Skip to main content
Log in

The case for subsidizing harm: constrained and costly Pigouvian taxation with multiple externalities

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many activities are subsidized despite generating negative externalities. Examples include needle exchanges and energy production subsidies. We explain this phenomenon by developing a model in which the policymaker faces constraints or costs. We highlight three examples. First, it may be optimal to subsidize a harmful activity if the policymaker cannot set the first-best tax on an externally harmful substitute. Second, it may be optimal to subsidize a harmful production process if the activity mix at lower levels of output uses more harmful activities than the activity mix at higher levels of output. Third, it may be optimal to subsidize a harmful activity if there is a large administrative cost associated with taxing a harmful substitute. We also show how the functional form of the cost of administering a Pigouvian tax affects the optimal tax. When administrative cost is a function of only tax rates, the policymaker should tax each activity. However, an increase in the tax presents a trade-off: lower externality but higher administrative cost. A subsidy may be optimal for some externally harmful activities. When administrative cost is a function of only activity levels, it may not be optimal to tax every activity. If it is optimal to tax each activity, the policymaker should set the tax equal to the externality plus the marginal administrative cost. If it is not optimal to tax every activity, the complementarity between activities comes into play, and it may be optimal to subsidize externally harmful activities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is a partial list of the external harms discussed in the World Energy Council’s 2016 World Energy Resource Report. Energy subsidies exceeded $600 billion dollars globally in 2017 (Taylor 2020).

  2. There are many different polluting activities, each of which releases different combinations of pollutants. The EPA requires factories to report on 650 chemicals, which are produced by several different productive activities, in a Toxic Release Inventory report.

  3. Our analysis generalizes Wijkander (1985) in two ways. First, we allow an arbitrary number of externally harmful activities, which makes an optimal subsidy on a harmful activity possible. Second, we allow the policymaker to face arbitrary constraints on the taxes she may impose. In Wijkander (1985)’s model, the binding constraint on the tax is equal to 0. Our model includes the cases in which the policymaker can tax externally harmful activities but is unable to set the efficient tax because of, for example, distributional concerns or a powerful lobby.

  4. Polinsky and Shavell (1982) develop a model with one externality in which administrative costs are fixed per firm and the tax causes the number of firms to vary. Polinsky and Shavell (1982) do not explore administrative costs that are a function of taxes alone.

  5. Green and Sheshinski (1976) show that when there are heterogeneous agents facing a congestion externality, it is possible that individuals choose higher levels of the externally harmful activity the more external harm there is, in which case indirect correction may be superior to direction correction. Congestion externalities cause no external harm to the individual who generates them. We study atmosphere externalities, which harm everyone regardless of who generates them.

  6. Our focus is on second-best environments that restrict the instruments available to the policymaker. However, there is a large body of literature that studies the second-best question of how a policymaker should use corrective taxation in the presence of other distortionary taxes, including Kaplow (1990), Bovenberg et al. (1994), Bovenberg and van der Ploeg (1994), Bovenberg and Goulder (1996), Parry (1997), Fullerton (1997), Pirttilä and Tuomala (1997), Cremer et al. (1998), Goulder (1998), Parry (1998), Goulder et al. (1999), Pirttilä (2000), Cremer and Gahvari (2001), Kaplow (2012), Gahvari (2014), and Jacobs and de Mooij (2015). Many of these papers also address distributional issues that we do not explore here. Notably, Bovenberg and Goulder (1996) show that if the revenue from corrective taxes is lump-sum distributed and not used to reduce distortionary taxes, then—when external harm is sufficiently small—it may be optimal for the policymaker to subsidize the externally harmful activity.

  7. As Table 2 describes, Polinsky and Shavell (1982) study a subset of the administrative cost functional forms that we study here.

  8. An activity is defined as a specific action undertaken at a specific time and in a specific place—for example, burning coal in San Francisco on July 1, 2020. With this level of specificity, each activity will have a well-defined externality.

  9. Activities have private benefit either directly or—because they result in the production of valuable goods that have a private benefit—indirectly. Thus, activities would include both dancing and burning coal. Dancing would have a direct private benefit, and burning coal would be used in the production of a good. There are, of course, many goods for which burning coal might be a part of the production process. The private market ensures that the goods with the highest net private benefit are produced. As in Becker (1965), the private benefit of activities may vary with the available goods.

  10. One way to ensure this outcome is to assume that \(\lim _{x_i \searrow \partial X} \tfrac{\partial {b}}{\partial {x_i}} = \infty\) and \(\lim _{x_i \nearrow \partial X} \tfrac{\partial {b}}{\partial {x_i}} = -\infty\).

  11. The net benefit approach cannot generally model non-competitive settings because, as Buchanan (1969) shows, market power changes the equilibrium level of activities, which may incidentally correct or exacerbate external harm. If so, the relationship between taxes and uncorrected external harm would require additional assumptions to model.

  12. We use matrix calculus and the associated notation, including \(^\top\) to denote a matrix’s transpose.

  13. This is true because the net benefit function is strictly concave, which rules out both perfect substitutes and perfect complements relationships between activities.

  14. Some papers, for example, Jacobsen et al. (2020), use the stronger assumption that \(x'(\gamma (r))\) is constant for \(r \in [0,1]\). Under this stronger assumption \(\frac{1}{2}(w - e)^\top \Delta x = \frac{1}{2}(w - e)^\top x'(e) (w - e)\).

  15. We omit analysis of the similar case in which the policymaker must set activity taxes above a certain level.

  16. An common example is undetectable illegal dumping (Fullerton and Kinnaman 1995).

  17. The net benefit approach allows a flexible relationship between activities even when there are only two. This can be reconciled to utility maximization by noting that net benefit maximization may be interpreted as utility maximization with an additional activity that is untaxed and causes no external harm (see appendix). As a consequence, when using a net benefit function, there is no requirement that activities be Hicksian substitutes when there are only two.

  18. Consider a very harmful activity with a low binding constraint. Optimal policy would require the policymaker to tax any complement above the marginal externality of that complement. But the complement might too face a binding constraint. Thus, with more than two externally harmful activities, it is possible to have a binding constraint \(T_j > e_j\), and technically possible to have a knife-edge case with a binding constraint \(T_j = e_j\).

  19. A special case of this model occurs when some activities are untaxable, in which case those activities have taxes with a binding constraint equal to 0. The uncorrected externality of the untaxable activities is equal to the marginal externality. If all binding constraints are equal to 0, (36) becomes

    $$\begin{aligned} {t_i}^* = e_i + \sum _{j=m+1}^n e_j \tfrac{\partial {x_j}}{\partial {x_i}} \end{aligned}$$

    Wijkander (1985) studies this problem when there are three activities, one of which is externally harmful but untaxable.

  20. One possible interpretation of a tax on a single output is a tax on income or consumption.

  21. As discussed in appendix, we assume private benefit is a function of output, and private cost is a function of activity levels. There is, thus, a relationship between private net benefit and output.

  22. As noted previously, many activities do not directly increase private benefit but do so indirectly as part of a production process for goods. For example, burning coal does not directly have a private net benefit (in most instances), but the energy derived from burning coal is used for many things that do have a private benefit.

  23. \(x(\tau )\) is well defined. See appendix.

  24. See appendix for a proof that A is negative definite. Recall that \(x'(t) = [b''(x)]^{-1}\). \(x'(\tau )\) is related, but, instead of keeping marginal private net benefit equal to the tax vector, it ensures that the marginal private net benefit of each activity is proportional to its marginal product. Moreover, the vector of marginal products plays a role in \(x'(\tau )\) because a change in \(\tau\) effectively changes the tax on each activity in proportion to its marginal product.

  25. This is somewhat abusive notation. x(t) is the mapping from activity taxes to activity levels, and \(x(\tau )\) is the mapping from output tax to activity levels.

  26. (3) is a necessary condition. Moreover, since the Hessians of b and q are symmetric, this is the same as saying that either the private marginal cost of solar activity increases with coal activity or the marginal product of solar activity decreases with coal activity or both.

  27. Although more enforcement requires a resource cost that higher rates do not, there are important cases in which more enforcement is optimal. First, when there are some taxpayers that completely evade and some that do not, then there is an increased distortion because of the higher effective tax rate on those that pay. Second, when evading requires resources (and more resources are spent at higher tax rates), more enforcement may be optimal.

  28. Similarly, if there is a positive externality, the subsidy rate is always lower than the case with no administrative cost.

  29. For positive externalities, \(\tfrac{\partial {c}}{\partial {t}}/\tfrac{\partial {x}}{\partial {t}} > 0\). In either case, the optimal tax will never be 0 because the marginal administrative cost is 0 at \(t=0\).

  30. However, the optimal subsidy is always smaller than the case with no administrative cost.

  31. Subsidies distort the private market in the same way that taxes do. Interpreting the net benefit model as a utility maximization problem in which one activity does not appear in b (see appendix), the subsidy inefficiently increases x and decreases the implicit activity.

  32. Because \(t'(x)^{-1} = x'(t)\), the sign of \(\tfrac{\partial {t_c}}{\partial {x_s}}\) will be the opposite of the sign of \(\tfrac{\partial {x_c}}{\partial {t_s}}\). If the policymaker wishes to marginally increase \(x_c\) holding \(x_s\) constant and if the two are substitutes, she must decrease both taxes. Thus, \(\tfrac{\partial {t_c}}{\partial {x_s}}<0\) if solar and coal are substitutes.

  33. Depending on the third derivative of b, there are other dynamics in the model by which changes in the marginal external harm of one activity would affect the optimal tax on another.

  34. Theoretically, the knife-edge case in which \(t^*_i = e_i + \sum _j \tfrac{\partial {c}}{\partial {t_j}} \tfrac{\partial {t_j}}{\partial {x_i}} = 0\) is possible.

  35. The matrix \(t'(x(t^*)) = b''(x(t^*))\) describes the effect of a change in the activity vector on tax rates at the optimal tax rate. Because b is concave, this matrix is negative definite, so the diagonals are all negative. An increase in \(t_i\) will, thus, reduce \(x_i\) although it may increase or have no effect on \(x_j\). This implies that \(t^*\) may have negative entries.

References

  • Ambec, Stefan, & Coria, Jessica. (2018). Policy spillovers in the regulation of multiple pollutants. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 87, 114–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, Gary S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. The Economic Journal, 75(299), 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennear, Lori Snyder, & Stavins, Robert N. (2007). Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy instruments. Environmental and Resource Economics, 37(1), 111–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg, A Lans, & van der Ploeg, Frederick. (1994). Environmental policy, public finance and the labour market in a second-best world. Journal of Public Economics, 55(3), 349–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg, A Lans, & Goulder, Lawrence H. (1996). Optimal environmental taxation in the presence of other taxes: General-equilibrium analyses. The American Economic Review, 86(2), 985–1000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg, A Lans, and Ruud A De Mooij. 1994. “Environmental levies and distortionary taxation.” The American Economic Review, 1085–1089.

  • Buchanan, James M. (1969). External diseconomies, corrective taxes, and market structure. The American Economic Review, 59(1), 174–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burtraw, Dallas, Krupnick, Alan, Palmer, Karen, Paul, Anthony, Toman, Michael, & Bloyd, Cary. (2003). Ancillary benefits of reduced air pollution in the US from moderate greenhouse gas mitigation policies in the electricity sector. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45(3), 650–673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, Helmuth, & Gahvari, Firouz. (1993). Tax evasion and optimal commodity taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 50(2), 261–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, Helmuth, & Gahvari, Firouz. (2001). Second-best taxation of emissions and polluting goods. Journal of Public Economics, 80(2), 169–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, Helmuth, Gahvari, Firouz, & Ladoux, Norbert. (1998). Externalities and optimal taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 70(3), 343–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, Don. (1997). Environmental levies and distortionary taxation: Comment. American Economic Review, 87(1), 245–251.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, Don, & Wolverton, Ann. (2005). The two-part instrument in a second-best world. Journal of Public Economics, 89(9), 1961–1975.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, Don, & Karney, Daniel H. (2018). Multiple pollutants, co-benefits, and suboptimal environmental policies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 87, 52–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, Don, and Robert D Mohr. 2003. “Suggested subsidies are sub-optimal unless combined with an output tax.” Contributions in Economic Analysis and Policy, 2(1).

  • Fullerton, Don, & West, Sarah E. (2002). Can taxes on cars and on gasoline mimic an unavailable tax on emissions? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(1), 135–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, Don, & Kinnaman, Thomas C. (1995). Garbage, recycling, and illicit burning or dumping. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29(1), 78–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gahvari, Firouz. (2014). Second-best pigouvian taxation: A clarification. Environmental and Resource Economics, 59(4), 525–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, Lawrence H. (1998). Environmental policy making in a second-best setting. Journal of Applied Economics, 1(2), 279–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, Lawrence H., Parry, Ian WH.., Williams, I. I. I., Roberton, C., & Burtraw, Dallas. (1999). The cost-effectiveness of alternative instruments for environmental protection in a second-best setting. Journal of Public Economics, 72(3), 329–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, Jerry, & Sheshinski, Eytan. (1976). Direct versus indirect remedies for externalities. Journal of Political Economy, 84(4), 797–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groosman, Britt, Muller, Nicholas Z., & O’Neill-Toy, Erin. (2011). The ancillary benefits from climate policy in the United States. Environmental and Resource Economics, 50(4), 585–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harberger, Arnold C. (1964). The measurement of waste. American Economic Review, 54(3), 58–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hines, James R., Jr., & Thaler, Richard H. (1995). Anomalies: The flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, Bas, & de Mooij, RuudA. (2015). Pigou meets Mirrlees: On the irrelevance of tax distortions for the second-best Pigouvian tax. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 71, 90–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, Mark R., Knittel, Christopher R., Sallee, James M., & van Benthem, Arthur A. (2020). The use of regression statistics to analyze imperfect pricing policies. Journal of Political Economy, 128(5), 1826–1876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, Louis. (1990). Optimal taxation with costly enforcement and evasion. Journal of Public Economics, 43(2), 221–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, Louis. (2012). Optimal control of externalities in the presence of income taxation. International Economic Review, 53(2), 487–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopczuk, Wojciech. (2003). A Note on optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Economics Letters, 80, 81–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, Kelvin. (1956). The general theory of the second best. Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), 11–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayshar, Joram. (1991). Taxation with costly administration. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 93(1), 75–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry, Ian WH.. (1997). Environmental taxes and quotas in the presence of distorting taxes in factor markets. Resource and Energy Economics, 19(3), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry, Ian WH.. (1998). A second-best analysis of environmental subsidies. International Tax and Public Finance, 5(2), 153–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, Arthur C. 1920. “The economics of welfare.”

  • Pirttilä, Jukka. (2000). A many-person Corlett-Hague tax rule with externalities. Oxford Economic Papers, 52(3), 595–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pirttilä, Jukka, & Tuomala, Matti. (1997). Income tax, commodity tax and environmental policy. International Tax and Public Finance, 4(3), 379–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, Charles R. (1966). Externalities and corrective taxes. Economica, 33(129), 84–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, Mitchell, & Shavell, Steven. (1982). Pigouvian taxation with administrative costs. Journal of Public Economics, 19(3), 385–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, Frank P. (1927). A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 37(145), 47–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo, Agnar. (1976). Direct versus indirect Pigovian taxation. European Economic Review, 7(4), 337–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, Joel. (1990). Optimal taxation and optimal tax systems. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(1), 157–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, Joel, & Yitzhaki, Shlomo. (2002). Tax avoidance, evasion, and administration. Handbook of Public Economics, 3, 1423–1470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, Michael. 2020. “Energy subsidies evolution in the global energy transformation to 2050.” International Renewable Energy Agency Staff Technical Paper.

  • Wijkander, Hans. (1985). Correcting externalities through taxes on/subsidies to related goods. Journal of Public Economics, 28(1), 111–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki, Shlomo. (1979). A note on optimal taxation and administrative costs. American Economic Review, 69(3), 475–480.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

We give special thanks to Jim Hines for his advice and support. We thank Steve Bond, Paul Courant, Adam Dearing, Marina Epelman, Morris Hamilton, Louis Kaplow, Tuomas Kosonen, Sara LaLumia, Natalia Lazzati, Ben B. Lockwood, JJ Prescott, Daniel Reck, Nate Seegert, Dan Silverman, Joel Slemrod, Kevin Spiritus, Ugo Troiano, Mike Zabek, and our anonymous referees for helpful suggestions. We also thank the members of the University of Michigan Public Finance community (in particular our seminar attendees), the faculty of the Centre for Business Taxation at Oxford University, and attendees of the 2016 and 2017 NTA Conferences on Taxation, the 2016 IIPF Annual Meeting, the 2017 Mid-Atlantic Junior Faculty Forum, and the 2017 ALEA Annual Meeting for invaluable comments and feedback. Schaffa gratefully acknowledges support from the NIA training grant to the Population Studies Center at the University of Michigan (T32 AG000221). Earlier drafts of this paper were titled “Pigouvian Taxation with Costly Administration and Multiple Externalities” and “The Case for Subsidizing Harm: Second-best Pigouvian Taxation with Multiple Externalities.” Any errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel Schaffa.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A Net benefit and utility maximization

Let \(u(x,x_{n+1}):\mathbb {R}^{n+1} \rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) be a strictly increasing, strictly concave representative agent’s utility function over \(n+1\) activities. Let \(p(x,x_{n+1}):\mathbb {R}^{n+1} \rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) be a strictly increasing, weakly convex function, such that \(p(x,x_{n+1}) = 0\) defines a production possibility frontier. Then

  1. (i)

    There exists a function \(f(x):\mathbb {R}^{n} \rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) such that \(p(x,x_{n+1})=0\) if and only if \(x_{n+1} = f(x)\);

  2. (ii)

    \(u(x,f(x)) = b(x)\) defines a strictly concave net benefit function; and

  3. (iii)

    Assuming activity \(n+1\) generates no external harm and is untaxed, the agent’s best response to a vector of activity taxes is the same under either the constrained utility maximization problem or the unconstrained net benefit maximization problem.

Proof

  1. (i)

    Under the implicit mapping theorem, there exists a function f such that \(p(x,x_{n+1})=0\) if and only if \(x_{n+1} = f(x)\) and \(f_i = -p_i/p_{n+1}\).

  2. (ii)

    First, the weak convexity of p implies the weak concavity of f.

    $$\begin{aligned} p(y,y_{n+1}) - p(x,x_{n+1})&\ge \sum _{i=1}^{n+1} p_i(x,x_{n+1})(y_i - x_i) \end{aligned}$$
    (73)

    Thus, \(\forall (x,x_{n+1}),(y,y_{n+1})\) such that \(p(x,x_{n+1}) = p(y,y_{n+1}) = 0\), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} 0&\ge \sum _{i=1}^{n+1} p_i(x,x_{n+1})(y_i - x_i) \implies \end{aligned}$$
    (74)
    $$\begin{aligned} -p_{n+1}(x,x_{n+1})(y_{n+1} - x_{n+1})&\ge \sum _{i=1}^{n} p_i(x,x_{n+1})(y_i - x_i) \implies \end{aligned}$$
    (75)
    $$\begin{aligned} (y_{n+1} - x_{n+1})&\le \sum _{i=1}^{n} (-p_i(x,x_{n+1}))/(p_{n+1}(x,x_{n+1}))(y_i - x_i) \implies \end{aligned}$$
    (76)
    $$\begin{aligned} f(y) - f(x)&\le \sum _{i=1}^{n} f_i(x) (y_i - x_i) \end{aligned}$$
    (77)

    Second, the weak concavity of f and strict concavity of u imply the strict concavity of b.

    $$\begin{aligned} \forall \theta \in [0,1] : b \left( \theta x + [1-\theta ] y \right)&= u(\theta x + [1-\theta ] y,f(\theta x + [1-\theta ] y)) \end{aligned}$$
    (78)
    $$\begin{aligned}&\ge u(\theta x + [1-\theta ] y,\theta f(x) + [1-\theta ] f(y)) \end{aligned}$$
    (79)
    $$\begin{aligned}&= u(\theta x + [1-\theta ] y,\theta x_{n+1} + [1-\theta ] y_{n+1}) \end{aligned}$$
    (80)
    $$\begin{aligned}&> \theta u(x, x_{n+1}) + [1-\theta ] u(y, y_{n+1}) \end{aligned}$$
    (81)
    $$\begin{aligned}&= \theta b(x) + [1-\theta ] b(y) \end{aligned}$$
    (82)
  3. (iii)

    With a vector of taxes t, the agent’s utility maximization problem is a Lagrangian with Lagrange multiplier \(\mu\),

    $$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {L} = u(x,x_{n+1}) - t^\top x -\mu p(x,x_{n+1}) \end{aligned}$$
    (83)

    with first-order conditions

    $$\begin{aligned} u_i -t_i - \mu p_i = 0\text { for all }i \in \{1, \hdots , n\}\hbox { and } u_{n+1} - \mu p_{n+1} = 0 \end{aligned}$$
    (84)

    which may be combined to yield

    $$\begin{aligned} u_i -t_i - u_{n+1} \frac{p_i}{p_{n+1}} = 0 \end{aligned}$$
    (85)

    With a vector of taxes t, the agent’s net benefit maximization problem is \(\max _x u(x,f(x)) - t^\top x\) with first-order conditions

    $$\begin{aligned} u_i +u_{n+1}f_i -t_i = 0\hbox { for all}\ i \in \{1, \hdots , n\} \end{aligned}$$
    (86)

    From (i), \(f_i = -p_i/p_{n+1}\). Thus,

    $$\begin{aligned} u_i -t_i - u_{n+1} \frac{p_i}{p_{n+1}} = 0 \end{aligned}$$
    (87)

    Since the two problems have the same first-order conditions, they imply the same agent best response function. \(\square\)

1.2 B Private net benefit and output

A rigorous investigation of the optimal output tax requires a formal relationship between private net benefit and output. We assume that private net benefit is the benefit of output less the cost of activities. Thus, when output is explicitly incorporated into the model, we require two additional functions. Strictly increasing, strictly concave v maps output to private benefit. Strictly increasing, strictly convex g maps the activities to private cost. Thus, \(b(x) = v(q(x)) - g(x)\) and the private market’s problem is

$$\begin{aligned} \max _x v(q(x)) - g(x) -\tau q(x) \end{aligned}$$
(88)

with first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} v'(q(x(\tau ))q'(x(\tau )) - g'(x(\tau )) -\tau q'(x(\tau )) = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(89)

Under the implicit mapping theorem, \(x(\tau )\) exists and is continuously differentiable everywhere that the derivative of first-order condition with respect to x has a nonzero determinant. The derivative of first-order condition with respect to x is

$$\begin{aligned}&v'(q(x))q''(x) + (q'(x))^\top v''(q(x)) q'(x) - g''(x) - \tau q''(x) \end{aligned}$$
(90)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad =[v'(q(x))-\tau ]q''(x) + v''(q(x)) (q'(x))^\top q'(x) - g''(x) \end{aligned}$$
(91)

\(v'(q(x))-\tau > 0\) under the first-order condition. \(q''(x)\) is negative semidefinite by assumption. \(v''(q(x)) < 0\) by assumption. \((q'(x))^\top q'(x)\) is positive semidefinite because for any vector v, \((v^\top q'(x)^\top )(q'(x)v) \ge 0\). And \(g''(x)\) is positive definite by assumption. Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} =&\underbrace{[v'(q(x))-\tau ]}_+ \underbrace{q''(x)}_\text {NSD} + \underbrace{v''(q(x))}_{-} \underbrace{(q'(x))^\top q'(x)}_\text {PSD} - \underbrace{g''(x)}_\text {PD} \end{aligned}$$
(92)

Because a positive (semi)definite matrix multiplied by a negative scalar is a negative (semi)definite matrix and since the sum of a negative definite matrix and a negative semidefinite matrix is a negative definite matrix, the sum here is negative definite. Since a negative definite matrix has a nonzero determinant, \(x(\tau )\) exists and is continuously differentiable. We have shown that \(b''(x) - \tau q''(x)\) is negative definite. Thus, its inverse, A, is also negative definite.

The additional structure that v and g provide to the problem makes it clearer under what circumstances the level of an activity increases with the output tax. In our solar and coal power example, we have

$$\begin{aligned} x'(\tau ) =&\text {A}q'(x(\tau ))^\top \end{aligned}$$
(93)
$$\begin{aligned} =&\frac{1}{\det (\text {A}^{-1})}\left( \begin{array}{cc} (v'-\tau ) q_{cc} + v''q_cq_c - g_{cc} &{} -(v'-\tau ) q_{sc} - v''q_sq_c + g_{sc} \\ -(v'-\tau ) q_{cs} - v''q_cq_s + g_{cs} &{} (v'-\tau ) q_{ss} + v''q_sq_s - g_{ss} \end{array} \right) \left( \begin{array}{c} q_s \\ q_c \end{array} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(94)
$$\begin{aligned} =&\frac{1}{\det (\text {A}^{-1})}\left( \begin{array}{c} q_s(v'-\tau ) q_{cc} + q_sv''q_cq_c - q_sg_{cc} -q_c(v'-\tau ) q_{sc} - q_cv''q_sq_c + q_cg_{sc} \\ -q_s(v'-\tau ) q_{cs} - q_sv''q_cq_s + q_sg_{cs} +q_c(v'-\tau ) q_{ss} + q_cv''q_sq_s - q_cg_{ss} \end{array} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(95)
$$\begin{aligned} \tfrac{\partial {x_c}}{\partial {\tau }} =&\frac{1}{\det (\text {A}^{-1})}\left( -q_s(v'-\tau ) q_{cs} + q_sg_{cs} +q_c(v'-\tau ) q_{ss} - q_cg_{ss} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(96)

Since \(\frac{1}{\det (\text {A}^{-1})}>0\), \(\tfrac{\partial {x_c}}{\partial {\tau }}>0\) requires

$$\begin{aligned} \underbrace{-q_s(v'-\tau ) }_\text {negative}q_{cs} + \underbrace{q_s}_\text {positive}g_{cs} + \underbrace{q_c(v'-\tau ) q_{ss}}_\text {negative} +\underbrace{ - q_cg_{ss}}_\text {negative} > 0 \end{aligned}$$

We know that \((v'-\tau )>0\), \(q_i >0\), \(q_{ss}<0\), and \(g_{ss}>0\). Thus, for \(\tfrac{\partial {x_c}}{\partial {\tau }}>0\) we require either \(q_{sc}<0\) or \(g_{sc}>0\). Having \(q_s\) be large, \(q_c\) be small, \(q_{ss}\) be small, and \(g_{ss}\) be small will also help push \(\tfrac{\partial {x_c}}{\partial {\tau }}\) above zero.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jaqua, D., Schaffa, D. The case for subsidizing harm: constrained and costly Pigouvian taxation with multiple externalities. Int Tax Public Finance 29, 408–442 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-021-09670-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-021-09670-5

Keywords

JEL Codes:

Navigation