Skip to main content
Log in

Transboundary Pollution Control and Competitiveness Concerns in a Two-Country Differential Game

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze a transboundary pollution control problem in a heterogeneous two-country differential game setting in which regulators care for the implications of environmental policies on the competitiveness. We characterize the noncooperative and the cooperative solutions, showing that under both scenarios, in the presence of competitiveness considerations, heterogeneous countries will generally set different carbon taxes. This suggests, while implementing a mitigation policy is necessary to combat climate change, a universally homogeneous policy may not be optimal. Moreover, when countries are symmetric, except for their degree of competitiveness concerns, under noncooperation introduction of such concerns lowers the abatement policies in both countries, however, the self-effect is stronger than the cross-effect. Nevertheless, under cooperation, an increase in country j’s competitiveness concerns leads to more stringent policies in country i, while, the self-effect could be either positive or negative. The latter result emphasizes the importance of cooperation to tackle pollution in the presence of competitiveness concerns.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

Data sharing not applicable to this article as no datasets were generated or analyzed during the current study.

Notes

  1. \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{i}}=\frac{\nu \left( \gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}\right) \left[ \beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha +\beta _{i}+6\beta _{j}\right) -\alpha ^{2}-6\beta _{j}\left( \alpha +\beta _{j}\right) \right] }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{_{j}}\right) ^{2}\right] ^{2}}\) and \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{j}}=\frac{\nu \left( \gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}\right) \left[ \beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha -5\beta _{i}\right) +\alpha ^{2}-\beta _{j}^{2}+\beta _{j}\left( 2\alpha +3\beta _{j}+2\beta _{i}\right) \right] }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{_{j}}\right) ^{2}\right] ^{2}}\), meaning if \(\beta _{i}>\beta _{j}\) (or \(\beta _{j}>\beta _{i}\)), then \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{i}}\ge 0\) (or \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{i}}\le 0\)) and \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{j}}\) is positive as long as \(\beta _{i}\) is not too large.

  2. The expression for \(A_{i}\) is not reported since it is too long but is available upon request.

References

  1. IPCC. (2007). Climate change 2007 - Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability- Summary for policymakers, in ”Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change” (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK).

    Google Scholar 

  2. IPCC. (2018). Climate Change 2018 - The physical science basis, Summary for policymakers, in: (Socker, T.F., Qin, D., Plattner, G.-K., Tignor, M., Allen, S.K., Boschung, J., Nauels, A., Xia, Y., Bex, V., Midgley, P.M., Eds.) “Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change” (Cambridge University Press: United Kingdom and New York)

  3. OECD. (2013). Effective carbon prices (OECD Publishing: Paris), available online at: https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264196964-en

  4. Ansuategi, A., & Perrings, C. A. (2000). Transboundary externalities in the environmental transition hypothesis. Environmental and Resource Economics, 17, 353–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Ansuategi, A. (2003). Economic growth and transboundary pollution in Europe: an empirical analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics, 26, 305–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (1994). North-South trade and the environment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 755–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Levinson, A., & Taylor, M. S. (2008). Unmasking the pollution haven effect. International Economic Review, 49, 223–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. van der Ploeg, F., & Withagen, C. (1991). Pollution control and the Ramsey problem. Environmental and Resource Economics, 1, 215–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Athanassoglou, S., & Xepapadeas, A. (2012). Pollution control with uncertain stock dynamics: when, and how, to be precautious. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 63, 304–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Saltari, E., & Travaglini, G. (2016). Pollution control under emission constraints: switching between regimes. Energy Economics, 53, 212–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. La Torre, D., Liuzzi, D., & Marsiglio, S. (2017). Pollution control under uncertainty and sustainability concern. Environmental and Resource Economics, 67, 885–903.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. van der Ploeg, F., & de Zeeuw, A. (1992). International aspects of pollution control. Environmental and Resource Economics, 2, 117–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Long, N. V. (1992). Pollution control: a differential game approach. Annals of Operations Research, 37, 283–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Rubio, S. J., & Ulph, A. (2007). An infinite-horizon model of dynamic membership of international environmental agreements. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 54, 296–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Masoudi, N., & Zaccour, G. (2013). A differential game of international pollution control with evolving environmental costs. Environment and Development Economics, 18, 680–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Pethig, R. (1976). Pollution, welfare and environmental policy in the theory of comparative advantage. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 2, 160–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Siebert, H. (1977). Environmental quality and the gains from trade. Kyklos, 30, 657–673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. McGuire, M. (1982). Regulation, factor rewards and international trade. Journal of Public Economics, 17, 335–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Jaffe, A. B., Peterson, S. R., Portney, P. R., & Stavins, R. N. (1995). Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing: what does the evidence tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 132–163.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Ederington, J., Levinson, A., & Minier, J. (2005). Footloose and pollution-free. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 92–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Aldy, J. E., & Pizer, W. A. (2015). The competitiveness impacts of climate change mitigation policies. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 2, 565–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Carbone, J. C., & Rivers, N. (2017). The impacts of unilateral climate policy on competitiveness: evidence from computable general equilibrium models. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11, 24–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Dechezlepretre, A., & Sato, M. (2017). The impacts of environmental regulations on competitiveness. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11, 183–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Financial Times. (2018). French business counts the cost of ‘gilets jaunes’ protests, available online at: https://www.ft.com/content/62e2f894-fc8c-11e8-aebf-99e208d3e521

  25. Government of Canada. (2017). Pricing carbon pollution in Canada: how it will work, available online at: https://www.canada.ca/en/environment-climate-change/news/2017/05/pricing_carbon_pollutionincanadahowitwillwork.html

  26. Newfoundland Government. (2018). Provincial government releases federally-approved made-in-Newfoundland and Labrador approach to carbon pricing, available online at: https://www.releases.gov.nl.ca/releases/2018/mae/1023n01.aspx

  27. Jorgensen, S., Martin-Herran, G., & Zaccour, G. (2010). Dynamic games in the economics and management of pollution. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 15, 433–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank the Editor and two anonymous referees for their constructive comments on an earlier draft of the paper. All remaining errors and omissions are our own sole responsibility. Simone Marsiglio acknowledges financial support by the University di Pisa under the “PRA - Progetti di Ricerca di Ateneo” (Institutional Research Grants) - Project no. PRA_2020_79 “Sustainable development: economic, environmental and social issues”.

Funding

Simone Marsiglio acknowledges financial support by the University di Pisa under the ”PRA Progetti di Ricerca di Ateneo” (Institutional Research Grants) - Project no. PRA 2020 79 ”Sustainable development: economic, environmental and social issues”. Nahid Masoudi did not receive support from any organization for the submitted work.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Both authors contributed to the study conception design and writing the manuscript. Both authors read and approved the final version.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nahid Masoudi.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of Interest

The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose. The authors have no conflicts of interest to declare that are relevant to the content of this article.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Technical Appendix

Noncooperative Solution

In the noncooperative case, the solution to the problem Eqs. (3) and (4) should satisfy the following Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equation, where \(J_{i}^{n}\left( P\right)\) represents the country \(i'\)s regulator value function and \(J_{i,P}^{n}=\frac{\partial J_{i}^{n}}{\partial P}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \theta J_{i}^{n}\left( P\right) = &\max _{0\le \tau _{i}<1}\left\{ \gamma _{i}P_{t}+\frac{1}{2}\alpha _{i}\tau _{i}^{2}+\beta _{i}\tau _{i}\left( \tau _{i}-\tau _{j}\right) \right. \\ & \left. +J_{i,P}^{n}\left[ \nu _{i}\left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) +\nu _{j}\left( 1-\tau _{j}\right) -\delta P\right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(17)

The first-order condition yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{i}\tau _{i}+2\beta _{i}\tau _{i}-\beta _{i}\tau _{j}-J_{i,P}^{n}\nu _{i}=0. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

We conjecture that the value function \(J_{i}^{n}\left( P\right)\) has the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} J_{i}^{n}\left( P\right) =A_{i}^{n}+B_{i}^{n}P, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

where \(A_{i}\) and \(B_{i}\) are some constants to be determined. Plugging the first-order conditions for the regulators of the two countries and the conjectured value function into Eq. (17) and solving for \(A_{i}\) and \(B_{i}\) yields \(B_{i}=\frac{\gamma _{i}}{\theta +\delta }\).Footnote 2 Using these results to substitute back into the first-order condition leads to noncooperative carbon tax rate given in Eq. (5). Substituting this into Eq. (4) and solving for P yields the noncooperative pollution trajectory given by: \(P^n=\frac{\nu _{i}(1-\tau _{i}^n)+\nu _{j}(1-\tau _{j}^n)}{\delta } + \left[ P_0 - \frac{\nu _{i}(1-\tau _{i}^n)+\nu _{j}(1-\tau _{j}^n)}{\delta }\right] e^{-\delta t}\). Since \(\tau _{i}^n\) and \(\tau _{j}^n\) are constant and \(\delta\) is strictly positive, it is straightforward to verify that the transversality condition \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-\theta t}J_i^n(P^n)=0\) is automatically satisfied. Since both the objective function and the state equation are convex in the control and state variables, it follows that the first-order conditions are both necessary and sufficient.

The derivatives of the carbon tax rate in Eq. (5) undoubtedly yield: \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \gamma _{i}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \gamma _{j}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \alpha _{i}}<0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}<0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \nu _{i}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \nu _{j}}>0\). The effect of the degree of the competitiveness concern is instead ambiguous, since the following results apply:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \beta _{i}}=\frac{\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \left( \alpha _{i}\nu _{j}\gamma _{j}-\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \nu _{i}\gamma _{i}\right) }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +\beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}},\end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tau _{j}^{n}}{\partial \beta _{i}}=\frac{\beta _{j}\left( \alpha _{i}\nu _{j}\gamma _{j}-\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \nu _{i}\gamma _{i}\right) }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +\beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}}, \end{aligned}$$
(21)

i.e., \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \beta _{i}}\le (\ge )0\) if \(\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \nu _{i}\gamma _{i}\ge (\le )\alpha _{i}\nu _{j}\gamma _{j}\), while \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \beta _{j}}\le (\ge )0\) if \(\left( 2\alpha _{i}+3\beta _{i}\right) \nu _{j}\gamma _{j}\ge (\le )\alpha _{j}\nu _{i}\gamma _{i}\).

The derivatives of the difference between the carbon tax rates in Eq. (6) are given by the following expressions which are again ambiguous:

$$\begin{aligned}& \frac{\partial (\tau _{i}^{N}-\tau _{j}^{N})}{\partial \beta _{i}}=\frac{\left( \alpha _{j}+\beta _{j}\right) \left( \alpha _{i}\gamma _{j}\nu _{j}-\gamma _{i}\nu _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right) }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +\beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}},\\& \frac{\partial (\tau _{i}^{N}-\tau _{j}^{N})}{\partial \beta _{j}}=-\frac{\left( \alpha _{i}+\beta _{i}\right) \left( \alpha _{j}\gamma _{i}\nu _{i}-\gamma _{j}\nu _{j}\left( 2\alpha _{i}+3\beta _{i}\right) \right) }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +\beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

However, \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \beta _{i}}\) and \(\frac{\partial (\tau _{i}^{N}-\tau _{j}^{N})}{\partial \beta _{i}}\) has same sign, while signs of \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{n}}{\partial \beta _{j}}\) and \(\frac{\partial (\tau _{i}^{N}-\tau _{j}^{N})}{\partial \beta _{j}}\) are opposite.

Cooperative Solution

In the cooperative case, the solution to the problem Eqs. (7) and (8) should satisfy the HJB equation, where now \(J_{i}^{*}\left( P\right)\) represents the social (joint) value function and \(J_{P}^{*}=\frac{\partial J^{*}}{\partial P}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \theta J^{*}\left( P\right) =\max _{0\le \tau _{i},\tau _{j}<1}&\left\{ \left( \gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}\right) P_{t}+\frac{1}{2}\left( \alpha _{i}\tau _{i}^{2}+\alpha _{j}\tau _{j}^{2}\right)\right. \\ & \left. +\left( \beta _{i}\tau _{i}-\beta _{j}\tau _{j}\right) \left( \tau _{i}-\tau _{j}\right) +\right. \nonumber \\ & +\big .J_{P}^{*}\left[ \nu _{i}\left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) +\nu _{j}\left( 1-\tau _{j}\right) -\delta P\right] \big \}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

The first-order condition yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \alpha _{i}+2\beta _{i}\right) \tau _{i}=\left( \beta _{i}+\beta _{j}\right) \tau _{j}+\nu _{i}J_{p}^{*}. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Our informed guess for the form of the value function is \(J^{*}\left( P\right) =A^{*}+B^{*}P\), where \(A^{*}\) and \(B^{*}\) are constant to be determined. Replacing this conjectured value function and the first-order condition into Eq. (22) leads to \(B^{*}=\frac{\gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}}{\theta +\delta }\). Using the result to substitute back into the first-order condition leads to cooperative carbon tax rate given in Eq. (10). Substituting this into Eq. (8) and solving for P yields the cooperative pollution trajectory given by: \(P^*=\frac{\nu _{i}(1-\tau _{i}^*)+\nu _{j}(1-\tau _{j}^*)}{\delta } + \left[ P_0 - \frac{\nu _{i}(1-\tau _{i}^*)+\nu _{j}(1-\tau _{j}^*)}{\delta }\right] e^{-\delta t}\). Also in this case, since \(\tau _{i}^*\) and \(\tau _{j}^*\) are constant and \(\delta\) is strictly positive, the transversality condition \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-\theta t}J_i^*(P^*)=0\) turns out to be automatically satisfied. Since both the objective function and the state equation are convex in the control and state variables, it follows that the first-order conditions are both necessary and sufficient.

The derivatives of the carbon tax rate in Eq. (10) undoubtedly yield: \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \gamma _{i}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \gamma _{j}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \alpha _{i}}<0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}<0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \nu _{i}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \nu _{j}}>0\). The derivatives with respect to the degree of competitiveness concerns are instead ambiguous:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{i}}=-\frac{\left( \gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}\right) \left( 2\alpha _{j}^{2}\nu _{i}-\beta _{i}^{2}\nu _{j}-2\beta _{i}\beta _{j}\left( 2\nu _{i}+\nu _{j}\right) +\alpha _{j}\left( 6\beta _{j}\nu _{i}-2\beta _{i}\nu _{i}-\alpha _{i}\nu _{j}+2\beta _{j}\nu _{j}\right) +\beta _{j}\left( 4\beta _{j}\nu _{i}-2\alpha _{i}\nu _{j}+3\beta _{j}\nu _{j}\right) \right) }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left( 2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{j}\right) ^{2}+\alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \right) ^{2}}, \\ \frac{\partial \tau _{i}^{*}}{\partial \beta _{j}}=\frac{\left( \gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}\right) \left( 2\beta _{i}\nu _{j}\left( \beta _{j}-\alpha _{i}\right) +\beta _{j}^{2}\left( 2\nu _{i}+\nu _{j}\right) -\beta _{i}^{2}\left( 2\nu _{i}+3\nu _{j}\right) +\alpha _{j}\left( 2\beta _{j}\nu _{i}+\alpha _{i}\nu _{j}+2\beta _{i}\left( \nu _{i}+\nu _{j}\right) \right) \right) }{\left( \delta +\theta \right) \left( 2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{j}\right) ^{2}+\alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \right) ^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

The derivatives of the difference between the carbon tax rates in Eq. (11) are given by the following expressions which are again ambiguous:

Cooperation vs Noncooperation

The derivatives of the size of the distortion obtained by subtracting Eqs. (5) from (10) yield:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \left( \tau _{i}^{*}-\tau _{i}^{n}\right) }{\partial \beta _{i}}=\frac{\gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}}{\left( \delta +\theta \right) }\left\{ \frac{\nu _{j}\left[ 2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{j}\right) ^{2}+\alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \right] -2\left( \alpha _{j}-\beta _{i}+\beta _{j}\right) \left[ \alpha _{j}\nu _{i}+\beta _{i}\nu _{j}+\beta _{j}\left( 2\nu _{i}+\nu _{j}\right) \right] }{\left[ 2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{j}\right) ^{2}+\alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}}\right\} + \\ & \qquad \qquad \qquad \; \frac{1}{\left( \delta +\theta \right) }\left\{ \frac{\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \left[ \nu _{i}\gamma _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) -\alpha _{i}\nu _{j}\gamma _{j}\right] }{\left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +\beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}}\right\} , \\& {1}\frac{\partial \left( \tau _{i}^{*}-\tau _{i}^{n}\right) }{\partial \beta _{j}}=\frac{\gamma _{i}+\gamma _{j}}{\left( \delta +\theta \right) }\left\{ \frac{\alpha _{j}\left[ 2\nu _{i}\left( \beta _{i}+\beta _{j}\right) +\nu _{j}\left( \alpha _{i}+2\beta _{i}\right) \right] +2\beta _{i}\nu _{j}\left( \beta _{j}-\alpha _{i}\right) +\beta _{j}^{2}\left( 2\nu _{i}+\nu _{j}\right) -\beta _{i}^{2}\left( 2\nu _{i}+3\nu _{j}\right) }{\left[ 2\alpha _{j}\beta _{i}-\left( \beta _{i}-\beta _{j}\right) ^{2}+\alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}}\right\} + \\ & \qquad \qquad \qquad \; \; \frac{1}{\left( \delta +\theta \right) }\left\{ \frac{\beta _{i}\left[ \nu _{j}\gamma _{j}\left( 2\alpha _{i}+3\beta _{i}\right) -\alpha _{j}\nu _{i}\gamma _{i}\right] }{\left[ \alpha _{i}\left( \alpha _{j}+2\beta _{j}\right) +\beta _{i}\left( 2\alpha _{j}+3\beta _{j}\right) \right] ^{2}}\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

From the above expressions, it is clear that the sign of these derivatives cannot be determined unambiguously.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Marsiglio, S., Masoudi, N. Transboundary Pollution Control and Competitiveness Concerns in a Two-Country Differential Game. Environ Model Assess 27, 105–118 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-021-09768-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-021-09768-4

Keywords

Navigation