds+\frac{1}{ \gamma }e^{-\int _{t}^{T}r_{u}du}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(K_{t}<K_{S},\) \(r_{s}>\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }.\) Straightforward algebra then implies that \(V_{t}<1/\gamma .\) Consequently, the economy is in the no innovation regime for \(t<T,\) consistent with \({\dot{N}}=0.\)

Thus, the constructed trajectory satisfies all the equilibrium conditions.

B. Assume now that \(K_{0}<{\hat{K}}\) and consider the following system

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}_{t}= & {} AK_{t}^{\alpha }-N_{0}c_{t}-\delta K_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{c}}_{t}= & {} \left( \frac{1}{\beta }-c_{t}\right) \left( r(K_{t})-\rho \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(23)

This is a standard system and there exists a unique saddle-path converging to its steady state such that \(c=1/\beta\) and \(K={\hat{K}}.\) To see this, note that since \(N_{0}<\beta C_{MGR},\) \({\hat{K}}<K_{MGR}.\) Check that the eigenvalues of the (triangular) linearized system around the steady state are \(r({\hat{K}})>0\) and \(-(r({\hat{K}})-\rho )<0.\) Then apply Theorem 7.15 in Acemoglu (2009).

Consider this trajectory for \(K<{\hat{K}}.\) In this portion, \(c<1/\beta .\) Otherwise, \({\dot{K}}<A{\hat{K}}^{\alpha }-N_{0}/\beta -\delta {\hat{K}}=0\) and the path cannot converge to \({\hat{K}},\) a contradiction. Consequently, since \(r(K_{t})>r({\hat{K}})>r(K_{MGR})=\rho ,\) \({\dot{c}}>0.\) Also, \({\ddot{K}}=r(K)\dot{ K}-N_{0}{\dot{c}}.\) If \({\dot{K}}\le 0\) for some \(K<{\hat{K}},\) then \({\ddot{K}}<0,\) implying, by induction, that K is decreasing after that date along the trajectory, which again would preclude convergence. Therefore, \({\dot{K}}>0.\) Finally, by using the Cauchy-Lipschitz theorem this saddle path can always be prolonged backwards to the minimum feasible value of K\(K=0.\) Therefore we can express this trajectory as \(c=c_{SP0}(K),\) where \(c_{SP0}^{\prime }>0,\) for all \(K\in (0,{\hat{K}}]\)

Let \(c_{SP}(K)=\max (c_{SP0}(K),0).\) Clearly, \(c_{SP}(K)=0\) for K lower than some critical \(K_{c}\) (If \(c_{SP0}\) is always positive, take \(K_{c}=0\) ). Since \(c>0\) locally around the steady state, clearly \(K_{c}<{\hat{K}}.\) It is then straightforward to check that the trajectory defined by \(c_{t}=c_{SP}(K)\) and \({\dot{K}}_{t}=AK_{t}^{\alpha }-N_{0}c_{SP}(K)-\delta K_{t}\) satisfies the consumer’s optimality conditions throughout and converges to the steady state such that \(c=1/\beta\) and \(K={\hat{K}}.\) This new trajectory coincides with the preceding one for \(K\ge K_{c},\) and is clearly such that \({\dot{K}}>0\) for \(0<K<K_{c}\).

Assume that the trajectory followed by the economy is such that (cK) are along this saddle-path and \(N=N_{0}.\) To prove that this is an equilibrium trajectory, we only need to show that \(V\le 1/\gamma\) throughout. From ( 11) we have that

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}=\int _{t}^{+\infty }(\mu -1)c_{t}e^{-\int _{t}^{s}r_{u}du}ds. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(N_{0}<N_{S},\) \({\hat{K}}<K_{S}.\) Therefore \(r_{t}=r(K_{t})>r({\hat{K}})> \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }\) and \(c_{t}<1/\beta .\) Clearly, then, \(V_{t}<1/\gamma .\) \(\square\)

1.6 Proof of Proposition 4

First, we can construct a unique saddle path \((K_{t},c_{t})\) such that (i) \((K_{t},c_{t})\) satisfies the system (22-23), (ii) \(K=K_{0}\) initially and (iii) \(c=\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\) at \(K=K_{MGR}.\)Footnote 25 The same steps as in the proof of Proposition 3, B,. allow us to construct a trajectory which satisfies the consumer’s optimality conditions and coincides with that saddle path for \(c>0\), as a continuous function \(c_{SP}(K)\), defined over \((0,K_{MGR})\) such that \(\ c_{SP}\ge 0,\) \(c_{SP}^{\prime }>0\) if \(c_{SP}>0,\) \(c_{SP}(K_{MGR})=\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\), as well as to prove that \({\dot{K}}>0\) for all \(K\in (0,K_{MGR}).\) Furthemore, over the compact set \([K_{0},K_{MGR}],\) the continuous function \(AK^{\alpha }-N_{0}c_{SP}(K)-\delta K\) reaches its minimum, denoted by \(\varepsilon\). Since this expression defines \({\dot{K}},\) \(\varepsilon\) is strictly positive except perhaps if it is reached at \(K=K_{MGR}\). But at \(K=K_{MGR}\), \(c=\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\) and therefore \(\frac{dK}{dt} =(N_{N}-N_{0})\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}>0.\) Therefore \(\varepsilon >0,\) implying that the point \(c=\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}\), \(K=K_{MGR}\) is reached in finite time. Denote by T the date when it is reached.

For \(t\le T\) we assume the economy follows this trajectory.

For \(t\ge T\) we assume that c and K remain constant at \(c=\frac{\rho }{ \gamma (\mu -1)},\) \(K=K_{MGR},\) while

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{N}}=C_{MGR}-N\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(r=\rho\) and c is constant, the consumer’s local optimality conditions are clearly satisfied for \(t\ge T.\) Since c is C1 as a function t,  they are also satisfied locally around T.

Since the point \(c=\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)}=c_{N},\) \(K=K_{MGR}\) lies on II,  i.e. \(r(K_{MGR})=\rho =\gamma (\mu -1)c_{N},\) we clearly have, for \(t\ge T,\) \(V=\frac{(\mu -1)c_{N}}{r}=\frac{1}{\gamma },\) consistent with the free entry condition for innovation.

Next, we prove that \(V<1/\gamma\) for \(t<T.\) As in the proof of Proposition 3, A, we have that for \(t<T\)

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}=\int _{t}^{T}(\mu -1)c_{t}e^{-\int _{t}^{s}r_{u}du}ds+\frac{1}{\gamma } e^{-\int _{t}^{T}r_{u}du}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(K_{t}<K_{T}=K_{MGR},\) \(r_{t}>\rho .\) Furthermore, \(c_{t}<\frac{\rho }{ \gamma (\mu -1)}.\) Therefore \(V_{t}<\int _{t}^{T}\frac{\rho }{\gamma } e^{-\rho (s-t)}ds+\frac{1}{\gamma }e^{-\rho (T-t)}=1/\gamma .\)

To complete the proof, we have to show that in partial equilibrium the consumer will prefer to pick the constructed equilibrium trajectory for \(c_{t}\) as opposed to \(c_{t}=1/\beta\) throughout. This latter choice needs to be ruled out, since it satisfies the local necessary conditions for optimality and, if feasible, would clearly deliver a higher utility level. Consider a consumer who would pick \(c_{t}=1/\beta .\) His wealth \(W_{t},\) which includes productive capital as well as patents, i.e. claims on existing producers of differentiated goods, evolves as

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{W}}_{t}=r_{t}W_{t}+w_{t}-N_{t}/\beta . \end{aligned}$$

A sufficient condition for this strategy to violate the consumer’s No Ponzi Game condition is that in steady state

$$\begin{aligned} w<N/\beta . \end{aligned}$$
(24)

To check this, note that \(N/\beta =N_{N}/\beta =C_{MGR}\frac{\gamma (\mu -1) }{\rho \beta }.\) By assumption, \(\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\rho \beta }>1.\) Since the modified golden rule has less capital than the golden rule, profits are larger than investment (see Abel et al. (1989)), hence consumption is greater than the wage bill. Therefore \(C_{MGR}>w,\) so that ( 24) holds.

Finally, the property that \(N_{N}>N_{S}\) is straightforward. By assumption, \(K_{S}=r^{-1}(\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta })<K_{MGR}=r^{-1}(\rho )<K^{*},\) implying \(C_{S}<C_{MGR}.\) Therefore \(N_{N}=C_{MGR}\frac{\gamma (\mu -1) }{\rho }>\beta C_{MGR}>\beta C_{S}=N_{S}.\) \(\square\)

1.7 Proof of Proposition 7

Consider a trajectory such that (i), (ii) and (v) hold. It follows from (i) that the net marginal product of capital satisfies (iii). It is also true from (ii) that the consumption Euler equation (14) holds. Property (iv) holds by construction and from the production function \(Y_{t}=A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha }.\) In particular Y is proportional to K\(Y= \frac{r+\delta }{\alpha }K=yA.\) From (iii) and (ii) we get that the equilibrium condition for innovation \(V=\pi /r=1/\gamma\) holds. Given the equilibrium values of r and g,  the property \(n>0\) follows from the assumption that \(g_{A}<\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\left( \frac{\gamma (\mu -1) }{\beta }+\delta (1-\alpha )\right) .\) To complete the proof, just substitute the values of \(N=nA,\) \(K=kA,Y=yA\) into the capital accumulation equation (6), which can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}_{t}=A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha }-C_{t}-\delta K_{t}-{\dot{N}}_{t}/\gamma , \end{aligned}$$
(25)

and check that it is satisfied. \(\square\)

1.8 Proof of Proposition 8

The proof is similar to that of Proposition 7, with the following differences. The Euler equation now holds because \(r=\rho .\) The equilibrium consumption level is the one which guarantees equilibrium innovation at \(r=\rho .\) The assumption \(\rho <\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }\) guarantees that this level is below satiation. In addition, the consumer’s transversality condition has to hold (it always holds under satiation). For this to be the case we need that \(r>g,\) which is implied by the assumption that \(g_{A}<(1-\alpha )\rho .\) This in turn guarantees that \((\rho +\delta )/\alpha -g-\delta >0,\) i.e. that N is positive along the trajectory. \(\square\)

1.9 Proof of Proposition 9

We construct a trajectory based on a path \(\{c_{t}\}.\) Clearly, the only degree of freedom is in picking the initial value of c\(c_{0}\), since the subsequent trajectory for c is pinned down by the Euler equation. Let us impose that the economy is in the innovation regime throughout. Then \(r_{t}=\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t},\) implying that

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t}=\left( \frac{\alpha A_{t}}{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta }\right) ^{ \frac{1}{1-\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Since K is a state variable, this pins down the initial c\(c_{0}.\) From the Euler equation (14), provided \(c_{0}>\frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)} ,\) \(r>\rho\) throughout and \(c_{t}\rightarrow 1/\beta .\) Furthermore, from the expression for k in (15), for \(k_{0}=K_{0}/A_{0}^{\frac{1}{ 1-\alpha }}\) above and close enough to k\(c_{0}\) will be below and close to \(1/\beta ,\) and therefore above \(\rho /(\gamma (\mu -1)),\) implying indeed that \(c_{t}\longrightarrow 1/\beta .\)

To have \(L_{t}=1,\) throughout, we need that \(w_{t}(1-\beta c_{t})>\mu \tau .\) Note that

$$\begin{aligned} w_{t}= & {} (1-\alpha )A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha } \\= & {} \left( \frac{\alpha }{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta }\right) ^{\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }}(1-\alpha )A_{t}^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$

I now show that \(w_{t}(1-\beta c_{t})\) grows over time. Let \(\ Q_{t}=A_{t}^{ \frac{1}{1-\alpha }}\left( \gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta \right) ^{-\frac{ \alpha }{1-\alpha }}(1-\beta c_{t})\). From the fact that \(r_{t}=\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}\) and the Euler condition (14) we get that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{Q}}}{Q}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha }g_{A}-\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }\left( \frac{1}{\beta }-c_{t}\right) \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}}{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta }\left( \gamma (\mu -1)-\rho /c_{t}\right) \\&-\frac{\beta }{ 1-\beta c_{t}}\left( \frac{1}{\beta }-c_{t}\right) (\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho ) \end{aligned}$$

A sufficient condition for Q to grow over time is therefore

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{1-\alpha }g_{A}-\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }\left( \frac{1}{\beta } -c_{t}\right) \left( \gamma (\mu -1)-\rho /c_{t}\right) -(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho )>0. \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, since we have assumed that \(g_{A}>(1-\alpha )\left[ \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }-\rho \right] ,\) this holds if c close enough to \(1/\beta ,\) i.e. again \(K/A^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}\) close enough to k. Along our trajectory c goes up and \(K/A^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}\) falls. Therefore, we can always pick initial conditions so that these two quantities are arbitrarily close to \(1/\beta\) and k,  respectively. In such a case, Q and therefore \(w(1-\beta c)\) grow over time, so that the inequality \(w_{t}(1-\beta c_{t})>\mu \tau\) will hold for all t,  provided it holds initially, that is

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{\alpha }{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{0}+\delta }\right) ^{\frac{\alpha }{ 1-\alpha }}(1-\alpha )A_{0}^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}(1-\beta c_{0})>0. \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, given the initial value of \(k_{0}\) and hence of \(c_{0},\) the preceding inequality holds for \(A_{0}\) large enough.

To summarize, there exists \(\eta\) such that we can choose \(k_{0}\in (k,k+\eta )\) and \(A_{0}>A(k_{0})\) in such a way that for \(K_{0}=k_{0}A_{0}^{ \frac{1}{1-\alpha }},\) the trajectory for \(K_{t}\) defined by (26), with \(\{c_{t}\}\) the unique solution to (14) such that (26) holds at \(t=0,\) is such that the representative consumer would pick \(L=1\) throughout. Furthermore, by construction the economy is in the innovation regime throughout, and since \(c_{t}\longrightarrow 1/\beta ,\) \(k_{t}=K_{t}/A_{t}^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}\longrightarrow k.\)

To complete our construction, we have to check the feasibility of the implied trajectory for \(N_{t}.\) Let \(g=g_{A}/(1-\alpha )\) and \(n_{t}=N_{t}/A_{t}^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}.\) Using (25) we get that

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{n}}_{t}/\gamma =k_{t}^{\alpha }-\delta k_{t}-{\dot{k}} _{t}-gk_{t}-c_{t}n_{t}-gn_{t}/\gamma . \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(n=\frac{k^{\alpha }-(g+\delta )k}{1/\beta +g/\gamma }.\) Clearly, then, as \(c_{t}\rightarrow 1/\beta\) and \(k_{t}\rightarrow k,n_{t}\rightarrow n.\) Since \(\frac{1}{\alpha }\left( \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{ \beta }+\delta (1-\alpha )\right) >\frac{g_{A}}{1-\alpha },\) by (16) \(n>0.\) For the trajectory for N to be feasible, we need that \({\dot{N}} _{t}\ge 0\) throughout. Note that we can always choose \(\eta\) small enough such that the quantity \(k_{t}^{\alpha }-(g+\delta )k_{t}\) is arbitrarily close to \((1/\beta +g/\gamma )n\) and \(c_{t}\) is arbitrarily close to \(1/\beta .\) Then

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{n}}_{t}}{\gamma n_{t}}=-\frac{{\dot{k}}_{t}}{n_{t}}+\left( \frac{ k_{t}^{\alpha }-(g+\delta )k_{t}}{n_{t}}-\frac{(1/\beta +g/\gamma )n}{n_{t}} \right) +\left( \frac{(1/\beta +g/\gamma )n}{n_{t}}-(c_{t}+\frac{g}{\gamma } )\right) . \end{aligned}$$

If \(n_{t}\) is sufficiently close to n,  the two terms in brackets are arbitrarily small. Since the first term is \(>0,\) this can be made larger than any negative number. In particular, larger than \(-g/\gamma .\) Thus we can pick \(k_{0}\) and \(n_{0}\) simultaneously close enough to k and n to make sure that \({\dot{N}}/N={\dot{n}}/n+g>0.\) \(\square\)

1.10 Proof of Proposition 10

We construct our trajectory in a similar fashion as for Proposition  9. Given a path for \(c_{t},\) we make sure that we are in the innovation regime and that there is an interior solution for labor supply. That is

$$\begin{aligned} r_{t}= & {} \alpha A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha -1}L_{t}^{1-\alpha }-\delta \\= & {} \gamma (\mu -1)c_{t} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}= & {} \frac{w_{t}}{\tau \mu }(1-\beta c_{t}) \\= & {} \left[ \frac{(1-\alpha )A_{t}}{\tau \mu }\right] ^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha } }K_{t}^{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }}(1-\beta c_{t})^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha }}, \end{aligned}$$

where the marginal productivity condition \(w_{t}=(1-\alpha )A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha }L_{t}^{-\alpha }\) has been used to derive this last expression. In turn, we can solve for K and L as a function of c : 

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t}=\varphi A_{t}^{\frac{2}{1-\alpha }}(1-\beta c_{t})(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta )^{-\frac{1+\alpha }{1-\alpha }}, \end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}=\psi A_{t}^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}(1-\beta c_{t})(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta )^{-\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

The composite parameters \(\varphi\) and \(\psi\) are defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi= & {} \alpha ^{\frac{1+\alpha }{1-\alpha }}\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\tau \mu }\right) , \\ \psi= & {} \left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\tau \mu }\right) ^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha } }\varphi ^{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$

We note that (27) defines K as a decreasing function of c which maps \((0,1/\beta )\) onto \((0,K_{\max }),\) where \(K_{\max }=\varphi A_{t}^{ \frac{2}{1-\alpha }}\delta ^{-\frac{1+\alpha }{1-\alpha }}.\) Therefore, for \(K_{0}<K_{\max }\) there exists a unique \(c_{0}\) associated with the initial capital stock \(K_{0}.\)

Since (14) here is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{c}}_{t}=\left( \frac{1}{\beta }-c_{t}\right) \left( \gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(29)

if \(\kappa _{0}=K_{0}/A_{0}^{\frac{2}{1-\alpha }}\) is not too large,  i.e. \(\kappa _{0}<\varphi (1-\beta \frac{\rho }{\gamma (\mu -1)})(\rho +\delta )^{- \frac{1+\alpha }{1-\alpha }},\) then \(c_{0}>\rho /(\gamma (\mu -1))\) and we clearly have that \({\dot{c}}>0\) throughout and \(c_{t}\rightarrow 1/\beta .\) Then, using (29) and (27), we have that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{K}}_{t}}{K_{t}}=\frac{2}{1-\alpha }g_{A}-(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho )-\frac{1+\alpha }{1-\alpha }\frac{\left( \gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho \right) (1/\beta -c_{t})}{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta }. \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Therefore

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{{\dot{K}}_{t}}{K_{t}}=\frac{2}{1-\alpha } g_{A}-\left( \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }-\rho \right) =g>0, \end{aligned}$$
(31)

where the inequality comes from the assumption that \(g_{A}>\frac{1-\alpha }{2 }(\gamma (\mu -1)/\beta -\rho ).\) A corollary is that for \(0<g^{\prime }<g,\) if \(c_{t}\) is close enough to \(1/\beta ,\) the RHS of (30) is \(>g^{\prime }.\) Since, from (27), for \(\kappa _{0}\) small enough \(c_{0}\) is arbitrarily close to \(1/\beta\), we can always pick \(\kappa _{0}\) small enough so that \(\frac{{\dot{K}}_{t}}{K_{t}}>g^{\prime }>0\) throughout our entire constructed trajectory.

It is also possible to compute \(Y_{t}=A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha }L_{t}^{1-\alpha },\) and we get

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}=\chi A_{t}^{\frac{2}{1-\alpha }}(1-\beta c_{t})(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta )^{-\frac{2\alpha }{1-\alpha }}, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \chi =\varphi ^{\alpha }\psi ^{1-\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$

Again \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{{\dot{Y}}_{t}}{Y_{t}}=g.\)

Turning now to labor supply, we have to make sure that \(L_{t}\) as defined by (28) remains \(<1\) throughout. We have that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{L}}_{t}}{L_{t}}=\frac{1}{1-\alpha }g_{A}-(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho )-\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }\frac{\left( \gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}-\rho \right) (1/\beta -c_{t})}{\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta }. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Consequently,

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{{\dot{L}}_{t}}{L_{t}}=\frac{1}{1-\alpha } g_{A}-\left( \frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }-\rho \right) =g_{L}<0, \end{aligned}$$

where the inequality comes from the assumption that \(g_{A}<(1-\alpha )(\gamma (\mu -1)/\beta -\rho ).\)

Clearly, then, if \(c_{t}\) is close enough to \(1/\beta ,\) the RHS of (32 ) is negative. Since \(c_{t}\) grows over time, all we need for this to be the case for all t is that \(c_{0}\) is close enough to \(1/\beta ,\) or equivalently, again, that \(\kappa _{0}\) is not too large. Then, for \(L_{t}\) to be lower than 1, we just need it to be lower than 1 initially. Substituting (27) into (28), we get that

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}=\frac{\psi }{\varphi }A_{t}^{-\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}K_{t}(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta )^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$

Thus we have \(L_{0}<1\) provided \(\lambda _{0}=K_{0}A_{0}^{-\frac{1}{1-\alpha }\text { }}\)is small enough. Denoting by \(\eta\) and \(\varsigma\) the upper bounds for \(\kappa _{0}\) and \(\lambda _{0}\) respectively, we can summarize our sufficient conditions on initial capital as \(K_{0}\le \min (\eta A_{0}^{ \frac{2}{1-\alpha }},\varsigma A_{0}^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}).\)

To conclude the proof, we need to check that the implied trajectory for \(N_{t}\) is feasible. Let \(z_{t}=N_{t}/K_{t}.\) The law of motion (25) is now replaced with

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}_{t}=A_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha }L_{t}^{1-\alpha }-C_{t}-\delta K_{t}-{\dot{N}} _{t}/\gamma . \end{aligned}$$
(33)

Using (27) and (28), it can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{z}}_{t}}{\gamma }=\frac{1}{\alpha }(\gamma (\mu -1)c_{t}+\delta )-z_{t}\left( c_{t}+\frac{1}{\gamma }\frac{{\dot{K}}_{t}}{K_{t}}\right) -\delta -\frac{\dot{ K}_{t}}{K_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, then \(z_{t}\rightarrow \frac{\frac{1}{\alpha }(\frac{\gamma (\mu -1) }{\beta }+\delta )-g-\delta }{1/\beta +g/\gamma }=z.\) From the definition of g in (31), this expression is positive iff

$$\begin{aligned} g_{A}<\frac{1-\alpha }{2}\left[ \frac{1+\alpha }{\alpha }\frac{\gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }+\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\delta -\rho \right] . \end{aligned}$$

The expression on the RHS is always larger than \((1-\alpha )\left( \frac{ \gamma (\mu -1)}{\beta }-\rho \right) ,\) which is \(>g_{A}\) by (19).

Recall that by picking \(\kappa _{0}\) small enough, we can have \(c_{t}\) arbitrarily close to \(1/\beta\) and \(\frac{{\dot{K}}_{t}}{K_{t}}\) arbitrarily close to g throughout the entire trajectory. If in addition to that, we pick \(z_{0}\) close enough to z,  i.e. \(N_{0}\in (K_{0}z(1-\varepsilon ),K_{0}z(1+\varepsilon ))\) for some \(\varepsilon >0,\) then \({\dot{z}} _{t}/z_{t}\) will be arbitrarily close to zero. Consequently, \(N_{t}=z_{t}K_{t}\) will grow at a strictly positive rate throughout. This proves that the trajectory for N is feasible. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Saint-Paul, G. Secular satiation. J Econ Growth 26, 291–327 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-021-09192-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-021-09192-z

Keywords

JEL

Navigation