Skip to main content
Log in

Heaven can wait: future tense and religiosity

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper identifies a new source of differences in religiosity: the type of future tense marking in language. We argue that the rewards and punishments that incentivise religious behaviour are more effective for speakers of languages without inflectional future tense. Consistent with this prediction, we show that speakers of languages without inflectional future tense are more likely to be religious and to take up the short-term costs associated with religiosity. What is likely to drive this behaviour, according to our results, is the relatively greater appeal of the religious rewards to these individuals. Our analysis is based on within-country regressions comparing individuals with identical observable characteristics who speak a different language.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Section 2 for a more detailed explanation of the two different future tense systems.

  2. For instance, the following famous passage from the Second Epistle to Timothy is in inflectional future tense in the French bible (1.), whereas the Finnish bible lacks inflectional future tense (2.).

    “And the Lord will rescue me from every evil attack and will bring me safely to his heavenly kingdom.” (2 Timothy 4:18)

    • 1. Le Seigneur med èlivrerade toute oeuvre mauvaise, et il mesauverapour me faire entrer dansson royaume cèlest.

    • And the Lord me deliverfuture of all works evil, and he me savefuture to me make enter into his kingdom heavenly.

    • 2. Ja Herraon vapahtavaminut kaikesta ilkivallasta japelastavaminut taivaalliseen valtakun-taansa.

    • And the Lord is freeingpresent me from all wickedness, and savespresent me in his heavenly kingdom.

  3. Our classification of languages is in line with that of Galor et al. (2016, 2020). However, unlike Galor et al. we stick to the original terminology of Dahl and Velupillai (2013) and speak of languages with “no inflectional future tense”, rather than languages with “periphrastic future tense”. The reason is that the term “periphrastic future tense” commonly refers to languages, such as English, which mark the future with an auxiliary (e.g. will), and not to languages that do not require any future tense marking at all, such as Finnish.

  4. Typically, time discounting is represented by a discounting function involving a discounting factor δ determined by an agent’s discount rate r. Smaller discount rates result in a discounting factor closer to 1.

  5. For example, Italy drops out of the sample since the only language spoken at home reported within the WVS sample is Italian (alongside “other” language which cannot be identified). On the other hand, Germany remains in the sample due to the presence of individuals speaking a language other than German (e.g. Turkish, Russian).

  6. Splitting this group into two—those with other and those with no denomination—has no implication for the results.

  7. The countries in this sub-sample include the following: Albania, Andorra, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Estonia, Georgia, Ghana, Guatemala, Hungary, Jordan, Latvia, Lebanon, Lithuania, Macedonia, Moldova, Palestine, Puerto Rico, Rwanda, Serbia, Singapore, Slovakia, Slovenia, Switzerland, Trinidad and Tobago, Uganda, and Uruguay.

  8. Some analyses on the link between language structures and outcomes have instead explicitly focused on a sample of immigrants (e.g. Gay et al. 2017; Galor et al. 2020), adopting “epidemiological approach” by comparing migrants descending from different countries within the same country of residence, in the hope that it might help to isolate the causal effect of speaking a language (although as a recent study by Beblo et al. (2020) suggests, studying immigrants may not overcome the concerns over causality since individuals who select into migration are more likely to reject the norms of their country of origin and may transmit their traits to their children). These studies, however, have used large single country datasets such as the US Census and American Community Survey, where detailed information on the background of individuals and their families is available. This exercise faces significant constraints within WVS where information on immigrant background is limited, and not available (and consistently defined) across all waves. We made an attempt at imitating a version of epidemiological approach on our dataset based on wave 3 (1994–1998) of WVS where information on the places of birth of the respondents, defined by broad continents, is available. The estimated marginal effect of No inflectional FT on Religious in a regression which includes dummies for continent of origin of immigrants in addition to baseline controls and host country dummies in a sample of immigrants (N= 2405) is statistically indistinguishable from 0. The results are available on request.

  9. Also, in unreported results, we include the size of one’s own language share in the population and its interaction with No inflectional FT as additional regressors in the baseline specification of our model. These are not statistically significantly related to the probability of being religious. Hence, the positive statistically significant association between No inflectional FT in one’s language and Religious does not appear to vary by the share of the population speaking the language.

  10. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this example.

  11. SUR system is system of equations with no endogenous right-hand-side variables that allows for contemporaneous cross-equation error correlation. It is different from three-stage least squares which represents a system of equations with endogenous regressors and requires instrumental variables for identification.

References

  • Alesina A, Devleeschauwer A, Easterly W, Kurlat S, Wacziarg R (2003) Fractionalization. J Econ Growth 8:155–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Athanasopoulos P (2007) Effects of the grammatical representation of number on cognition in bilinguals. Bilingualism Lang Cogn 9:89–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Athanasopoulos P (2009) Cognitive representation of color in bilinguals. Bilingualism Lang Cogn 12:83–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Athanasopoulos P, Aveledo F (2012) Linguistic relativity and bilingualism. In: Altarriba J, Isuri L (eds) Memory, Language, and Bilingualism: Theoretical and Applied Approaches, Chapter 9. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 236–255

  • Ayres I, Kricheli-Katz T, Regev T (2020) Do languages generate future-oriented economic behavior? experimental evidence for causal effects. unpublished

  • Beblo M, Görges L, Markowsky E (2020) Gender matters in language and economic behaviour. Labour Econ 101850

  • Campo F, Nunziata L, Rocco L (2020) Talking business: new evidence on how language shapes economic behaviour. IZA Discussion Paper 13897

  • Casasanto D (2015) Linguistic relativity. In: Riemer N (ed) Routledge handbook of semantics. Routledge, New York, pp 158–174

  • Chen MK (2013) The effect of language on economic behavior: evidence from savings rates, health behaviors, and retirement assets. Amer Econ Rev 103(2):690–731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S, Cronqvist H, Ni S, Zhang F (2017) Languages and corporate savings behavior. J Corpor Financ 46:320–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chi J, Su DX, Tang Y, Xu B (2020) Is language an economic institution? Evidence from R&D investment. Journal of Corporate Finance. (forthcoming)

  • Comrie B, Dryer MS, Gil D, Haspelmath M (2013) Introduction. In: Dryer MS, Haspelmath M (eds) The world atlas of language structures online. Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology, Leipzig

  • Dahl Ö, Velupillai V (2013) The future tense. In: Dryer MS, Haspelmath M (eds) The World Atlas of Language Structures Online. Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology, Leipzig

  • Davis LS, Abdurazokzoda F (2016a) Language, culture and institutions: Evidence from a new linguistic dataset. J Compar Econ 44(3):541–561

  • Davis LS, Williamson CR (2016b) Culture and the regulation of entry. J Compar Econ 44(4), 1055–1083

  • Davis L, Reynolds M (2018) Gendered language and the educational gender gap. Econ Lett 168:46–48

  • Dryer MS, Haspelmath M (eds) (2013) WALS Online. Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology, Leipzig

  • Frederick S, Loewenstein G, O’donoghue T (2002) Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J Econ Lit 40(2):351–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Özak Ö, Sarid A (2016) Geographical origins and economic consequences of language structures. Working paper

  • Galor O, Özak Ö, Sarid A (2020) Linguistic traits and human capital formation. AEA Papers and Proceedings

  • Gay V, Hicks DL, Santacreu-Vasut E, Shoham A (2017) Decomposing culture: an analysis of gender, language, and labor supply in the household. Review of Economics of the Household

  • Ginsburgh V, Weber S (2020) The economics of language. J Econ Lit 58(2):348–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godlewski CJ, Weill L (2019) Are loans cheaper when tomorrow seems further? Working paper; available at SSRN 3347225

  • Guin B (2015) Culture and household saving. Working paper; available at SSRN 2698872

  • Hicks DL, Hicks JH, Maldonado B (2016) Women as policy makers and donors: Female legislators and foreign aid. Eur J Polit Econ 41:46–60

  • Hicks DL, Santacreu-Vasut E, Shoham A (2015) Does mother tongue make for women’s work? Linguistics, household labor, and gender identity. J Econ Behav Organ 110:19–44

  • Jeny A, Santacreu-Vasut E (2017) New avenues of research to explain the rarity of females at the top of the accountancy profession. Palgrave Commun 3(17011)

  • Kashima ES, Kashima Y (1998) Culture and language: The case of cultural dimensions and personal pronoun use. J Cross-Cult Psychol 29(3):461–486

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kousta S-T, Vinson DP, Vigliocco G (2008) Investigating linguistic relativity through bilingualism: the case of grammatical gender. J Exper Psychol Learn Memory Cogn 34(4):843–858

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurinski E, Sera MD (2011) Does learning spanish grammatical gender change english–speaking adults’ categorization of inanimate objects? Bilingualism: Lang Cogn 14:203–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP (1999) Culture and language. J Polit Econ 107 (S6):S95–S126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Licht AN, Goldschmidt C, Schwartz SH (2007) Culture rules: the foundations of the rule of law and other norms of governance. J Compar Econ 35(4):659–688

  • Lucy JA (1997) Linguistic relativity. Annu Rev Anthropol 26:291–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavisakalyan A (2015) Gender in language and gender in employment. Oxf Dev Stud 43(4):403–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavisakalyan A, Weber C (2017) Linguistic structures and economic outcomes. J Econ Surv 32(3):916–939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavisakalyan A, Tarverdi Y, Weber C (2018) Talking in the present, caring for the future: Language and environment. J Compara Econ 46(4):1370–1387

  • Nunziata L, Rocco L (2016) A tale of minorities: evidence on religious ethics and entrepreneurship. J Econ Growth 21(2):189–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunziata L, Rocco L (2018) The protestant ethic and entrepreneurship: evidence from religious minorities in the former holy roman empire. Eur J Polit Econ 51:27–43

  • Pascal B (1995) Pensées and Other Writings. Oxford University Press

  • Roberts SG, Winters J, Chen K (2015) Future tense and economic decisions: controlling for cultural evolution. PLoS One 10(7):1–46

  • Santacreu-Vasut E, Shenkar O, Shoham A (2014) Linguistic gender marking and its IB ramifications. J Int Bus Stud 45(9):1170–1178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter M, Angerer S, Glätzle-Rützler D, Lergetporer P (2018) Language group differences in time preferences: Evidence from primary school children in a bilingual city. Eur Econ Rev 106:21–34

  • Tabellini G (2008) Presidential address institutions and culture. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(2-3):255–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Velde L, Tyrowicz J, Siwinska J (2015) Language and (the estimates of) the gender wage gap. Econ Lett 136:165–170

  • Wang M, Rieger MO, Hens T (2016) How time preferences differ: evidence from 53 countries. J Econ Psychol 52:115–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winawer J, Witthoft N, Frank MC, Wu L, Wade AR, Boroditsky L (2007) Russian blues reveal effects of language on color discrimination. Proc Natl Acad Sci 114(19):7780–7785

  • YouGov (2015) Death, Fieldwork: 16th - 17th August 2015. https://d25d2506sfb94s.cloudfront.net/cumulus_uploads/document/zcui1w66ie/Copy

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the editor, Klaus F. Zimmermann, and two anonymous referees for their excellent comments on this paper. We also thank the participants of the economics internal seminar at the University of Western Australia for their feedback.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Astghik Mavisakalyan.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the positions of their institutions.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Klaus F. Zimmermann

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 9 Regressions with alternative dependent variables: religious denomination - probit marginal effects

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mavisakalyan, A., Tarverdi, Y. & Weber, C. Heaven can wait: future tense and religiosity. J Popul Econ 35, 833–860 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-021-00850-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-021-00850-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation