Skip to main content
Log in

Portfolio selection with active strategies: how long only constraints shape convictions

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Asset Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the recent years, an intense effort has been dedicated to the research on equity factors. If the academic literature questions their rewarding nature, the financial industry competes for the best portfolio implementation, either in long-short or in long only vehicles. While both solutions try to exploit the same factors while controlling risk, two kinds of managers co-exist in the meantime: fundamental, discretionary stock-pickers, and quantitative, systematic managers. The contribution of this paper is twofold. The core message is that a quantitative long only portfolio, built with any factor as a future returns’ proxy and a risk control, ends up to be high conviction portfolios: the long only constraint polarizes naturally the portfolio on a concentrated set of nonzero positions. In this respect, actively managed, quantitative long only portfolios share some similarity with discretionary stock pickers. Beyond this message, and backed by numerical experiments, we derive theoretical results and closed-form formulas to show in addition that: (i) selected stocks are those that realize a trade-off between a low \(\beta\) and a high loading on the factor; (ii) the thresholds driving this selection are endogenous, leading to a recursive procedure to select the stocks. In other words: the portfolio selection problem may be solved linearly instead of using an optimizer. We highlight in particular the crucial role played by low \(\beta\) stocks and by the co-linearity of the risk model with the factor used to forecast returns.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Defining conviction is not an easy task and the literature is rather scarce on this theme. See, however, (Crezée and Swinkels 2010).

  2. See (Gander et al. 2012; Lo 2016) for a complete discussion on the fine distinction between indexing, passive and active investment.

  3. They are in general more difficult to shape, manage, risk-weight, and bare the implicit expectation that the performance of the portfolio is greater than the performance of the considered benchmark.

  4. In the same vein, an interested reader could refer to Sebastian and Attaluri (2014) or Siegel and Scanlan (2014).

  5. Situations where active performance is computed ex-post but does not appear in the optimization program are tackled in Browne (2000) for instance.

  6. This experiment has been built upon a random pick of equi-weighted portfolios.

  7. Such a procedure is the canonical approach used by quantitative asset managers to run backtests.

  8. Following in the past, a fixed set of stocks made of the composition of the SP500 now, would be such an example.

  9. We clearly set ourselves in the context of a “sample-based” approach in the words of Gillen (2016), which is, however, the procedure that quantitative boutiques use most of the time for real-time portfolio allocation. The two papers use a bootstrap-like approach to assess the interest of such allocated portfolios and confirm their superior out-of-sample robustness. We nonetheless do notice in Sect. 4.3.1 that estimation noise will be such that the more noisy the estimation is, the fewer the number of stocks in the final portfolio.

  10. Local discrepancies between the two risk can be tolerated and no ex-post risk rescaling is applied.

  11. Sect. 4.3.3 goes deeper in the construction of such implied portfolios, and more generally detail how long only portfolio construction transforms them.

  12. Let’s note, however, that we do not see sparsification of the portfolio is an objective per se. Consequently, we do not have any regression objective making that, a technique like lasso, could be useful in our case. However, the \(L^1\) constraint in the lasso optimization program is very equivalent to the expression of the fully invested constraint plus the positive positions constraint of the long only set up. They may share in consequence the same effects.

  13. Those comments are not the core results per se of the paper but are a necessary sanity check before assessing that our empirical results do align with our theoretical results.

  14. Two solutions may be proposed to get homogeneous figures: rescale the ex-post returns to get equivalent figures; or modify and improve the risk model to get ex-post a better risk estimation. Improved risk model is another topic (see (Bun et al. 2016) and references herein for different proposals). In this paper we consider the risk model as exogenously given, hence the variations between the targeted risk and the realized one are out of the scope of this paper.

  15. A proof would be to derive Eq. (4) from a list of K long only constraints, one for each asset.

  16. Let’s note that \(\omega _{{1\mu ^{\pi } }} = 1^{T} \Omega ^{{ - 1}} \Omega \pi = 1^{T} \pi\).

  17. In such as case \(A^2=\pi ^T\Omega \pi\), then \(a^2 = \frac{\omega _{11}A^2 - 1}{\omega _{11} \pi ^T\Omega \pi -1}=1\).

  18. As opposite to the long only Minimum Variance portfolio.

  19. Taking weekly returns allows to better take into account the auto-correlation of daily returns.

  20. Long only funds have a huge capacity, often greater than 10e9 billions USD. Generally those funds do not trade lots that are lower than 100 lots.

  21. This represents the weight of 100 lots in a 1billions USD fund.

  22. The diversification ratio is equal to the number of effective positions (see supra) squared when all stocks have the same volatility and when their returns are independent two by two.

  23. Please note that all our quantities \(\omega _{11}\), \(\omega _{\mu 1}=\omega _{1\mu }\) and \(\omega _{\mu \mu }\) are explicit and known in advance.

  24. This norm is simply defined using \(x^T\Omega ^{-1}y\) as the scalar product between vectors x and y.

References

  • Ang, A. 2014. Asset management: A systematic approach to factor investing. Financial Management Association Survey and Synthesis: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., W. Goetzmann, and S. Schaefer. 2009. Evaluation of active management of the Norwegian Government Pension Fund - Global. Report to the Norwegian Ministry of Finance: Technical report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asness, C., T. Moskowitz, and L. Pedersen. 2013. Value and momentum everywhere. Journal of Finance 68 (13): 929–985.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Best, M., and R. Grauer. 1991. On the sensitivity of mean-variance-efficient portfolios to changes in asset means : some analytical and computational results. The Review of Financial Studies 4 (2): 315–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouchaud, J.-P., Ciliberti, S., Landier, A., Simon, G., and D. Thesmar. 2016. The Excess Returns of “Quality” Stocks: A Behavioral Anomaly. https://arxiv.org/abs/1601.04478.

  • Bouchaud, J.-P., and M. Potters. 2009. Theory of financial risk and derivative pricing: From statistical physics to risk management, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browne, S. 2000. Risk-constrained dynamic active portfolio management. Management Science 46 (9): 1188–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bun, J., R. Allez, J.-P. Bouchaud, and M. Potters. 2016. Rotational invariant estimator for general noisy matrices. IEEE Transactions on Information Theory 62 (12): 7475–7490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carhart, M. 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance 52 (1): 57–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chopra, V., and W.T. Ziemba. 1993. The effect of errors in means, variances, and covariances on optimal portfolio choice. Journal of Portfolio Management 19 (2): 6–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choueifaty, Y., and Y. Coignard. 2008. Toward maximum diversification. Journal of Portfolio Management 35 (1): 40–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, R., H. De Silva, and S. Thorley. 2011. Minimum variance portfolio composition. Journal of Portfolio Management 31 (2): 31–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crezée, D., and L. Swinkels. 2010. High-conviction equity portfolio optimization. The Journal of Risk 13 (2): 57–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeMiguel, V., L. Garlappi, F. Nogales, and R. Uppal. 2009. A generalized approach to portfolio optimization: Improving performance by constraining portfolio norms. Management Science 55 (5): 798–812.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J., and S. Archer. 1968. Diversification and the reduction of dispersion: An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance 23 (5): 761–767.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E., and K. French. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33 (1): 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, L., and J.H. Lorie. 1970. Some studies of variability of returns on investments in common stocks. The Journal of Business 43 (2): 99–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gander, P., D. Leveau, and T. Pfiffner. 2012. (r)evolution of indexing methods: Why was diversification forgotten? Journal of Index Investing 3 (1): 62–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillen, B. (2016). Subset optimization for asset allocation. https://authors.library.caltech.edu/79336/1/sswp1421.pdf.

  • Goetzmann, W., S. Brown, M. Gruber, and E. Elton. 2014. Modern portfolio theory and investment analysis, 9th ed. New Jersey: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldfarb, D., and G. Iyengar. 2003. Robust portfolio selection problems. Mathematics of Operations Research 28 (1): 1–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gotz, F. 2009. A long road ahead for portfolio construction: Practitioners’ views of an EDHEC Survey. http://faculty-research.edhec.com/servlet/com.univ.collaboratif.utils.LectureFichiergw?ID_FICHIER=1328885973150.

  • Harvey, C., Liu, Y., and H. Zhu, 2016. ... and the cross-section of expected returns. Review of Financial Studies, 29 (1): 5–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huij, J. and J. Derwall, 2011. Global equity fund performance, portfolio concentration, and the fundamental law of active management. Journal of Banking and Finance, 35 (1): 155–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huij, J., Lansdorp, S., Blitz, D., and P. van Vliet, 2014. Factor investing: Long-only versus long-short. Available at SSRN: https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2417221.

  • Jagannathan, R., and T. Ma. 2003. Risk reduction in large portfolios, why imposing the wrong constraints help. Journal of Finance 58 (4): 1651–1684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2004. Honey, I shrunk the sample covariance matrix. Journal of Portfolio Management 30 (4): 110–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. 2016. What is an Index? Journal of Portfolio Management 42 (2): 21–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mier, J. 2014. Deep concentration a review of studies discussing concentrated portfolios. Lazard Asset Management: Technical report.

  • MSCI. 2014. MSCI momentum indexes methodology. MSCI: Technical report.

  • MSCI. 2017. Msci momentum methodology. MSCI Methdologies.

  • Novy-Marx, R. 2013. The other side of value: The gross profitability premium. Journal of Financial Economics 108 (1): 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roncalli, T. 2011. Understanding the impact of weights constraints in portfolio theory. www.ssrn.com/abstract_id=1761625.

  • Roncalli, T. 2013. Introduction to risk parity and budgeting. Financial Mathematics: Chapman & Hall/CRC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sankaran, J., and A. Patil. 1999. On the optimal selection of portfolios under limited diversification. Journal of Banking and Finance 23 (11): 1655–1666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savona, R., and C. Orsini. 2019. Taking the right course navigating the ERC universe. Journal of Asset Management 20: 157–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sebastian, M., and S. Attaluri. 2014. Conviction in equity investing. Journal of Portfolio Management 40 (4): 77–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, L.B., and M. Scanlan. 2014. No fear of commitment: The role of high-conviction active management. Journal of Investing 23 (3): 7–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, G. 1998. On the inverse of the covariance matrix in portfolio analysis. Journal of Finance 53 (5): 1821–1827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors want to thank an anonymous referee for her/his precise discussion and challenging questions on the paper during the review process. We also thank Lorenzo De Leo, Alexios Beveratos, Laurent Erecca and Olivier Tournaire for their comments and contributions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Guillaume Simon.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Analytics: definition of quantities

We define and describe in this section the quantities and the analytics that we use in the results throughout the paper. We adopt the empirical convention (that holds most of the time among practitioners!) where an active return is the return obtained by subtracting to the original return of the strategy, the return of the Benchmark on the same period; an excess return is the return obtained by subtracting to the original return of the strategy, the return of the Benchmark on the same period times the beta (sensitivity) of the strategy with respect to the Benchmark at the time of the return. In the following, \(R_t\) is the time series of daily returns of a strategy and \(R_t^B\) the time series of daily returns of the Benchmark.

Risk-related quantities:

  • Beta: is the sensitivity of \(R_t\) towards \(R_t^B\). It is computed as the regression coefficient of \(R_t^B\) in the OLS regression of \(R_t\) on \(R_t^B\) with no intercept. We can estimate this beta as a univariate one that we simply note \(\beta\) or as a rolling one \(\beta _t\) which is the time series of the same quantity but computed on the subsets of data \((R_{t'}, R_{t'}^B)_{t' \in [t-250;t]}\).

  • Volatility: annualized (in percents) standard deviation of weekly returnsFootnote 19 of the return time series of the strategy. The annualization is done by multiplying with a factor \(\sqrt{52}\).

  • Active Risk: volatility (see above) of \(R_t-R_t^B\).

  • Excess Risk: volatility (see above) of \(R_t-{\hat{\beta }}_t \cdot R_t^B\).

Gain-related quantities:

  • Sharpe: annualized Sharpe ratio of weekly returns of the return time series of the strategy, computed as the ratio of the average return by the standard deviation, annualized by multiplying by \(\sqrt{52}\).

  • Active Sharpe: Sharpe ratio (see above) of \(R_t-R_t^B\).

  • Excess Sharpe: Sharpe ratio (see above) of \(R_t-{\hat{\beta }}_t \cdot R_t^B\).

  • Costs: we estimate costs as the half-spread of consumed by transactions. Our cost of rebalancing is then:

    $$\begin{aligned} \sum _{k=1}^N \frac{\hbox {abs}(w_k(t)-w_k(t-1))}{w({t-1})^T \cdot \mathbf {1}} \times \frac{1}{2} \hbox {spread}_k(t). \end{aligned}$$

    We report the average value of this time series (to provide a univariate quantity) in the tables.

Portfolio-related quantities for a portfolio of positions in cash w:

  • Leverage: this quantity is simply \(w^T \cdot \mathbf {1}\).

  • Turnover: the turnover at date t is the proportion of the portfolio that changes from previous position and equals to:

    $$\begin{aligned} \sum _{k=1}^N \frac{\hbox {abs}(w_k(t)-w_k(t-1))}{w({t-1})^T \cdot \mathbf {1}} . \end{aligned}$$

    We report the median value of this time series in the tables.

  • Maximum Drawdown (MaxDD): indicator of maximum value of peak-to-valley cumulated return. Indicates the level of the maximum continuous loss. To be computed, we form the cumulated sum of the returns minus the expanding maximum of the same cumulated return serie. We report the minimum (maximum order of magnitude negative value) of this series in the tables.

  • Number of effective positions (\(\mathcal{N}_{\!\hbox {\tiny eff}}\)): the number of effective positions is the integer part of the ratio

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{(\sum _{k=1}^N |w_k|)^2}{\sum _{k=1}^N w_k^2}. \end{aligned}$$

    We report the median value of this time series in the tables.

  • Number of nonzero positions: to overcome numerical effects, counting strictly positive positions is not convenient, so here is computed the number of realistic positions. A position is defined as realistic if its relative weight in the portfolio is higher than the portion represented by an elementary number of lotsFootnote 20 in a long only fund. So we count as being nonzero a position at time t for an asset k if its relative weight \(w_k(t) / w(t)^T \cdot \mathbf {1}\) in the portfolio is greater than:Footnote 21

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{w_k(t)}{w(t)^T \cdot \mathbf {1}} > \frac{c_k(t) \times 100}{1e9}, \end{aligned}$$

    where \(c_k(t)\) is the close price of the asset k. We report the median value of this time series in the tables.

  • Diversification Ratio (DR): we take the definitionFootnote 22 of Choueifaty and Coignard (2008) where this quantity is equal to:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{w^T \cdot \sigma }{\sqrt{w^T \cdot {\Omega } \cdot w}} \end{aligned}$$

    where \(\sigma _t\)here is the vector made of the univariate volatilities of the assets at date t. We report the median value of this time series in the tables.

Results and tables

See Table 5.

Table 5 Exhaustive statistics for all portfolios studied in the paper

Weights of a long-short portfolio

We study here the case of a long-short version of our long only portfolio of interest. Therefore, the problem is similar to the one of Sect. 3.2 except that the positions are unconstrained. We control the variance while following a rewarded factor. The portfolio construction following a rewarded factor with expected returns of \(\mu\) is then:

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \begin{array}{lll} \max _w &{} &{} w^T \mu \\ \hbox {u.c.} &{} (i) &{} w^T \mathbf {1}= 1\\ &{} (ii) &{} {1\over 2}w^T \Omega w\le {1\over 2}A^2 \end{array}\right. . \end{aligned}$$

Please note that as soon \(\mu\) is positive, we expect the risk constraint (ii) to be saturated, i.e. \(w^T \Omega w= A^2\).

To find its solution, it is enough to use Lagrange multipliers \(\lambda\) and \(\gamma\) (given this optimization problem respects the Karush-Kuhn-Tucker conditions since all expressions are smooth and convex). The optimization program reads

$$\begin{aligned} w^T \mu - \gamma (w^T \mathbf {1}- 1) - \frac{\lambda }{2}(w^T \Omega w - A^2). \end{aligned}$$

Deriving, respectively, to w and applying the first order condition gives that we simply have to look for the weights, solving \(\mu -\lambda \Omega w -\gamma \mathbf {1}= 0\) as a function of the multipliers, i.e.

$$\begin{aligned} w^{\mu mv} = {1\over \lambda } \Omega ^{-1} (\mu -\gamma \mathbf {1}). \end{aligned}$$
(20)

To find the values of the multipliers, we simply need to inject them in the constraints. In this respect, we introduce the following notation:Footnote 23

$$\begin{aligned} \omega _{11}= & {} \mathbf {1}^T\Omega ^{-1}\mathbf {1},\\ \omega _{1\mu }= & {} \mathbf {1}^T\Omega ^{-1}\mu ,\\ \omega _{\mu \mu }= & {} \mu ^T\Omega ^{-1}\mu . \end{aligned}$$

The linear constraint then reads:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda + \omega _{11}\gamma - \omega _{1\mu } = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(21)

and the quadratic one reads:

$$\begin{aligned} A^2 \lambda ^2 - \omega _{11}\gamma ^2 + 2\omega _{1\mu }\gamma -\omega _{\mu \mu } = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

A simple way to obtain the weights of the portfolio is to express them as

$$\begin{aligned} w^{\mu mv} = a\;\Omega ^{-1}\left( \mu -\frac{\omega _{1\mu }}{\omega _{11}}\mathbf {1}\right) + \frac{1}{\omega _{11}}\Omega ^{-1}\mathbf {1}, \end{aligned}$$
(23)

where \(a=1/\lambda\) is chosen to set the risk at the desired level \(A^2/2\). Moreover, injecting \(\gamma =(\omega _{1\mu } -\lambda )/\omega _{11}\) in Eq. 22 gives the exact and very useful relation between a and A (in other words, this relation links the desired level of risk with the risk aversion in the optimization program):

$$\begin{aligned} a^2 = \frac{\omega _{11}A^2 - 1}{\omega _{\mu \mu } \omega _{11} - \omega _{1\mu }^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Just note that a is well defined because:

  • The numerator of the right-hand side of this equality is positive as far as \(A^2>1/\omega _{11}\). It is always the case, and is equal if and only if the constraint on the risk is such that the portfolio is the Minimum Variance one.

  • Its denominator is always positive too because of the Cauchy-Schwartz, inequality applied to the Hermitian normFootnote 24 associated with \(\Omega ^{-1}\). It reaches zero only for the Minimum Variance portfolio, which is a specific case, that we may deal with the specific optimization problem detailed in Sect. 3.4.

Long only minimum variance portfolio

To explore the existence of a subset of stock selected in a Minimum Variance long only portfolio as described in 4.3.1, we will use a continuous framework to show the existence of a threshold on betas such that

$$\begin{aligned} B = \frac{1/{{\bar{\sigma }}}^2 + \sum _{k\in \mathfrak {S}} \beta _k^2/\sigma _k^2}{\sum _{k\in \mathfrak {S}} \beta _k/\sigma _k^2} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\mathfrak {S}\) is the set of all \(\beta _k\) lower than B. In this continuous framework we will no more have sums but integrals, and the set of stocks \((\beta _k,\sigma _k)_k\) will be defined by a joint density \(dm(\beta ,\sigma )\). To reflect the reality of the joint distribution of betas and idiosynchratic volatilities (see Fig. 1), we will make the technical assumption that the support of m is bounded in \(\beta\), i.e. there is a maximum beta \({\bar{\beta }}\) and a minimum beta \(\underline{\smash {\beta }}\). It allows to rewrite the upper equality as

$$\begin{aligned} B\cdot \int _{\beta<B} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma )= c + \int _{\beta <B} \frac{\beta ^2}{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ), \end{aligned}$$

where c is a positive constant properly defined.

The existence of a zero for the following function:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {B}}(x) = x\cdot \int _{\beta<x} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - \int _{\beta <x} \frac{\beta ^2}{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - c \end{aligned}$$

is now enough to proof the existence of B. For reader’s information, Fig. 3 shows the graph of this function on our real dataset (Russel 1000 from 2002-03-29 to 2018-12-27). Start by studying the behaviour of \({\mathfrak {B}}\) when x goes to extreme values:

  • When x is very small, equal to the minimum \(\underline{\smash {\beta }}\), then it is obvious that

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {B}}(\underline{\smash {\beta }})=\underline{\smash {\beta }}\frac{\underline{\smash {\beta }}}{\underline{\smash {\sigma }}^2} m(\underline{\smash {\beta }},\underline{\smash {\sigma }}) - \frac{\underline{\smash {\beta }}^2}{\underline{\smash {\sigma }}^2} m(\underline{\smash {\beta }},\underline{\smash {\sigma }}) - c=-c < 0. \end{aligned}$$
  • When x is very large, then \({\mathfrak {B}}(x)\) can be negative. In fact it is easy to see that when

    $$\begin{aligned} c+\int \frac{\beta ^2}{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - \int _{\beta <0} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) \ge \int _{\beta \ge 0} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ), \end{aligned}$$

    then \({\mathfrak {B}}(x)\) is negative for large values of x. We hence need to ask to \(m(\cdot , \cdot )\) (the joint distribution of the betas and the idiosyncratic volatilities of the stocks) to verify the opposite inequality:

    $$\begin{aligned}&c+\int \frac{\beta ^2}{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - \int _{\beta<0} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma )\\&\quad < \int _{\beta \ge 0} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ). \end{aligned}$$
    (P)

    Under such a condition, we observe that as soon as \(x>1\),

    $$\begin{aligned} x\cdot \int \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - \int \frac{\beta ^2}{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - c \ge \epsilon > 0. \end{aligned}$$

    The only “missing part” between the upper quantity and \({\mathfrak {B}}(x)\) is

    $$\begin{aligned} x\cdot \int _{\beta>x} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - \int _{\beta >x} \frac{\beta ^2}{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ). \end{aligned}$$

    And when x goes towards the maximum value \({\bar{\beta }}\) for the betas, this “missing part” goes to zero by definition of the Lebesgue integral. Thence there is a limit \(x_\epsilon\) such that when x is larger than \(x_\epsilon\), the missing part is lower than \(\epsilon\). As a consequence \({\mathfrak {B}}(x)>0\) as soon as \(x>x_\epsilon\).

We now know that \({\mathfrak {B}}\) goes from negative values at the left to positive values at the right. It is enough to know that it has at least one zero. Since the derivative of \({\mathfrak {B}}\) reads

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {B}}'(x)= & {} \int _{\beta<x} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ) - x \cdot \frac{x}{\sigma ^2} m(x,\sigma ) \\&+ \frac{x^2}{\sigma ^2} m(x,\sigma ) = \int _{\beta <x} \frac{\beta }{\sigma ^2} dm(\beta ,\sigma ). \end{aligned}$$

As underlined in Fig. 3, it is clear that this derivative it monotonous: it starts to be negative (under the realistic assumption that \(\underline{\smash {\beta }}<0\)) and is positive after a while because of Assumption (P). This is enough to conclude that there is one and only one zero for \({\mathfrak {B}}\) under our realistic assumption. It is equivalent to the existence and unicity of the threshold B needed to have a nonempty long only Minimum Variance portfolio.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Graph of function \({\mathfrak {B}}(x)+c\) for real data. The shape clearly confirms the theoretical results: going to zero by negative values at the left, towards positive values at the right; moreover the slope starts to decrease and after a while increases, leading to a unique zero for the function, here around 0.22. We know by Table 3 that the zero of \({\mathfrak {B}}(x)\) is around 0.33

Elements of proof for the existence of long only portfolios

Long only Managed Volatility portfolio

The complexity of defining conditions for the existence of a long only Managed Volatility portfolio stems from adding one dimension to the Minimum Variance one: now one has to deal not only with betas but also with factor loadings, and hence one have to consider two variables involving sums over the selected stocks: \(\mathbf {B}\) and \(\mathbf {C}\). This short appendix simply tries to give an intuition of what is be needed to proof the existence of a long only Managed Volatility portfolio on a given universe.

Going to deep in the details would be out of the scope of this paper, but it is easy to see that provided that \((\mu _k, \beta _k)\) are constrained to lay in the manifold \(\mathfrak {M}(a,v,\mathfrak {S})\) defined by

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _k = \frac{\omega _{11}}{1-a\,\omega _{1\mu }}(v-1)+ \frac{\beta _k}{\mathbf {C}(\mu _k,\beta _k,\mathfrak {S})}, \end{aligned}$$
(25)

then the problem is one dimensional and very close to the one of the Minimum Variance, since the condition (13) to keep a beta is now

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _k < v\cdot \mathbf {B}. \end{aligned}$$

Provided that Eq. 25 defines properly a one dimensional manifold, i.e. provided that it can be reduced to an implicit function \(\mu _k=f_{\mathfrak {M}(a,v,\mathfrak {S})}(\beta _k)\), then along this line in \(\mu _k\) we are facing the long only Minimum Variance problem. This means that we no more face a curve like the one of Fig. 3, but a surface made of such curves, organized in the \((\mu ,\beta )\) plane according to the \(\mathfrak {M}(a,v,\mathfrak {S})\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lehalle, CA., Simon, G. Portfolio selection with active strategies: how long only constraints shape convictions. J Asset Manag 22, 443–463 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41260-021-00219-z

Download citation

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41260-021-00219-z

Keywords

Navigation