Skip to content
BY 4.0 license Open Access Published by De Gruyter April 22, 2021

Corporate Social Bonds: A Legal Analysis

  • Diletta Lenzi EMAIL logo

Abstract

The article focuses on corporate social bonds, which are commonly defined as debt securities whose proceeds are used to finance projects or ventures at favourable conditions, in order to achieve positive social outcomes or to address specific social issues. Social bonds belong to the family of sustainable finance currently developing on international financial markets, especially in the European Union, and where a recent interest has also emerged at the political level. Although in March 2018 the European Commission published its Action Plan on Financing Sustainable Growth, at the moment of writing there is no specific EU legal framework for social bonds. The absence of a precise definition of social bonds and the uncertainty around the remedies for non-compliance of promised ‘social’ obligations entail serious risks of ‘socialwashing’ (i.e., the misappropriation of an increasingly attractive label).Through an analysis of the contractual design of social bonds, and the identification of different types of social bonds, the article identifies potential legal ‘Achilles heels’ of social bonds and suggests possible contractual remedies to ensure that both issuers and beneficiaries comply with their duties in terms of social impact achievement. Finally, the article suggests a European Union intervention in developing a ‘goal-oriented’ definition for social bonds.

1. Introduction

1.1. The European Legal Framework for Sustainable Finance and the International Market of Socially Responsible Investments

Expressions such as ‘sustainable finance’ or ‘socially responsible investment’ (SRI) usually refer to investors financing projects and ventures in order to generate a positive impact for society and/or the environment. Empirical studies of the European market show that institutional investors (mainly pension funds and insurers) increasingly invest in organisations, enterprises and projects that have a positive social and environmental impact, and in recent years we have witnessed the emergence of several forms of social financing.[1]

At the European Union level, ‘sustainable finance’ is commonly defined as that segment of the financial industry characterised by (i) the goal of financing sustainable and inclusive growth in the real economy and (ii) the incorporation of ESG[2] factors in investors’ decision-making process.[3]

Particularly, the European Commission considers private finance as a necessary driver towards more sustainable growth since, to this end, “the scale of the investment challenge is beyond the capacity of the public sector alone”;[4] and it is strongly engaged in promoting sustainable finance. In 2016, the Commission set up the High-Level Expert Group on Sustainable Finance (HLEG) and its 2018 report triggered the commitment by the Commission to “accelerat[e] the shift to sustainable finance”. On the basis of the HLEG report, the Commission adopted the Action Plan on Financing Sustainable Growth,[5] which aims to: “(1) reorient capital flows towards sustainable investment in order to achieve sustainable and inclusive growth; (2) manage financial risks stemming from climate change, environmental degradation and social issues; [and to] (3) foster transparency and long-termism in financial and economic activity”.[6]

The goal is not only to make the financial market more sustainable by fostering a long-term view, but also to use it as a driver towards more socially responsible enterprises and to enhance the transition towards a more sustainable growth of the real economy.

On the other hand, the international financial market has seen the steady growth of ‘socially responsible investing’, better known as ‘SRI’. This expression refers to investors that integrate social and environmental considerations into the research, analysis and selection of investments, or which adopt selection criteria that exclude beneficiaries that have a negative or not sufficiently positive impact on the environment or society, together with beneficiaries that are not managed in a sufficiently transparent and participative way.[7]

There are six main SRI strategies for investment selection known in market practices:[8](i) sustainability-themed investments (assets specifically related to sustainability funds); (ii) best-in-class investment selection (where investors choose companies with the highest ESG or other criteria-related scores in a specific industry);[9](iii) the exclusion of holdings from a specific investment universe (based on the exclusion of specific business sectors such as weapons, or countries that regularly violate human rights);[10](iv) norms-based screening (where beneficiaries are selected on the basis of human-rights fulfilment or the adoption of certain guidelines such as the UN Global Compact);[11](v) ESG factors’ integration in financial analysis; and (vi) engagement and voting on sustainability issues.

1.2. Social Impact Investing

Social impact investing can be considered as a specific type of the broader category of socially responsible investing, and sometimes it is understood as an SRI investment strategy.[12]

Social impact investing consists of hybrid forms of finance where investors’ actions are driven by both economic and social interests. Without a clear legal definition, we can describe it only in terms of market practice, where impact investing is characterised by three main features:

  1. Intentionality: the purpose of impact investing is to generate a positive and measurable social and/or environmental results;

  2. Additionality: this positive impact is pursued together with a ‘traditional’ financial return;

  3. Measurement: social impact investing must “account for in a transparent way on the financial, social and environmental performance of investments”,[13] and the implementation of a monitoring process to quantify the impact generated by the investment activities is required to support the social mission.[14]

Social impact can be obtained by adapting traditional financial tools (e. g. shares, bonds) or by devising new financial instruments (e. g. social impact bonds). In the first case, compared to their traditional correspondents (e. g. conventional bonds or shares in traditional companies, etc.), impact investments are generally ‘patient capital’:[15] namely, they do not pursue short-term financial returns. In general, sustainable financing rejects a short-term approach, which is not perceived as shorter-term financing—and indeed “liquidity management, treasury, trade credit and other financing of short duration all have their place in a sustainable financial system”—but as the “practice of finance that is focused on near-term profits rather than strategic fundamentals” and which is “reflected in analysis, allocation and trading that seeks to extract value over a time horizon where the underlying economic returns do not have the time to materialise”.[16]

Despite the absence of a European legal framework for impact investing, the European Commission, together with the European Committee of the Regions, has recently highlighted the importance for the European Union of supporting municipal and regional initiatives, such as green bonds, social bonds and sustainable bonds.[17]

This article focuses specifically on social bonds. After a preliminary description of the regulatory framework, it identifies the key legal aspects of these bonds, stressing potential weaknesses, and suggesting possible contractual remedies and regulatory interventions to enhance the integrity of the social bond market.

2. Social Bonds: Towards a Common Definition

Social bonds are commonly defined as debt securities[18] where proceeds are used to finance projects or ventures in order to achieve positive social outcomes or to address specific social issues. Social bonds have begun to spread in the wake of the green bonds market[19] and, together with the latter, they are more a ‘market product’[20] than a regulatory one.

Despite the growing market for social bonds and for impact investing in general, there is no public regulatory infrastructure; while in March 2018 the European Commission declared its intention to develop standards for green financial products,[21] no regulatory plan is addressing social bonds.[22]

Given the absence of a legal framework, a definition for social bonds needs to be found in market practice and private regulation.

The International Capital Market Association (ICMA)[23] has developed a set of ‘Social Bond Principles’ (SPBs), meant as a voluntary guidance process for issuing social bonds, freely available to market participants and designed to increase capital allocation to projects that have a positive social impact.[24] The guidelines address social bond issuers who are primarily responsible for implementing the Principles, and they are intended for investors to familiarise with the language, institutions and intrinsic structures of social bonds.

The Social Bond Principles define social bonds as any type of bond instrument whose proceeds are exclusively employed to finance (or re-finance in part or in full)[25] ‘eligible’ social projects (as listed in the guidelines), and which complies with the four core components of the Principles that define methods and processes for social issuers, as follows:

  1. Use of proceeds: proceeds must be employed to finance projects meant to provide specific social benefits or to address specific target populations. The document provides a list of social project categories, including but not limited to affordable basic infrastructure (such as clean drinking water or transport); access to essential services (such as health or education); affordable housing; employment; food security and sustainable food system; socioeconomic empowerment. Target populations include those “living below the poverty line (...), marginalised populations (...), people with disabilities, migrants (...), [the] undereducated (...), [the] underserved (...), [the] unemployed, women and/or sexual and gender minorities, aging population and vulnerable youth, [and] other vulnerable groups (...)”;[26]

  2. Project or business evaluation and selection: investors should be informed of the social objectives, the process of project selection and the projects' eligibility criteria;

  3. Management of proceeds: proceeds should be tracked and managed in a way that ensures commitment to the social impact;

  4. Reporting techniques: the guidelines recommend transparency, disclosure and reporting mechanisms to make social bonds more appealing products in the financial market.

This is the basis of any social bond’s issue and must be assessed against the bond’s terms and conditions. The details of the ICMA guidelines are examined in the following paragraphs. The analysis of the ICMA definition together with social bond experiences, all help identify the main characteristics of social bonds.

3. Core Characteristics of Social Bonds

As long as they seek to generate a positive social impact, social bonds can differ to some degree in the ways proceeds are employed and investment risk is balanced, as well as in relation to the social-impact timeframe or the role of the issuer. What should always be ensured is the generation of a social positive impact through the allocation of (even part of) the proceeds by a sophisticated subject (the issuer) that is in charge of selecting the project or the beneficiary and monitoring the effective generation of the social impact.

Within this frame there are three main distinctions which may facilitate the development of different types of social bonds. Categories of social bonds may mainly depend on:

  1. Who is in charge of achieving the social impact (issuer or beneficiary), and on what legal basis;

  2. The definition given to the achievement of the ‘social’ impact;

  3. Investor remuneration.

3.1. The Issuers of Social Bonds and Their Role in Achieving the Social Impact

A first distinction can be made depending on who is in charge of producing the social impact: the beneficiaries or the issuer.

Traditionally, social bonds have been issued to finance specific projects, ventures, or categories of ventures addressing targeted social issues. They normally involve three subjects: the issuer (e. g. a corporation, a bank, or other financial institutions), bondholders, and one or more ‘beneficiaries’ that are funded by the issuer thanks to the capital raised by issuing social bonds. Therefore, the beneficiary or beneficiaries are in charge of generating the social impact as contractually defined (e. g. building the hospital or developing the educational programme). These bond types can in turn be divided into two sub-types, depending on the issuer’s way of financing the beneficiary/ies: ‘grant-based’ and ‘loan-based’ social bonds. In the so-called ‘grant-based’ social bonds the issuer assigns a certain amount of money to finance a social project or venture (traditionally a non-profit organisation). By contrast, the so-called ‘loan-based’ social bonds help raise capital that will be employed by the issuer to grant loans at better-than-market conditions to selected targets of businesses.Loan-based social bonds allow a leverage effect that breaks the dependency of social enterprises on grant funding, making loans to social businesses less expensive.[27]

A second category of social bonds can be identified whenever corporations issue bonds to collect resources to be used to improve theirown positive social performance (e. g. to finance a health programme for their employees, or to start an employee’s family support programme). In this case, there are only two types of subjects involved (issuers and bondholders), and the issuer itself is responsible for the generation of the social impact.

Those two different types of social bonds may generate different legal issues. For instance, whenever the issuer is in charge on the social impact, it is even more important to provide for investor safeguards in terms of traceability of proceeds (para. 4.1.), and to consider appointing a bondholders’ representative (para. 4.3.).

3.2. The ‘Social’ Side of Social Bonds: The Lack of a Common Definition of ‘Social Impact’

To be defined as a social bond, a bond has to commit proceeds to generate a ‘social impact’. The absence of a clear definition of what is deemed ‘social’—or ‘green’ or ‘sustainable’—may hinder the development of a sustainable financial market.

The need to clarify the meaning of ‘sustainable’ impact has been acknowledged by the European Commission itself in its Action Plan of March 2018. This has also clearly emerged in the Taxonomy Technical Report of June 2019,[28] but only with specific reference to the concept of ‘environmental sustainability’ and ‘green bonds’. By contrast, at the time of writing there is no work in progress on the development of a common definition of positivesocial impact, with the consequent centrality of the contract in determining the social benefit.

In general terms, three key questions remain unanswered. The first is whether in determining the business’ or project’s positive social impact it is necessary to look at the impact as a whole, including its environmental effects. The ICMA guidelines state: “It is understood that certain Social Projects may also have environmental co-benefits, and that the classification of a use of proceeds bond as a social bond should be determined by the issuer based on its primary objectives for the underlying projects”. However, it goes on to state that “bonds that intentionally mix green and social projects are referred to as Sustainability Bonds”.[29] A reasonable interpretation of such a ‘provision’ should be that social bonds are created to generate a social positive impact and in doing so they can avoid aiming to generate a positive environmental impact. Yet, this does not mean that social bonds can generate a negative environmental impact. This may not, however, be as simple as it appears since environmental concerns may contrast with social needs, and sometimes a choice has to be made between one interest over another.

A second uncertainty is whether there are any activities that should not be financed through social bonds. For instance, can a bond issued to finance a business that produces weapons, but that employs a high percentage of disabled employees, qualify as a ‘social’ bond?

A third aspect is the worrying practice of conferring the social qualification to very generic activities, such as financing MSMEs.[30] Sometimes even ‘access to finance’ is treated as a social good per se.[31] In sophisticated markets, however, these practices should not be encouraged by international guidelines such as the Social Bond Principles: the social impact should go beyond the natural positive effects of the financial market itself. A loose definition of social impact may allow the inclusion of many projects and businesses under the social bond umbrella, which could negatively affect the understanding of social bonds, and thus reduce their attractiveness.

However, with regard to the impact ‘component’ of social bonds, the question of precisely which activities and projects can or cannot be financed does not really have an impact on the legal aspects of this financial instrument. On the contrary, different timeframes of impact achievement create different legal challenges.

In some cases, the social impact is achieved through the ‘simple’ act of financing the beneficiary: this is the case of loan-based social bonds issued to collect resources to grant loans at below market rates to specific business categories, and which generate a positive social impact by virtue of their mere ‘existence’ on the market (e. g. businesses owned and managed by minorities): in this case the social impact is achieved when the business receives the loan.

In other cases, impact achievement requires both time and the collaboration of the beneficiary. This is, for instance, the case of social bonds issued to grant resources to build a hospital, or to loan money at favourable rates provided that the beneficiary has a programme of hiring more workers with disabilities every year for the next x years. These social bonds with a long-term impact raise specific challenges in terms of ongoing evaluation of the beneficiary’s behaviour, or of the issuer’s conduct (whenever the issuer is also the beneficiary, see supra para. 3.1.).

3.3. Bondholder Remuneration

When social investors buy social bonds, they expect to contribute to the generation of a social impact and be remunerated for doing so.[32] However, the absence of a financial remuneration does not seem to overturn the nature of the social bond.

A full allocation of proceeds in favour of the social purpose, without any remuneration for bondholders, actually enhance the social impact of the single bond. However, such bond may realistically attract only ‘public-oriented’ investors, meant as proper public entities or investors with a declared mission that is purely altruistic. Differently, a private investor may be less attracted by social bonds with no financial remuneration: the same result—sometimes at a lower cost—could be obtained through a direct donation to the social project or venture; here the investor would suffer lower contractual and monitoring costs, and possibly enjoy the tax benefits that may come with grants. Moreover, private institutional investors would be limited by their core mission and could not underwrite social bonds that are not financially remunerated.

On the contrary, private investors could be more attracted by social bonds that provide financial remuneration. Even if these bonds would reduce the money allocated to the social impact for a single bond—due to the resources saved to reward the investor—they can improve the resources of the social bond market overall considered by attracting different types of investor: not only purely altruistic investors, but also investors willing to generate a positive social impact without relinquishing their right to financial remuneration. This would make social bonds attractive to the growing market of ‘hybrid’ investors that consider non-financial interests driven by financial interests.[33]

In conclusion, social bonds may vary in relation to the existence of a third beneficiary (para. 3.1.), the employment of proceeds or the impact achievements’ timeframe (para. 3.2.), and with regard to bondholders’ remuneration. Finally, social bonds may differ depending on the investment risk. For example, the social investors’ financial remuneration could be partially linked to the outcome of the social project—with or without potential recourse to the issuer.[34] In much the same way, bonds can be issued as collateralised by one or more specific social projects—including covered bonds, asset-backed securities, mortgage-backed security, and so forth.[35]

4. The Integrity of the Social Bond Market: How to Reduce ‘Socialwashing’

Even if social bonds are among the most recent forms of sustainable financing, they are rapidly spreading throughout financial markets, especially in Europe.[36] The fact that social bonds—together with green bonds—are flexible, easy to understand, and often resemble traditional bonds makes them attractive to institutional investors and private corporations alike.[37] However, as part of the impact investing family they are vulnerable to ‘socialwashing’.[38]

Social bonds are, de facto, ‘standardised’ financial instruments, where the actors involved are presumed to (also) act in the interest of generating a positive social impact. Any action that deviates or distorts this interest will damage the integrity of the social bond market, to the detriment of investors who genuinely engage in this market on account of its social impact.

Market actors should not be allowed to conceal traditional financial tools behind the ‘social’ (or ‘green’) label, making them more attractive on the market, for two main reasons:

  1. To safeguard bondholders who underwrite a social bond on account of the agreement that bond proceeds will be allocated to generate a social impact: if the investment rationale is the social impact, stakeholder interest becomes part of the contract, a ‘condition’ for investors to finance; they are no longer third-party interests, but an integral part of the bondholder’s interest;

  2. To preserve the integrity of the social bond market: the natural dynamic of such bonds (bondholders invest on the basis of a specific interest that bond proceeds are allocated to a social project or third party that generates a social impact) comes with several potential conflicts of interest. These are higher than those of traditional bonds since there are three parties involved (bondholders, issuers and beneficiaries) and interests which are heterogeneous (financial and non-financial interests). Also, social bonds drive up agency costs, and contractual costs increase due to any higher costs related to the analysis of these financial tools compared to traditional bonds. It is thus vital to prevent the actors that issue social bonds in good faith—having to bear additional costs compared to traditional bonds—from suffering from the deteriorating reputation of these financial instruments.[39]

The approach adopted with social bonds differs from the ESG proposal. The ESG approach is designed to increase the duties of compliance with environmental and social standards of investors and market actors, based on the political view that a transition to a more sustainable financial market (and then to a more sustainable real economy) is necessary, as well as on the basis that adopting a long-term view can be profitable. When it comes to social bonds, however, the goal is just to ensure that enterprises do what they say they are doing in terms of sustainability, so as to avoid socialwashing and to preserve the integrity of financial markets for social bonds.

In line with these goals, the considerations developed below are designed to foster the analysis of the legal implications and, more broadly, the debate on these new financial tools.

There are two main types of risks that the contract or law regulating the issue of social bonds should try to minimise. First, the bondholder’s risk that the issuer diverts proceeds to other activities or subjects, thus not fulfilling its social impact obligation. Second, whenever the social impact is not generated by the investment per se, but requires the collaboration of the beneficiary, there is the additional risk of proceeds being diverted for both bondholder and issuer. These risks call especially for the development of disclosure procedures. The second risk requires mechanisms to monitor the beneficiaries. Both involve processes for proceeds’ traceability, but also infra-group financing, and require the development of effective enforcement mechanisms. Moreover, within each risk category the approach should vary depending on the planned timeframe for impact achievement (see supra para. 3.2.).

What follows reflects on mechanisms to lock-in proceeds in favour of the generation of a social impact, processes for information disclosure, monitoring tools and procedures relating to both issuer and beneficiary (when the beneficiary is not the issuer), the effectiveness of enforcement mechanisms in case of non-fulfilment, and the role of independent review providers.

4.1. Allocating Proceeds for the Social Impact

A core concern is to ensure the commitment of proceeds in favour of beneficiaries as identified in the contract, and to avoid the management of proceeds in a way that is inconsistent with what has been agreed.

Firstly, procedures need to be in place to ensure traceability of proceeds. Crediting the net proceeds of social bonds (or an equal amount) to a sub-portfolio—as suggested by the ICMA guidelines—[40] could be considered a good rule to follow. Bondholders should be consequently informed: the issuer should disclose their intended management of proceeds to investors. This should clarify the investment operations engaged to realise the social impact, especially when the beneficiary is identified in a generic way (infra para. 4.2.1.). Ensuring the proper traceability of bond proceeds is even more important when the issuer is the party in charge of generating the social impact, e. g. bonds issued to improve the positive social externalities of the corporate issuer in terms of employee training.

Information should be updated periodically and communicated on a regular basis (e. g. annually). This mechanism should be backed up by the appointment of an auditor, entrusted to verify the internal tracking method and the general allocation of social bond proceeds (see infra para. 5.).

Secondly, the contract should disclose the existence of any economic relationship between the issuer and the beneficiary whenever the beneficiary is a different entity (e. g. being part of the same corporate group). What must be avoided is that the issuer uses social bonds to raise capital that will be employed to finance beneficiaries selected on the basis of the economic return that they will provide to the issuer; a typical example is the circumstance where the beneficiary is a member of the corporate group or an economic partner of the issuer. Any kind of pre-existing and new economic relationships between the issuer and the beneficiary should then be disclosed to bondholders at the time of the underwriting and in periodical reports.

4.2. Bondholder Ability to Monitor the Generation of the Social Impact

4.2.1. The Importance of Clearly Identifying the Social Impact

In the absence of a precise legal definition of what constitutes ‘social’, to help bondholders monitor the generation of the beneficiary, social impactshould be determined in the bond’s legal documentation in the clearest way possible. That is, issuers should specify the beneficiary by indicating the project’s and enterprise’s category, the industry, and—whenever possible—the alignment with market-wide guidelines: any information that can help the investors in their decision-making process is relevant. In addition, the issuer should clarify what this social impact consists of, also by identifying any target population(s), and the key performance indicators that will be employed to measure the social outcomes. In this context, the ICMA list of indicative project categories—which captures the most commonly used types of projects supported by, or potentially supported by, the social bond market—does not help significantly due to the rather general nature of some of the categories.[41]

Whenever social impact is generated by beneficiaries who are identified by the issuer, the issuer’s reputation and future capacity to attract new capital are conditional on the integrity of beneficiaries and their ability to generate the social impact. Thus, even from the issuer’s perspective, it is crucial that the legal documentation clearly identifies and assesses how social impact is actualised by the company financed or the project invested in.[42] This information should also be clearly communicated to bondholders.

Furthermore, where feasible, a quantification of social impact could increase bond appeal, but it should not be considered a core feature. What should be clearly quantified is the amount of proceeds addressed to the beneficiary or funded project, and the bondholder’s remuneration on investment. Similarly, the beneficiary should be identified in the most detailed way possible. However, financing the beneficiary could be considered as generating a social impact per se (e. g. financing a medical research centre for innovative oncological treatment) and the absence of an impact quantification in these cases does not seem to diminish the bond effectiveness.

4.2.2. Ex Ante and On-Going Disclosure of Information

A clearer identification of social impact in the bond indenture can simplify the monitoring process. Yet the contractual asymmetry of the parties involved and the heterogeneity of the interests tend to undermine monitoring strength and make it ineffective.

To empower investors and to make the monitoring process possible, the issuer should communicate transparent, accurate, and complete information to bondholders in a simple and regular way.[43] Disclosure of information is the prerequisite of any monitoring activity, so that transparency and disclosure become crucial to ensure the market integrity of social bonds as well as to enable a comparison with different financial products, thus creating a level playing field for social bonds.[44]

In some cases, where consistent with the national legal framework, administrative rights may also be established to improve monitoring. Bondholders traditionally have no power to influence companies’ management; they do not normally have voting rights or other governance rights, unlike equity owners. However, we can imagine mechanisms to increase investors’ powers, at least in terms of monitoring. In Italy, for instance, bondholders of public companies (società per azioni) are organised in special assemblies,[45] one for each bond issue,[46] that appoint a common representative. The representative has the right to take part in shareholders’ general meetings and is in charge of safeguarding the bondholder’s interest in their relationships with the company.[47] Furthermore, the bondholders’ meeting is called to approve the modifications to lending conditions. In such legal framework, in the case of a social bond issuing, bondholders could appoint a common representative authorised to take part in any shareholder general meetings, with the consequent ability to access direct information and better monitor the enterprise’s behaviour with regard to achieving social impact. However, under the Italian law these governance rights are only for bondholders of public companies, and do not legally apply to bonds issued by banks,[48] so that governance rights of this kind, in Italy, may not apply to those long-term loan-based social bonds mainly issued by banks for which monitoring social impact is particularly complicated, and where a bondholders’ representative could be important for reducing the deficit of information. Nothing, however, seems to prohibit a contractual provision designed to establish and regulate bondholders’ governance rights.

Finally, disclosure should not only concern the issuer’s use of proceeds, but also the beneficiary’s governance and activity, and the progress made in social impact achievement.

The inability of beneficiaries to address (or mitigate) deviation from the specific social issue and/or to achieve the social outcomes as set out in the contract can damage the issuer. Consequently, from the issuers’ perspective, a key concern is the existence and content of engagement policies to oversee the beneficiary’s behaviour and social impact achievement. The issuer should demand that the beneficiary provide transparent reporting on relevant sustainability issues in relation to business strategy, operations and risks, including the most significant parts of their supply chain. The assessment should take into consideration the intrinsic long-term view of any social impact, and beneficiaries may also be required to engage with their stakeholders.[49] In this context, the use of qualitative and, where feasible, quantitative performance indicators is appropriate.

The quality and credibility of non-financial disclosure, however, “is often doubted due to the control that companies exercise over this information”.[50] To prevent socialwashing a third independent party could be selected and be actively encouraged to take responsibility for verifying information (even by means of certification and independent auditing),[51] and for helping with an informed selection of beneficiaries.[52]While the issuer could look at the market to appoint an independent auditor, purely private certifications—especially when there is no post-issuing control over the issuer (as it is with the ICMA Social Bond Principles) —risk being less effective[53]. On the opportunity to develop a certification system at the European Union level see infra para. 6.

4.3. Making Monitoring and Enforcement Effective

If tracking methods for proceeds (para. 4.1.), together with the identification of a beneficiary that is not too generic (para. 4.2.1.), and an adequate disclosure procedure (para. 4.2.2.) could make social bonds more appealing in theory, it is still doubtful whether non-fulfilment by issuers are enforceable in practice. This is because it is required to verify whether, on the one hand, bondholders have the incentives to monitor the issuer; and, on the other hand, whether bondholders have the incentives and capacity to take actions in cases of non-fulfilment. Disclosure is extremely important but may prove useless if the addressee does not have the incentive and strength to correctly monitor and force the issuer to comply with the obligations set out in the bond contract.

Generally, bondholders are believed to have few or no interests in the decision-making process of corporate management, since they enjoy priority over shareholders in cases of insolvency. For traditional bonds, creditors’ interest consists of being paid back and having their investment financially rewarded. This sort of interest is indirectly satisfied by shareholders’ interest in making profits and shareholders are the most motivated when it comes to monitoring management behaviour: as long as the company is solvent, the interests of shareholders and creditors can be considered aligned. On the contrary, shareholders will not necessarily be interested in monitoring the achievement of social impact in cases of issuing social bonds.

Another issue emerges when considering how, in contrast to common bonds, the holder of a social bond is no longer the principal beneficiary of the contract, but the contracting parties (bondholder and issuer) voluntarily decide to benefit a third party. In the worst-case scenario both bondholder and issuer could deviate from the social ‘goal’ and agree (even implicitly) on a different use of proceeds. If put into practice this approach would undermine the credibility of the financial instrument on the market and cause significant distortion of competition with other social bond issuers. To prevent such deviations, and to make monitoring effective, several contractual devices can be used.

We have already examined the case of appointing a common representative of bondholders—with the example of the Italian ‘rappresentante degli obbligazionisti’ (para. 4.2.2.)—who could also be empowered to claim for damages in the name of bondholders.

In this context, and still thinking in terms of contractual solutions, the bond indenture could also establish economic incentives for an external actor to monitor the issuer. The contract could, for instance, identify a second potential beneficiary entitled to claim for social bond proceeds in the case of the issuer’s non-fulfilment, thus compensating for the inactivity of the original beneficiary and providing for the cases of undetermined beneficiaries or categories of beneficiaries which are excessively generic.[54]

Another contractual remedy could be the ex-ante identification of a bondholders’ trustee responsible for monitoring the issuer’s behaviour in terms of social impact achievement and for reporting to bondholders on their findings, and who could be authorised to enforce the breach of contract in the name of the bondholder.[55]

The contract can also provide covenants that restrict the issuer’s right to take decisions, by providing penalties for specific behaviours.

4.4. Consequences of Non-Fulfilment of the ‘Social’ Obligation

From the investor’s perspective, if the issuer does not comply with the repayment obligation, traditional enforcement tools apply, and the bondholder could potentially claim for an order of compliance and legal compensation. Differently, there is much less certainty when it comes to the consequences faced by the issuer in cases of failure to comply with its duty to use proceeds to finance social projects or ventures. This sort of situation would seem to integrate a breach of contract, as in the case of non-compliance with repayment obligations: when the bondholder chooses a social bond because of its ‘social’ nature, this choice integrates a legal interest worthy of protection within the legal framework of the European Union. Nevertheless, social bonds are not only an expression of freedom of contract, but are also consistent with the European political choice to engage private finance in the process of supporting the transformation of Europe’s economy into a more sustainable one.[56] The development and dissemination of a new financial instrument go hand in hand with the protection provided by law in cases of non-fulfilment.

To facilitate the recognition of such a legal interest, international guidelines such as the ICMA Principles—together with any future regulation—should suggest that, in bond indentures, the rationale behind the underwriting and the bondholder’s willingness to generate a (more or less) specific social impact through the allocation of bond proceeds be made explicit. However, this leaves room for several and still unanswered questions.

Firstly, what happens in the case of non-performance of the social impact obligation when this requires the collaboration of the beneficiary? There appear to be three main options open:

  1. The issuer is the only person accountable to the bondholder in the case of non-fulfilment;

  2. The issuer and the beneficiary are jointly liable;

  3. Issuer accountability can be negotiated, and can be excluded by contract, leaving the beneficiary as the sole party liable.

The last option, if legally feasible under national law,[57] should be discouraged. The issuer is the one primarily responsible for the generation of social impact not only because it is the issuer who selects and negotiates with the beneficiary, but also because, from an efficiency perspective, the issuer will probably be a more sophisticated actor than the bondholder, and in a better position to monitor the behaviour of the parties involved. Removing the issuer’s potential liability will eliminate any incentive for the issuer to monitor the beneficiary’s effective engagement to generate a positive social impact and, more generally, to cooperate in order to give full effect to the contract.

On the other hand, the first two options both seem feasible, and a joint liability of issuers and beneficiaries is probablies the preferred solution from the bondholder’s perspective.

Secondly, for any social bond it is doubtful whether the bondholder can claim specific performance of the contract (at least in those legal systems where national law regulates the right to performance of non-monetary obligations) when the beneficiary is not identified by the contract, or he/she can only claim for damages. This is why the terms and conditions of the bond should both be as specific as possible—if not in the details of the project or company to be financed, at least—in the process and criteria adopted to evaluate and select the beneficiary project or enterprise (supra para. 4.2.1.), and regulate the case of non-performance.

Thirdly, it is not clear how damage is to be quantified. One partial solution would be to use contractual covenants in bond contracts that provide for acceleration in terms of non-compliance.[58]

Finally, there is clear room for public supervision, albeit what its structure and extent should be requires further reflections. In particular, it is conceivable that the violation of the duty to generate social impact be considered as a market manipulation under Article 12, Regulation (EU) No. 596/2014 (‘MAR’) and Article 5, Directive (EU) 2014/57 (‘MAD II’).[59] In this perspective, it seems important to distinguish the case in which the failure to comply with the ‘social impact’ obligation was already existing at the moment of the issuing (e. g. social bonds issued with no intention nor capability to generate a positive social impact), from the case in which the impact was never realised despite the issuer’s will (e. g. the beneficiary did not build the hospital as it was supposed to do).

Moreover, whenever the issuer of social bonds is subject to Directive (EU) 2014/65 (‘MiFID II’), so-called ‘product governance’ rules can apply, and social bonds can be subjected to the supervision of the European Securities and Market Authorities.

5. Review Provider

ICMA guidelines advise the appointment of “external review providers to confirm the alignment of their bonds with the four components of the SBP (...)”, and also recommend public disclosure of external reviews.

Some of the risks analysed above could indeed be mitigated through the appointment of a review provider, who could be responsible for:

  1. Formulating a second-party opinion on social bond feasibility that will support the issuer in selecting the beneficiary. In this context, the advice of an independent reviewer may help in the identification of social projects or ventures;[60]

  2. Verifying the tracking method and the general allocation of social bond proceeds;

  3. Monitoring the social impact and evaluating its achievement: in contrast to other forms of sustainable finance, an external independent evaluator is not necessary for social bonds.[61] However, the contract may provide for the appointment of an evaluator, which seems particularly appropriate in the case of social bonds with a long-term impact;

  4. Verifying the information released by the issuer to the market.

If appointed, the review provider should be independent of both issuer and beneficiary, at least when he/she is entrusted with the opinion on the social bond feasibility and the verification of the information released by the issuer to the market. On the contrary, and when compatible with national jurisdictions, responsibility for tracking proceeds and monitoring social impact could be conferred to issuers’ internal auditors or internal committees, thus limiting the costs.

6. Final Remarks. A Goal-Oriented ‘Label’ for Social Bonds?

Social bonds are a good example of what financial innovation can achieve. At the EU[62] and the international level there is a growing awareness of the central role that the private sector can play in supporting sustainable development. In this sense the financial market is essential in providing incentives for activities in line with the goals of the United Nations 2030 Agenda.[63]

In this context, social bonds may be particularly appealing to market actors since they strongly resemble traditional bonds. Yet the social allocation of proceeds generates new challenges. Above we have identified the key components of social bonds and suggested contractual devices to enhance their sustainability, by ensuring the effectiveness of the social impact achievement. However, purely contractual solutions may not be enough to preserve the integrity of the social bond market and to avoid sacrificing those investors who genuinely engage in order to generate a social positive impact, potentially suffering reduced profitability comparing to traditional investments.

To fight socialwashing, the need for some sort of public supervision arises and a ‘rulemaking’ intervention is called for.

The rationale underlying any regulation of the social bond market should partially differ from what is taking place at the EU level with the awareness-raising process on the so-called ‘ESG’.[64] Taken together, all these aim to encourage the financial system to adopt higher standards in terms of environmental and social positive externalities of investment. However, social bonds reach beyond socially responsible investing, since the holders of social bonds do not simply consider environmental and social concerns in their investment selection process (e. g. preferring investments that reduce negative externalities), but want to actively generate a positive social impact.[65] Consequently, the main issue with impact investing is finding ways to empower these investors driven by the desire for social (or environmental) impact to use the market as a way to achieve it.[66] By recognising this different ‘rationality’[67] that can drive investors in their market choices, it is necessary to adjust the system so as to ensure suitable safeguards. This should be the rationale of a regulatory intervention in this context: not only should the specific bondholder interest(s) be taken into consideration, but also the general ‘SRI market’ interest[68] of preserving social bond integrity in the financial market, thus limiting socialwashing.

In terms of how to regulate, it is believed that many of the solutions described above could be introduced by private ordering and supported by private guidelines, through a ‘permissive’, rather than ‘prescriptive’, rulemaking approach.[69] However, clarifying what ‘social impact’ means—in line with the ‘regulation’ of standards for green bonds[70]—appears to be important:[71] specifying what can be considered a social bond may help reduce uncertainty and avoid the development of socialwashing that will consequently generate scepticism regarding these financial instruments.

Turning to the question of how far a regulatory intervention should go in standardising the content of the contract, a social bond definition should not be too detailed. On the other hand, detail appears to be preferable to a minimal intervention, thus avoiding the risk of adopting a definition that will rapidly become obsolete: a ‘goal-oriented’ definition could identify a minimum common core of requirements necessary for a social bond to be defined as such, and then be assisted by a set of guidelines for voluntary adoption, which should be devised to take best market practices into account, and their development over time (e. g. imagining a periodic review process of standards).

The need to ensure the trust of investors and civil society in the social impact achievements of social bonds should be weighed against the need to allow social bonds to evolve over time and to be responsive to changing market needs.[72]

Consequently, a public regulatory intervention should be made alongside private guidelines. Guidelines for voluntary adoption can be considered a positive tool in promoting integrity, ensuring greater transparency and better enforcement, consequently increasing capital allocation to social bonds. Furthermore, guidelines may allow access to innovative financing not only to banks, professional investors and large corporations, but also to small and medium-sized closed corporations, for which innovation is often too costly. At this preliminary stage, the ICMA guidelines can be considered a good example in terms of intention and methodology, since they are designed to create a collaborative and consultative community. However, they still seem to lack clarity and effective monitoring and enforcement mechanisms, leaving room for improvement.

A combination of improved feasibility and standardisation could enhance the development of a sustainable market for corporate social bonds. Standardisation[73] in general makes financial instruments less expensive, accessible to unsophisticated investors, and more attractive to market actors. In doing so any (public and private) regulatory regimes must be configured in a way that considers long-term expectations of financial returns.[74]

Finally, what level of regulation has to be reached to arrive at a shared consensus on the notion of social bonds—international, European, national? Ideally, an internationally agreed definition would be the best option. However, there is even less international consensus on what is considered to have a social impact than on what is environmentally sustainable. Social sustainability is highly influenced by a country’s standard of human rights’ compliance, and international standards on human rights are often weaker than already protected rights, for instance, those protected by the European Convention on Human Rights, or at the national level in some countries (e. g. US laws against gender discrimination). Working for an international consensus on a common definition of the social impact may therefore lower the level of compliance for some Western or, at least, some European countries.

On the other hand, opting for a national regime, even if it allows a greater level of depth and detail, runs a risk of fragmentation and may enhance competition among legal systems, which may in turn lead to ‘a race to the bottom’.

Having considered all this, one valid option may be to look at the EU level for consensus. First, the European Commission has demonstrated a strong political interest on financial innovation. Second, it is building expertise in the sector thanks to its work on the taxonomy for green financial products.[75] Third, the European Union could easily offer assistance in terms of external control and public supervision of the issuer’s compliance with social bond standards: this is vital when it comes to ensuring that what a business declares it is doing is what it is actually doing. The European Union has already shown itself capable of managing such a system.[76]

A European standard, however, should not be limited to European issuing, but should be accessible for potential non-European issuers, in line with the mission of the EU Technical Expert Group on Sustainable Finance for green bonds.[77]

In conclusion, considering the ongoing work at the European Union level in terms of social innovation and sustainable finance, it would be a lost opportunity were the EU’s interest in sustainable finance to be limited to green financial products, leaving social bonds out of the debate. In the same way, it seems necessary to clarify the relationship between social impacts and environmental impacts.


Note

The Article has benefitted from the author’s participation in the research project ‘From the theory of social finance to a concrete social bond’ directed by Riccardo Salomone, held at the University of Trento-Faculty of Law and financed by Fondazione CARITRO (March 2018–March 2020). A preliminary version of this Article was presented at the workshop ‘Finance for sustainability’, organised by Beate Sjåfjell within the ‘Daughters of Themis Network’ (June 2019), when the paper has received beneficial remarks. The author would like to thank Lorenzo Stanghellini, Andrea Zorzi and Luigi Vigoriti for their valuable advice and precious comments on the final version of the paper. The usual disclaimers apply.


Published Online: 2021-04-22
Published in Print: 2021-04-12

© 2021 Diletta Lenzi, published by Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 25.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/ecfr-2021-0014/html
Scroll to top button