Elsevier

Journal of Macroeconomics

Volume 69, September 2021, 103333
Journal of Macroeconomics

Bank lending and interest on excess reserves: An empirical investigation

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2021.103333Get rights and content

Highlights

  • After 2008, US banks decreased lending and increased holdings of excess reserves.

  • Banks hold excess reserves if the rate on reserves is above other short-term rates.

  • Panel data show a switch to a high excess reserve regime after the financial crisis.

  • Interest on reserves accounts for the majority of decline in lending after 2008.

Abstract

This paper econometrically tests for effects on bank lending of the Federal Reserve’s policy of paying interest on excess reserves (IOER). Following the 2008 financial crisis, US banks decreased their loan allocations and increased holdings of excess reserves. A model of bank asset allocation shows that when the rate of IOER is higher than other short-term rates, banks will switch from zero excess reserves to a regime with higher excess reserves and lower lending. Using a sample of panel data on US banks from 2000 through 2018, we find evidence of a switch to a positive excess reserve regime in the post-crisis period. Controlling for market interest rates, loan demand, and economic activity, we find that IOER accounts for the majority of the decline in bank lending after the financial crisis.

Introduction

During the financial crisis of 2008, the Federal Reserve initiated a variety of new and unprecedented policies. One such change transformed the Fed’s monetary policy framework by allowing it to pay interest on the excess reserves (IOER) that banks hold at the Fed. Though garnering fewer headlines than its quantitative easing (QE) program and its ad hoc last-resort lending facilities,1 the Fed’s IOER policy and its effect on bank reserves is “one of the most notable and important policy issues in U.S. banking” (Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2017, p.1). There is, however, little research on the empirical effects of IOER policy and in particular “little analysis of how reserves affect bank lending when interest is paid on reserves” (Martin et al., 2016, pp. 216–217).

Building on a model of bank asset allocation from Dutkowsky and VanHoose (hereafter “DV” Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2017, Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2018a, Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2018b, Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2020), we find that low rates of IOER increase lending but that banks reduce their loan allocations when the rate of IOER is greater than rates on other short-term assets. A Fed balance sheet expansion that increases total reserves will increase lending if the rate of IOER is below short-term interest rates, as in a corridor system of monetary policy. When the rate of IOER is above other short-term interest rates, as it was following the financial crisis, an increase in total reserves leads to a decrease banks’ loan allocations since excess reserves become a profitable alternative to loans.

This study provides an empirical investigation of the effects of IOER on bank lending. In Q4 of 2008, the Fed began paying a rate of IOER that was higher than other short-term rates, which our model indicates may have caused banks to increase their excess reserve holding and decrease their loan allocations. Using regression analysis, we test for the effects of IOER on bank loan allocations in a sample of panel data on US banks from Q1 of 2000 through Q4 of 2018. We find evidence of a change to a regime of positive excess reserves following the 2008 financial crisis. In the post-crisis regime, IOER has large negative effects on bank lending. Controlling for economic factors such as GDP growth, unemployment, uncertainty, and loan demand, we find that the rate of IOER relative to other short-term interest rates accounts for the majority of the post-crisis decline in lending as a percentage of bank assets.

Section snippets

Background

The Fed was granted the power to pay IOER by the Financial Services Regulatory Relief Act of 2006. The effective date was originally set as October 1, 2011, but due to the turmoil of the financial crisis, the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 allowed IOER to be implemented early, effective as of October 1, 2008. The rate was set at 0.25% from December 2008 to December of 2016, when it was raised to 0.5% and eventually to 2.4% by December of 2018.2

Theory

We consider the effects of IOER policy on bank lending using a model building on DV (Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2017, Dutkowsky and VanHoose, 2018b). First, we lay out the model and solve for the bank’s loan supply function when banks hold either zero or positive excess reserves. Next, we solve for the conditions under which a change in equilibria might occur. We then convert the loan supply function into reduced form equations and modify the forms of these equations for use in our empirical

Data

We conduct our empirical analysis using a sample of panel data on FDIC-insured banks from Q1 of 2000 through Q4 of 2018. Quarterly data are gathered from the Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income (Call Reports) of US commercial banks.10 Data are provided at the individual bank level, but many of these banks are owned by bank holding companies (BHCs). As is common in the literature, data for individual banks are summed

Analysis

Does the rate of IOER affect the allocation of bank loans? Studies such as Ennis and Wolman (2015) and Bernanke and Kohn (2016) acknowledge that IOER could influence lending, but they tentatively find that the marginal rate of IOER is too small to have important effects. We provide empirical tests for a regime change in banks’ excess reserve holdings and estimate the relationships between bank loans, the rate of IOER, and other interest rates.

Conclusion

This study contributes to the important debate over the Fed’s new operating framework. Using a model of bank asset allocation, we show that high rates of IOER can cause banks to switch from holding zero excess reserves to a regime of positive excess reserves, which may have negative effects on bank lending. Such a switch is likely to occur when the rate of IOER is higher than the fed funds rate and other short-term interest rates, as it was following the 2008 financial crisis.

Based on this

Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Acknowledgments

For helpful comments and suggestions, the author thanks John Cochrane, Judge Glock, Kevin Grier, William Luther, David Schatz, George Selgin, David VanHoose, Andrew Young, and seminar participants at Texas Tech University, Troy University, the American Institute for Economic Research, the Association for Private Enterprise Education, and the Southern Economic Association.

References (47)

  • BanegasAyelen et al.
  • BarajasAdolfo et al.

    U.S. Bank Behavior in the Wake of the 2007-2009 Financial CrisisIMF Working Paper WP/10/131

    (2010)
  • BeckworthDavid

    The Great Divorce: The Federal Reserve’s Move to a Floor System and the Implications for Bank Portfolios

    (2018)
  • BernankeBen S. et al.

    The Fed’s Interest Payments to Banks

    (2016)
  • BerrospideJose
  • BianchiJavier et al.

    Banks, Liquidity Management and Monetary PolicyNBER Working Paper No. 20490

    (2017)
  • BridgesJonathan et al.

    The Impact of Capital Requirements on Bank LendingBank of England Working Paper No. 486

    (2014)
  • CarlstromCharles T. et al.

    Monetary Policy in a World with Interest on ReservesFederal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary 2010-4

    (2010)
  • DeYoungRobert et al.

    The past, present, and probable future for community banks

    J. Financ. Serv. Res.

    (2004)
  • DutkowskyDonald H. et al.

    Equal treatment under the fed: Interest on reserves, the federal funds rate, and the ‘Third Regime’ of bank behavior

    J. Econ. Bus.

    (2020)
  • ElyasianiElyas et al.

    Costs of adjustment, portfolio separation, and the dynamic behavior of bank loans and deposits

    J. Money Credit Bank.

    (1995)
  • EnnisHuberto M. et al.

    Understanding monetary policy implementation

    Fed. Reserve Bank Richmond Econ. Q.

    (2008)
  • EnnisHuberto M. et al.

    Interest on reserves and daylight credit

    Fed. Reserve Bank Richmond Econ. Q.

    (2007)
  • Cited by (6)

    View full text