Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How ongoing structural change creates a double dividend: outdating of technologies and green growth

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Portuguese Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we study how the ongoing transition to newer technologies, what we refer to as dynamic structural change, in a doubly-differentiated R&D-based economy can generate both higher economic growth and a slowdown of climate change, thus, creating a win-win situation known as double dividend. We first consider the unregulated decentralised economy and show that ongoing structural change can lead to lower environmental damages than the economy with a fixed structure. Next, we consider an emission tax differentiated across sectors which raises economic growth and reduces emissions in the economy. Our results indicate that promoting transition to newer technologies indeed may serve as a partial substitute to conventional abatement policy options.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. for a survey, see also the book by Greiner and Semmler (2008).

  2. the social planner problem may be formulated along the same lines as in Hart (2004) but we intentionally formulate a decentralised economy to illustrate the importance of dynamic structural change for our results even without optimal management.

  3. we omit the time argument t as long as no ambiguity arises.

  4. this is equivalent to conventional savings out of composite final good. We just reduce the hierarchy by excluding this composite output from consumption and limiting it to the special assets good, as for example in Peretto and Connolly (2007)

  5. for example, T could be interpreted as the deviation of the average surface temperature on earth from its pre-industrial level. By (10) we adopt the environmental externality influencing production rather than utility for the sake of exposition. Observe that this is fully equivalent to damages entering the utility as in Hart (2004), since \(C_{i}=Y_{i}\) relationship. In general, the model may be equivalently formulated for utility including environment rather than production, see early Gradus and Smulders (1993) for such a discussion.

  6. we follow this seminal paper in formulating vertical innovations as intermediate capital products, but depart from it in formulation of variety expansion: in our case it does not use the special human capital (research labour) and we do not include any positive spillovers, unifying the mechanics of productivity-improving and variety-enhancing innovations. The overall R&D scheme is analogous to Hori et al. (2016) but is separated from producing firms decisions and uses only assets and no labour.

  7. the physical input into R&D is the research labour of self-employed firms’ owners evaluated at the economy-wide wage rate. Since all of the income of these firms is paid back as assets returns to households, we do not include salary for this self-employed labour into the balancing equation.

  8. this can be easily modified along the lines of assuming some feedback as in Barbier (1999), but there is no empirical evidence of such a feedback.

  9. in the subsequent analysis we set \(\gamma =1\) to streamline the exposition without affecting the generality of results.

  10. observe that the form of (21) is deceptively simple: the output Y and emissions e are both composite functions of the the current structure of the economy, see further discussion in the text.

  11. as the best case scenario, this can be easily relaxed to any integrable function

  12. to obtain these last expressions we just solve ODEs \(\dot{N}_{min,max}=\delta ^{2}\pi ^{R}\) with initial conditions \(N_{min,max}(0)\) and with \(N_{min,max}(t_{min,max}(N_{0}))=N_{0}\) equalizing solutions

  13. we make use of the resource constraint (15) and capital market clearing condition \(a^{D}=a^{S}\) here

  14. although we neglect specific environment-friendly R&D and, thus, the emissions intensity is heterogeneous across sectors, but, otherwise fixed.

  15. of course, \(e_{0}\) can be set to any level between 0 and 1. This will not affect the qualitative results of the simulation.

  16. Observe that this is not the simplest tax which can be levied. The simplest tax is the uniform one and it will lead to qualitatively the same results. We prefer to stick to the original formulation of the Pigou (1920) to internalize the environmental externality.

  17. horizontal innovations have potential profits from vertical innovations as the only incentive, since the latter are increasing in i; the same is true for variety expansion.

  18. The quantity \(\epsilon\) used in this result is arbitrary small and differs from \(\varepsilon\) used throughout the paper

  19. By these we mean the comparison of models with and without dynamic turnover of technologies, see Sec. 3.1.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Bursztyn L, Hemous D (2012) The environment and directed technical change. Am Eco Rev 102(1):131–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Cao D (2015) Innovation by entrants and incumbents. J Eco Theo 157(C), 255–294

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2):323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez-Cuadrado F, Long N, Poschke M (2017) Capital-labor substitution, structural change and growth. Theo Eco 12(3)

  • Barbier E (1999) Endogenous growth and natural resource scarcity. Environ Res Eco 14(1):51–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bondarev A (2019). R&d policy in the economy with structural change and heterogeneous spillovers. Macroeconomic Dynamics (First View), 1–20. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100519000646.

  • Bondarev A, Clemens C, Greiner A (2014) Climate change and technical progress: Impact of informational constraints. In: Moser E, Semmler W, Tragler G, Veliov VM (eds) Dynamic Optimization in Environmental Economics. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg, Berlin, Heidelberg, pp 3–35

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bondarev A, Greiner A (2019) Endogenous growth and structural change through vertical and horizontal innovations. Macroecon Dyn 23(1):52–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bondarev A, Weigt H (2018) Sensitivity of energy system investments to policy regulation changes: Too many, too fast? Energy Policy 119(C), 196–205

  • Bovenberg L, Smulders S (1995) Environmental quality and pollution-augmenting technological change in a two-sector endogenous growth model. J Pub Eco 57(3):369–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bréchet T, Camacho C, Veliov VM (2014) Model predictive control, the economy, and the issue of global warming. Ann Oper Res 220(1):25–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bretschger L, Karydas C (2018) Optimum Growth and Carbon Policies with Lags in the Climate System. Environ Res Econ 70(4):781–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bretschger L, Lechthaler F, Rausch S, Zhang L (2017) Knowledge diffusion, endogenous growth, and the costs of global climate policy. Euro Eco Rev 93(C), 47–72

  • Chu AC (2011) The welfare cost of one-size-fits-all patent protection. J Econ Dyn Con 35(6):876–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feichtinger G, Hartl RF, Kort PM, Veliov VM (2005) Environmental policy, the porter hypothesis and the composition of capital: Effects of learning and technological progress. J Environ Econ Manag 50(2):434–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forster B (1973) Optimal consumption planning in a polluted environment. Eco Rec 49(4):534–545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradus R, Smulders S (1993) The trade-off between environmental care and long-term growth-pollution in three prototype growth models. J Econ 58(1):25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner A (2005) Anthropogenic climate change and abatement in a multi-region world with endogenous growth. Ecol Econ 55(2):224–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner A, Semmler W (2008) The Global Environment, Natural Resources, and Economic Growth. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grimaud A, Rouge L (2014) Carbon sequestration, economic policies and growth. Res Energy Econ 36(2):307–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halkos GE, Paizanos  EA (2016) Environmental macroeconomics: Economic growth, fiscal spending and environmental quality. Int Rev Environ Res Econ 9(3-4), 321–362

  • Hamano M, Zanetti F (2017) Endogenous product turnover and macroeconomic dynamics. Rev Econ Dyn 26:263–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart R (2004) Growth, environment and innovation– a model with production vintages and environmentally oriented research. J Environ Econ Manag 48(3), 1078–1098

  • Hori T, Mizutani N, Uchino T (2016) Endogenous structural change, aggregate balanced growth, and optimality. Econ Theo 1–29

  • Keeler E, Spence M, Zeckhauser R (1972) The optimal control of pollution. J Econ Theo 4(1):19–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kongsamut P, Rebelo S, Xie D (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Rev Econ Stud 68(4):869–882

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mäler KG (1974) Environmental Economics: A Theoretical Inquiry. John Hopkins University Press/Baltimore

  • Meckl J (2002) Structural change and generalized balanced growth. J Econ 77(3):241–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ngai LR, Pissarides CA (2007). Structural change in a multisector model of growth. Am Eco Rev 97(1), 429–443

  • Nordhaus W (2007) The challenge of global warming: economic models and environmental policy, Volume 4. Yale University

  • Peretto P (1998) Technological change and population growth. J Econ Growth 3(4):283–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peretto P, Connolly M (2007) The manhattan metaphor. J Econ Growth 12(4):329–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peretto P, Valente S (2015) Growth on a finite planet: resources, technology and population in the long run. J Econ Growth 20(3):305–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou AC (1920) The Economics of Welfare. Macmilian and Co./London

  • Reid W (1980) Sturmian Theory for Ordinary Differential Equations. Springer-Verlag/New York

  • Ricci F (2007) Environmental policy and growth when inputs are differentiated in pollution intensity. Environ Res Econ 38(3):285–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Political Econ 98(5):S71–S102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1942) Capitalism. Socialism and Democracy. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Smulders S, Gradus R (1996) Pollution abatement and long-term growth. Euro J Political Econ 12(3):505–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1998) Growth without scale effects. J Political Econ 106(1):41–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anton Bondarev.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix

Households derivations

The objective function of the household is

$$\begin{aligned} J^H=\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }{} \mathbf{e} ^{-\rho t}U(C) dt\;. \end{aligned}$$
(61)

with \(U(C)=\ln C\) being the utility function from composite consumption C consisting of the continuum of products,

$$\begin{aligned} C= \left[ \int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} C_i^\frac{\varepsilon -1}{\varepsilon }di \right] ^\frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1}\;. \end{aligned}$$
(62)

with \(1<\varepsilon <\infty\) being the elasticity of substitution between goods. All these goods are choice variables. The dynamic constraint is (86). We use the Lagrangian multiplier method to derive optimal \(C_{i}\) (this is equivalent to Hamiltonian approach in our case).

The Lagrangian of the household is

$$\begin{aligned} L= \left[ \int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} C_i^\frac{\varepsilon -1}{\varepsilon }di \right] ^\frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1} - \lambda \left( \int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_i C_i di - ra + \dot{a} + L \right) \;. \end{aligned}$$
(63)

The first order condition for consumption good i is

$$\begin{aligned} C_i^{-\frac{1}{\varepsilon }} C^{\frac{1}{\varepsilon }} = \lambda P_i\;. \end{aligned}$$
(64)

Taking the F.O.C. for i and for j and substituting in yields

$$\begin{aligned} C_i = C_j \left( \frac{P_i}{P_j}\right) ^{-\varepsilon }\;. \end{aligned}$$
(65)

Substituting this back into the equation for expenditure, Equation (6) yields

$$\begin{aligned} C_j \left( \frac{1}{P_j}\right) ^{-\varepsilon } \int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_i^{1-\varepsilon }di = E\;, \end{aligned}$$
(66)

which can be rearranged to yield

$$\begin{aligned} C_i = E \frac{P_i^{-\varepsilon }}{\int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_j^{1-\varepsilon }dj}\;. \end{aligned}$$
(67)

and the standard Euler equation implies that the optimal growth rate for expenditure is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{E}}{E} = r-\rho \;. \end{aligned}$$
(68)

Production sector derivations

Output of good i is given by (10):

$$\begin{aligned} Y_i=\frac{1}{1+T}A_{i}^{\alpha } L^{Y}_{i}\;. \end{aligned}$$
(69)

where \(0<\alpha <1\) is the productivity of technology in production. The maximization problem of firm i is

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{P_{i}}\Pi _i = P_i Y_i - L^{Y}_i - \Psi \;, \end{aligned}$$
(70)

where \(\Psi\) is a fixed operating cost (in labour units).

The only use for output of all goods i is consumption, so that \(C_i=Y_i\). The only product used for investments is financial capital a and is excluded from this spectrum.

The output by an individual firm \(Y_i\) equals to the consumption of that good \(C_i\), so that we can insert Equation (67) into the profit function:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _i= & {} P_i Y_i - L^{Y}_i - \Psi \end{aligned}$$
(71)
$$\begin{aligned}= & {} P_i Y_i -Y_i A_i^{-\alpha }(1+T) - \Psi \end{aligned}$$
(72)
$$\begin{aligned}= & {} P_iE \frac{P_i^{-\varepsilon }}{\int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_j^{1-\varepsilon }dj} - E(1+T) \frac{P_i^{-\varepsilon }}{\int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_j^{1-\varepsilon }dj} A_i^{-\alpha } - \Psi \end{aligned}$$
(73)

The baseline model is obtained by letting \(T=0\) above.

We use further the assumption of zero mass of each individual product in the price index, (9) which is usual when the continuum of goods is employed.

Maximizing profit with respect to the price under this non-atomic assumption yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _i}{\partial P_i} = \frac{E}{\int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_j^{1-\varepsilon }dj} (1-\varepsilon ) P_i^{-\varepsilon } -(1+T) \frac{E}{\int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}} P_j^{1-\varepsilon }dj} P_i^{-\varepsilon -1} (-\varepsilon ) A_i^{-\alpha } = 0\;. \end{aligned}$$
(74)

The price is thus

$$\begin{aligned} P_i = \frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1} (1+T)A_i^{-\alpha }\;. \end{aligned}$$
(75)

All products out of the range \(N_{max}-N_{min}\) have zero prices:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{i}={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 0,\,t<t_{max}(i), t_{max}(i): \Pi _i= 0, \dot{\Pi _i}>0;\\ (1+T)\frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1} A_i^{-\alpha },\, t_{max}(i)<t\le t_{min}(i),t_{min}(i): \Pi _i=0, \dot{\Pi _i}<0;\\ 0, t>t_{min}(i). \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(76)

Labour employed in sector i is thus a sum of fixed costs and a function of the relative productivity of labour in sector i. Repeating arguments being made for the price formation we have piecewise-defined labour demand:

$$\begin{aligned} L^{D}(i)={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 0,\, t<t_{max}(i),t_{max}(i): \Pi _i= 0, \dot{\Pi _i}>0;\\ \frac{\varepsilon -1}{\varepsilon }E\frac{A_{i}^{-\alpha (1-\varepsilon )}}{\int \limits _{{N_{min}}}^{N_{max}}A_{j}^{-\alpha (1-\varepsilon )}dj}+\Psi ,\, t_{max}(i)<t\le t_{min}(i),t_{min}(i): \Pi _i=0, \dot{\Pi _i}<0;\\ 0, t>t_{min}(i). \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(77)

where \(\Psi\) is production-independent part of labour demand.

The patent for each new technology has a price

$$\begin{aligned}&p_{A}(i)\overset{def}{=}\int \limits _{t_{max}}^{t_{min}}\mathrm {e}^{-r(t-t_{max})}\Pi _{i}dt. \end{aligned}$$
(78)

which does not depend on time (only on integration limits). To see this, substitute for profits from (71,72,73), prices from (76), labour from (77). All these are functions of time. However once we integrate over the time period \(t_{max}\) to \(t_{min}\) the patent price becomes a function of \(t_{max}(i), t_{min}(i)\) only and thus for each i it is a given quantity, albeit varying across technologies.

The markets clearing implies constant expenditures as long as \(\mathcal {O}\) is constant:

$$\begin{aligned} E(t) &=& \int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N}P(i,t)C(i,t)di{\mathop {=}\limits ^{(76)}}\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}(1+T)\frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1} A_i^{-\alpha }Y(i,t)di{\mathop {=}\limits ^{(10)}}\nonumber \\ &= & {} \frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1}\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}L^{Y}(i,t)di= \frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1}(L-\mathcal {O}\Psi ). \end{aligned}$$
(79)

R&D derivations

The incentive for horizontal innovation is the potential profit from selling the (improved) technology to manufacturing firms. Thus, the value of horizontal R&D consists solely in expected future profits from vertical innovations:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{N}=\max _{u(\cdot )}\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }\mathrm {e}^{-rt}\left( \delta \pi ^{R}(i)|_{i=N} u(t)-\frac{1}{2}u^{2}(t)\right) dt \end{aligned}$$
(80)

Here profit of developing next technology \(i=N\) is the value of vertical innovation into technology i, which is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^{R}(i)|_{i=N}=p_{A}(N)-\frac{1}{2}\int \limits _{t_{0}(N)}^{t_{min}(N)}\mathrm {e}^{-r(t-t_{0})}g^{2}(N,t)dt. \end{aligned}$$
(81)

with g(Nt) being investments costs of developing technology N during the patent duration.

The HJB equation for the problem given by (80), (17) is:

$$\begin{aligned} rV=\max _{u(\cdot )}\left\{ \delta \pi ^{R}(i)|_{i=N} u(t)-\frac{1}{2}u^{2}(t)+\frac{\partial V}{\partial N}\delta u(t)\right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(82)

Taking F.O.C. we have

$$\begin{aligned} u^{*}=\delta \pi ^{R}(i)|_{i=N}+\delta \frac{\partial V}{\partial N}. \end{aligned}$$
(83)

Substituting back into the HJB equation, we find that it can be satisfied only for \(V=const\), as long as \(\pi ^{R}(i,t)|_{i=N}\) is constant.

This last has to be constant, since there is a free entry condition for vertical innovations: if some of the technologies yielded higher profits, all of the resources would go into the development of only those more profitable technologies. However, the investments are symmetric, thus, requiring constant and equal profits across technologies. Hence, we have

$$\begin{aligned} u^{*}=\delta \pi ^{R}(i)|_{i=N}=\delta \pi ^{R} \end{aligned}$$
(84)

yielding (28).

The profit of the single R&D firm developing technology i is:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^{R}(i)=p_{A}(i)-\frac{1}{2}\int \limits _{t_{0}}^{t_{min}}\mathrm {e}^{-r(t-t_{0})}g^{2}(i,t)dt. \end{aligned}$$
(85)

with investments going into increase of productivity:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{A}(i,t)=\gamma g(i,t)-\beta A(i,t). \end{aligned}$$
(86)

where \(\gamma\) is the efficiency of investments into productivity increase (equal for all sectors) and \(\beta\) is the cost of supporting the productivity on the current level (this abstracts infrastructure and human capital, required for reproduction of the current level of technology).

The aggregate problem for vertical R&D reads:

$$\begin{aligned} V=\max _{g}\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }e^{-rt}dt\int \limits _{N_{min}(t)}^{N(t)}p_{A}(i)di-\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }e^{-rt}\int \limits _{N_{min}(t)}^{N(t)}\frac{1}{2}g^{2}(i,t)di dt;\end{aligned}$$
(87)
$$\begin{aligned} s.t.\end{aligned}$$
(88)
$$\begin{aligned} \forall i\in [N_{min},N]\subset \mathbb {R}_{+}: \dot{A}(i,t)=\gamma g(i,t)-\beta A(t)\end{aligned}$$
(89)
$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{N_{min}(t)}^{N(t)}g(i,t)di=a(t)-u{\mathop {=}\limits ^{def}}G(t). \end{aligned}$$
(90)

Implementing Maximum Principle approach, we derive optimal investments for each R&D firm as a function of shadow costs of investments, \(\psi (i,t)\), this last being the function of price of the patent:

$$\begin{aligned}&\dot{\psi }(i,t)=r\psi (i,t)-\frac{\partial p_{A}(i)}{\partial A(i)},\nonumber \\&g^{*}(i,t)=\gamma \psi (i,t)-\frac{\int \limits _{N_{min}(t)}^{N(t)}\gamma \psi (i,t)di-G(t)}{N(t)-N_{min}(t)}. \end{aligned}$$
(91)

it may be demonstrated, that shadow costs of investments are the same across all existing technologies:

$$\begin{aligned} \psi ^{*}(i,t)=\psi ^{*}=\frac{\frac{\partial p_{A}(i)}{\partial A(i)}}{r+\beta } \end{aligned}$$
(92)

with \(\frac{\partial p_{A}(i)}{\partial A(i)}=const\) by homogeneity of technologies (see Bondarev and Greiner (2019) for detailed proof). Combining (91) and (92) yields (35).

Dynamics of productivities themselves differ by the depreciation rate:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{A}(i,t)=\frac{a(t)-u}{N(t)-N_{min}(t)}-\beta A(i,t). \end{aligned}$$
(93)

with u given by (28) and a(t) being the solution of (38).

Constant core derivation

The fact that the size of the economy is constant follows from definitions of \(N_{min}\), \(N_{max}\)

$$\begin{aligned}&N_{min}(t):\, \frac{1}{\varepsilon -1}(L-\mathcal {O}\Psi )\frac{A_{N_{min}}^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}}{\int \limits _{{N_{min}}}^{N_{max}}A_{j}^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj}-\Psi =0; \end{aligned}$$
(94)

and

$$\begin{aligned}&N_{max}(t): \frac{1}{\varepsilon -1}(L-\mathcal {O}\Psi )\frac{A_{N_{max}}^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}}{\int \limits _{{N_{min}}}^{N_{max}}A_{j}^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj}-\Psi =0; \end{aligned}$$
(95)

Now observe that maximum profit for any sector i is reached at the point of \(\dot{\Pi }(i)=0\). Then it follows, that growth of \(N_{min}\) and \(N_{max}\) is equal:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{\Pi }(i)=0 \Leftrightarrow \left( \frac{\dot{A}(i,t)}{A(i,t)}-\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}\frac{\dot{A}(j,t)}{A(j,t)}dj\right) =\frac{\Psi }{\alpha L} (\dot{N}_{max}-\dot{N}_{min}) \end{aligned}$$
(96)

However, bracket in the lefthandside has to be equal to zero, since it equalizes growth rate of productivity of sector i and average growth rate of productivity in the economy. Since all the technologies are symmetric except for the time of their invention, it is straightforward to say that maximum profit for the given industry is reached at the point where its productivity grows at the average rate of the economy. Otherwise there will be still room for improvements of technology or the technology is already overdeveloped. From this it follows that \(\dot{N}_{max}-\dot{N}_{min}=0\) yielding constant range of operational sectors in the economy, \(\mathcal {O}=const\).

Growth rate of the benchmark economy

We start with the observation that (94) and (95) lead to

$$\begin{aligned} \forall i\in [N_{min},N_{max}]:\frac{A(i,t_{max}(i))^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}}{A(i,t_{min}(i))^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}}=\frac{{\int \limits _{N_{min}(t_{max}(i))}^{N_{max}(t_{max}(i))}A(j,t_{max}(i))}^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj}{{\int \limits _{N_{min}(t_{min}(i))}^{N_{max}(t_{min}(i))}A(j,t_{min}(i))}^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj}. \end{aligned}$$
(97)

Thus all technologies’ productivities grow at the same average speed during the time period of operational activity of the technology,

$$\begin{aligned} \forall i \in [N_{min},N_{max}], \forall t\in [t_{max}(i),t_{min}(i)]:\dot{A}=\frac{a-u}{N-N_{min}}. \end{aligned}$$
(98)

To obtain output growth rate consider aggregate output:

$$\begin{aligned} Y=\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}\left( \frac{A(i,t)^{\alpha \varepsilon }}{\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(j,t)^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}}\right) di=\frac{\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(i,t)^{\alpha \varepsilon }di}{\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(j,t)^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj} \end{aligned}$$
(99)

The direct calculation of output growth rates from (99) yields with the help of (98):

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\dot{Y}}{Y}=\frac{\dot{\left( \int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(i,t)^{\alpha \varepsilon }di\right) }}{\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(i,t)^{\alpha \varepsilon }di}-\frac{\dot{\left( \int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(j,t)^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj\right) }}{\int \limits _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}A(j,t)^{\alpha (\varepsilon -1)}dj}{\mathop {=}\limits ^{\dot{N}_{min}=\dot{N}_{max}}}\alpha \frac{a-u}{N-N_{min}}\frac{N_{max}-N_{min}}{\bar{A}}\nonumber \\&= \alpha \frac{\dot{\bar{A}}}{\bar{A}}(N_{max}-N_{min})>0. \end{aligned}$$
(100)

Proof of Lemma 3

Total expenditures of households are unchanged for given \(N_{min},N_{max}\):

$$\begin{aligned} E^{\tau }=\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}P^{\tau }_{i}C^{\tau }_{i}di=\frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}L^{Y}_{i}di \end{aligned}$$
(101)

Tax revenues coming to households are:

$$\begin{aligned} R{\mathop {=}\limits ^{def}}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{1}{i}P^{\tau }_{i}Y^{\tau }_{i}di{\mathop {=}\limits ^{(52),(53)}}\frac{\epsilon }{\epsilon -1}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{1}{i}L^{Y}_{i}di \end{aligned}$$
(102)

Rearranging terms we get

$$\begin{aligned} R-E^{\tau }=\frac{\epsilon }{\epsilon -1}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{1-i}{i}L^{Y}_{i}di \end{aligned}$$
(103)

Further using

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}L^{\tau }_{i}di=\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{i-1}{i}L^{Y}_{i}di=\nonumber \\&\frac{\epsilon }{\epsilon -1}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{i-1}{i}L^{Y}_{i}di-\frac{1}{\epsilon -1}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{i-1}{i}L^{Y}_{i}di \end{aligned}$$
(104)

and accounting for (52), (53) we get from (59)

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{a}^{\tau }=ra^{\tau }-\frac{1}{\epsilon -1}\int _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}\frac{i-1}{i}L^{Y}_{i}di \end{aligned}$$
(105)

Observe now that both (103) and the second term of (105) are positive or negative simultaneously depending on whether \(N_{max}\le 1\) (both positive) or \(N_{min}\ge 1\) (both negative).

It remains to observe that since both \(N_{min}, N_{max}\) are monotonic, these are exactly the only two regimes for assets dynamics.

Since the size of the economy increases in time, the actual expenditures change by

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta E= E^{\tau }-E=\frac{\varepsilon }{\varepsilon -1}\left( \int \limits _{N^{\tau }_{min}}^{N^{\tau }_{max}}L^{Y}_{i}-\int _{N_{min}}^{N_{max}}L^{Y}_{i}di\right) >0 \end{aligned}$$
(106)

because the size of the core increases and \(N^{\tau }_{max}>N_{max},N^{\tau }_{min}>N_{min}\) holds.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bondarev, A., Greiner, A. How ongoing structural change creates a double dividend: outdating of technologies and green growth. Port Econ J 21, 125–160 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-021-00196-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-021-00196-6

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation