Skip to main content
Log in

Retailer voluntary investment against a threat of manufacturer encroachment

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

To elucidate supply chain cooperation between a manufacturer and a retailer, this study examines a model in which the retailer makes voluntary investments to reduce the marginal production cost of the manufacturer. The manufacturer is allowed to introduce a direct selling channel in addition to the indirect channel through the retailer (i.e., manufacturer encroachment), which however dampens the retailers’ investment incentives. The retailer can leverage its voluntary investments as a means of deterring manufacturer encroachment. We demonstrate that manufacturer encroachment is strategically deterred when the retailer’s cost-reduction technology is sufficiently effective. This strategic encroachment deterrence encourages the retailer to invest more, but it narrows the variety of channels from which consumers can select. When the latter effect dominates the former effect, consumer surplus declines with strategic encroachment deterrence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For instance, the Shanghai office of Fast Retailing has an official technical support team, the Takumi Team, comprising technical experts with more than 30-year experience in sewing and plant management. The Takumi Team gives textile production technology to partner manufacturers located in China, which improves the production process efficiency. Fast Retailing corporate annual reports of 2005 and 2006 present relevant details. Sources: https://www.fastretailing.com/eng/ir/library/pdf/annual2005.pdf and https://www.fastretailing.com/eng/ir/library/pdf/annual2006_05.pdf Last visited August 11, 2020.

  2. According to (Cooper and Slugmulder 1999), when Miyota fails to meet its target costs, Citizen sends technical staff to help reduce its production costs.

  3. Theoretically, firms are likely to face quantity competition. Actually, Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) state that price competition may yield into quantity competition when considering long-term product market competition. Therefore, this study examines quantity competition.

  4. The analyses in this paper differ from Yoon (2016) and Matsushima and Mizuno (2018) in that we examine the retailer’s voluntary investments. Yoon (2016) allows a manufacturer to make investments that reduce its own marginal cost, whereas Matsushima and Mizuno (2018) consider a retailer’s selfish cost-reducing investments.

  5. Source: https://services.amazon.com/selling/pricing.htm/ Last visited July 16, 2020.

References

  • Arya, A, & Mittendorf, B. (2013). The changing face of distribution channels: Partial forward integration and strategic investments. Production and Operations Management, 22(5), 1077–1088.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arya, A, Mittendorf, B, & Sappington, DE. (2007). The bright side of supplier encroachment. Marketing Science, 26(5), 651–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, J, Liang, L, Yao, DQ, & Sun, S. (2017). Price and quality decisions in dual-channel supply chains. European Journal of Operational Research, 259(3), 935–948.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, W Y, Chhajed, D, & Hess, JD. (2003). Direct marketing, indirect profits: A strategic analysis of dual-channel supply chain design. Management Science, 49(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R, & Slugmulder, R. (1999). Supply chain development for the lean enterprise: Interorganizational cost management (strategies in confrontational cost management series). Productivity Press.

  • Dan, B, Xu, G, & Liu, C. (2012). Pricing policies in a dual-channel supply chain with retail services. International Journal of Production Economics, 139(1), 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1979). A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 20–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X, Liu, B, Chen, YJ, & Wang, H. (2020). Inducing supply chain transparency through supplier encroachment. Production and Operations Management, 29(3), 725–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gopalakrishnan, S, Granot, D, Granot, F, Sošisić, G, & Cui, H. (2021). Incentives and emission responsibility allocation in supply chains. Management Science: Articles In Advance.

  • Hsiao, L, & Chen, YJ. (2013). The perils of selling online: Manufacturer competition, channel conflict, and consumer preferences. Marketing Letters, 24(3), 277–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konur, D. (2020). Collaborative emission targets joining and quantity flow decisions in a Stackelberg setting. Journal of Cleaner Production, 249, 119425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D M, & Scheinkman, JA. (1983). Quantity precommitment and Bertrand competition yield Cournot outcomes. The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2), 326–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Z, Gilbert, SM, & Lai, G. (2014). Supplier encroachment under asymmetric information. Management Science, 60(2), 449–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsui, K. (2016). Asymmetric product distribution between symmetric manufacturers using dual-channel supply chains. European Journal of Operational Research, 248(2), 646–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsui, K. (2020). Optimal bargaining timing of a wholesale price for a manufacturer with a retailer in a dual-channel supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 287(1), 225–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsushima, N, & Mizuno, T. (2018). Supplier encroachment and retailer effort. ISER Discussion Paper.

  • Mizuno, T. (2012). Direct marketing in oligopoly. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 21(2), 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan, M, & Sošić, G. (2008). Game–theoretic analysis of cooperation among supply chain agents: Review and extensions. European Journal of Operational Research, 187(3), 719–745.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pei, Z, & Yan, R. (2015). Do channel members value supportive retail services? Why? Journal of Business Research, 68(6), 1350–1358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, N, & Vives, X. (1984). Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. The RAND Journal of Economics, 15(4), 546–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, X, Tang, W, Chen, J, Li, S, & Zhang, J. (2019). Manufacturer encroachment with production cost reduction under asymmetric information. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 128, 191–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, AA, & Agrawal, N. (2004). Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age. Production and Operations Management, 13(1), 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoon, DH. (2016). Supplier encroachment and investment spillovers. Production and Operations Management, 25(11), 1839–1854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J, Cao, Q, & He, X. (2020). Manufacturer encroachment with advertising. OMEGA, 91, 102013.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, R, Ma, W, Si, H, Liu, J, & Liao, L. (2021). Cooperative game analysis of coordination mechanisms under fairness concerns of a green retailer. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 59, 201361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, JZ, Watson, G.F. IV, & Palmatier, RW. (2018). Customer relationships evolve — So must your CRM strategy. MIT Sloan Management Review, 59(3), 1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, S, Zhang, J, & Zhu, G. (2019). Retail service investing: An anti-encroachment strategy in a retailer-led supply chain. OMEGA, 84, 212–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are truly indebted to Natalie Mizik (editor-in-chief) and two anonymous referees for their invaluable comments and suggestions. We would like to thank Noriaki Matsushima, seminar participants at The University of Kitakyushu, and participants at the 2020 JAAE autumn conference online. This work was partially supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers 17H00959, 18K12909, 19H01474, 20H01551, and 21K13409. The usual disclaimers apply.

Funding

JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers 17H00959, 18K12909, 19H01474, 20H01551, and 21K13409.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jumpei Hamamura.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Author contributions

Analysis and writing: Jumpei Hamamura and Yusuke Zennyo. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proofs of results derived in the main model

Proof of Lemma 1

First, it is apparent that

$$ \left. {x_{R}^{E}} \right|_{\theta=0} = \frac{a-c}{8bk-1} = {x_{R}^{N}} . $$
(A.1)

Next, the partial derivative of \({x_{R}^{E}}\) with respect to 𝜃 is given as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{\partial {x_{R}^{E}}}{\partial \theta}=-\frac{16 b (1-\theta ) \left( 64 -48 \theta+18 \theta^{3} -9 \theta^{4}\right) k (a-c)}{\left[b \left( 8-3 \theta^{2}\right)^{2} k-8 (1-\theta )^{2}\right]^{2}}<0. \end{array} $$
(A.2)

Proof of Proposition 1

Computing \({\pi _{R}^{N}} - {\pi _{R}^{E}}\) yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {\pi_{R}^{N}} - {\pi_{R}^{E}}=\frac{b \theta \left( 128-112 \theta +9 \theta^{3}\right) k^{2} (a-c)^{2}}{2 (8 b k-1) \left[b \left( 8-3 \theta^{2}\right)^{2} k-8 (\theta -1)^{2}\right]}, \end{array} $$
(A.3)

which is greater than zero under Assumption 1. □

Proof of Proposition 2

Solving \({\pi _{M}^{N}} > {\pi _{M}^{E}}\) yields

$$ \frac{\Phi-\theta(128-112\theta+9\theta^{3})\sqrt{\Psi}} {8b(8-3\theta^{2})^{3}(16-16\theta+5\theta^{2})} <k< \frac{\Phi+\theta(128-112\theta+9\theta^{3})\sqrt{\Psi}} {8b(8-3\theta^{2})^{3}(16-16\theta+5\theta^{2})} \equiv \tilde{k}, $$
(A.4)

where Φ = 2(8 − 3𝜃2)2(64 − 60𝜃2 + 24𝜃3 − 3𝜃4) > 0 and Ψ = 2(2 − 𝜃)(6 − 𝜃)(8 − 3𝜃2)3 > 0.

Moreover, \(\underline {k}\) lies within the interval presented in Inequality Eq. A.4. Therefore, it holds that \({\pi _{M}^{N}}>{\pi _{M}^{E}}\) if and only if \(\underline {k}<k<\tilde {k}\). □

Proof of Corollary 1

The partial derivative of \(\tilde {k}\) with respect to 𝜃 is given as

$$ \frac{\partial \tilde{k}}{\partial \theta} = \frac{\sqrt{2}(1-\theta) \cdot {\Xi}} {2b(8-3\theta^{2})^{2}(16-16\theta+5\theta^{2})^{2}\sqrt{\Psi}} , $$
(A.5)

where \({\Xi } = 2(8-3\theta ^{2})(49152-85016\theta +74752\theta ^{2}-54016\theta ^{3}+29824\theta ^{4}-8688\theta ^{5}+840\theta ^{6}+27\theta ^{7})+4(1024-768\theta +192\theta ^{2}-288\theta ^{3}+192\theta ^{4}-27\theta ^{5})\sqrt {\Psi }\). It is noteworthy that Ξ consists of a parameter, which is 𝜃 only. We can demonstrate that Ξ takes a positive value for all 𝜃 ∈ [0, 1]. □

Proof of Proposition 3

Solving CSN > CSE gives

$$ \frac{{\Phi}_{CS}-\theta(8-3\theta)\sqrt{{\Psi}_{CS}}} {4b(8-3\theta^{2})(16+8\theta-9\theta^{2})} <k< \frac{{\Phi}_{CS}+\theta(8-3\theta)\sqrt{{\Psi}_{CS}}} {4b(8-3\theta^{2})(16+8\theta-9\theta^{2})} \equiv \tilde{k}_{CS}, $$
(A.6)

where ΦCS = 2(2 − 𝜃)(2 + 3𝜃)(8 − 3𝜃2) > 0 and ΨCS = 80 − 76𝜃2 + 12𝜃3 + 9𝜃4 > 0.

Moreover, \(\underline {k}\) lies within the interval presented in Inequality Eq. A.6. Therefore, it holds that CSN > CSE if and only if \(\underline {k}<k<\tilde {k}_{CS}\).

Additionally, comparison between \(\tilde {k}\) and \(\tilde {k}_{CS}\) relies on parameter 𝜃 only. One can show that \(\tilde {k}>\tilde {k}_{CS}\) holds for any 𝜃 ∈ [0, 1]. □

Proof of Proposition 4

Solving SWN > SWE gives

$$ \frac{{\Phi}_{SW}-\theta(4+\theta)(8-3\theta)(4-3\theta)\sqrt{{\Psi}_{SW}}} {8b(8-3\theta^{2})^{2} \cdot {\Xi}_{SW}} <k< \frac{{\Phi}_{SW}+\theta(4+\theta)(8-3\theta)(4-3\theta)\sqrt{{\Psi}_{SW}}} {8b(8-3\theta^{2})^{2} \cdot {\Xi}_{SW}} \equiv \tilde{k}_{SW}, $$
(A.7)

where ΦSW = 49152 − 8192𝜃− 60416𝜃2− 7168𝜃3+ 49024𝜃4− 10368𝜃5− 7344𝜃6+ 2160𝜃7+ 27𝜃8 > 0, ΨSW = 348160 − 163840𝜃− 413696𝜃2+ 171008𝜃3+ 192064𝜃4− 78336𝜃5− 28656𝜃6+ 10800𝜃7+ 621𝜃8 > 0, and ΞSW = 768 − 768𝜃 − 64𝜃2 + 240𝜃3 − 51𝜃4 > 0.

Moreover, \(\underline {k}\) lies within the interval presented in Inequality Eq. A.7. Therefore, it holds that SWN > SWE if and only if \(\underline {k}<k<\tilde {k}_{SW}\).

Additionally, comparison between \(\tilde {k}\) and \(\tilde {k}_{SW}\) relies solely on parameter 𝜃. One can demonstrate that \(\tilde {k}<\tilde {k}_{SW}\) holds if and only if \(\tilde {\theta }_{SW} \leq \theta \leq 1\), where \(\tilde {\theta }_{SW} \simeq 0.689911\). □

Appendix B: Analysis for Section 5.1

We reverse the order of decisions of stages 1 and 2 in the original game. Specifically, the timing of the game is the following. In stage 1, the retailer chooses the level of voluntary investment. In stage 2, the manufacturer decides whether to open its direct channel. In stage 3, the manufacturer charges a wholesale price. In stage 4, Cournot competition takes place in the retail market. Then, we solve the game using backward induction.

Analyses for stages 3 and 4 are the same as those of the main model. That is, without encroachment, the manufacturer sets w = (a + cxR)/2 in stage 3; then, the retailer chooses qR = (ac + xR)/(4b). The resulting profits of the manufacturer and the retailer are computed as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{M} &=& \frac{(a-c+x_{R})^{2}}{8b}, \end{array} $$
(B.1)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{R} &=& \frac{(a-c+x_{R})^{2}}{16b} - \frac{k}{2} {x_{R}^{2}}. \end{array} $$
(B.2)

By contrast, with encroachment, the manufacturer sets its wholesale price at the one presented in Eq. 8 in stage 3. In stage 4, Cournot competition occurs. The quantities sold by the manufacturer and the retailer are therefore computed as qM = (ac + xR)(2 − 𝜃)(4 + 𝜃)/2b(8 − 3𝜃2) and qR = 2(ac + xR)(1 − 𝜃)/b(8 − 3𝜃2). Then, the resulting profits are given as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{M} &=& \frac{(a-c+x_{R})^{2}(12-8\theta+\theta^{2})}{4b(8-3\theta^{2})}, \end{array} $$
(B.3)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{R} &=& \frac{4(a-c+x_{R})^{2}(1-\theta)^{2}}{b(8-3\theta^{2})^{2}} - \frac{k}{2} {x_{R}^{2}}. \end{array} $$
(B.4)

In stage 2, given xR, the manufacturer decides whether to encroach or not. Comparison between Eqs. B.1 and B.3 reveals that the manufacturer certainly chooses to encroach for any xR.

In stage 1, the retailer anticipates manufacturer encroachment; then the retailer chooses its investment level to maximize the profit presented in Eq. B.4, implying that \(x_{R} = {x_{R}^{E}}\). The resulting investment level and other equilibrium outcomes are equal to the values derived in the right column of Table 2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hamamura, J., Zennyo, Y. Retailer voluntary investment against a threat of manufacturer encroachment. Mark Lett 32, 379–395 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-021-09575-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-021-09575-7

Keywords

Navigation