Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Do women face a glass ceiling at home? The division of household labor among dual-earner couples

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we use data on mixed-gender dual-earner couples in Southern and Western Europe to investigate how the division of unpaid household labor within mixed-gender couples varies depending on the ratio of the partners’ market wages. From analysis of the EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions, we first show that married or cohabiting women do twice as much household work as single women with the same income. Furthermore, women’s time spent in home production does not vary in relation to the couple’s relative wages in Southern Europe. We find a positive elasticity of substitution between male and female labor in home production with respect to their relative within-couple wages in Western Europe. Our identification is based on predicting each country’s wage distributions within gender-specific cells defined by age group and education using distributions in all the other countries. We present a positive evidence for presence of a “second-shift” that women face especially in Southern Europe, which may stem from regional gender norms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1: Ranking of all countries in the EVS according to the GVI.
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Source: Authors’ computations based on EU-SILC data.

  2. Source: Authors’ computations based on EVS (2016).

  3. Examples of such research include Bisin & Verdier (2001), Alesina & Fuchs-Schündeln (2007), Doepke & Zilibotti (2008), Roland (2010), and Voigtländer & Voth (2012).

  4. Our definition of “wages” includes earned income from both employment and self-employment, divided by number of hours worked. We include the self-employment income in the numerator, because it can be viewed as primarily labor income rather than capital income. The data also contains separate information on capital income, which does not enter our definition.

  5. As discussed further in Section 3, we define marriage markets by age and education.

  6. We discuss pros and cons of our instrumental variable in Section 3.

  7. In this paper, we include childcare and caring for other dependent household or family members together with cleaning, shopping and similar activities in the definition of household work.

  8. These statistics approximately correspond to various European time use surveys (Charmes, 2015)

  9. We cannot use the HETUS as the main source in our analysis, because it contains only income from the main activity. Moreover, the income is interval-coded. Both of these factors increase the measurement error. Moreover, the first factor causes a downward systemic bias in the income estimates.

  10. The EVS is a research program that collects data on individuals’ attitudes, beliefs and opinions about various social, economic, and political issues.

  11. For an introduction to the principal component analysis, or PCA, see e.g. Jackson (2003).

  12. For instance, strong agreement with the first statement, “It is important to share household work in marriage”, which is coded as “1” changes the value of the index for a given answerer by 1 × − 0.05 = −0.05. On the other hand, strong disagreement with this statement (coded as “4”) contributes to the index by 4 × −0.05 = −0.2. Alternatively, strong agreement with the statement “Pre-school child suffers with working mother”, changes the value of the index for a given person by 1 × 0.553 = 0.553, while strong disagreement with the said statement modifies the index by 4 × 0.553 = 2.212.

  13. The ISCO (International Standard Classification of Occupations) is a classification system for jobs maintained by the International Labour Organization.

  14. The method of k-means clustering aims to partition observations into k clusters in which each observation belongs to the cluster with the nearest mean of the GVI, serving as a prototype of the cluster. In effect, it minimizes within-cluster variances, so it creates clusters based on closeness of the observations to each other. In our case k = 2. For a more detailed discussion of this method, see e.g. Hastie et al. (2009)

  15. These graphs do not control for the fact that married or cohabitating women are more likely than single women to have children. Their purpose is to illustrate differences between West and South.

  16. Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics or NUTS (French: Nomenclature des unités territoriales statistiques) is a geocode standard for referencing the subdivisions of countries for statistical purposes developed and regulated by the European Union.

  17. The NUTS-1 level consists of five geographical units: Northwest Italy, Northeast Italy, Central Italy, South Italy, and Insular Italy. Each NUTS-1 unit is composed of groups of traditional Italian regions. For example, Northwest Italy contains regions Piemonte, Valle d’Aosta, Liguria, and Lombardia, which are classified as NUTS-2 level. For our purposes, we classified Northwest, Northeast and Central Italy as ‘North’, and South and Insular Italy as ‘South’.

  18. We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.

  19. Notably, we take a different modeling approach from Grossbard-Shechtman (1984) who also considers two types of work and allows for individual supply and demand schedules of the spouses, which leads to interesting interdependence. In contrast, even though a household is composed of two spouses in our model, it is ultimately a single economic unit. Because of our static empirical setting our simple model also abstracts from marriage and divorce choices.

  20. We recognize the endogeneity associated with joint income, so we instrument it analogously to the relative wages.

  21. Ventiles are points that divide an ordered distribution into 20 equally-sized parts, similarly to how a median divides it into two equally sized parts.

  22. NACE (French: Nomenclature statistique des activités économiques dans la Communauté européenne — The Statistical Classification of Economic Activities in the European Community) is the industry classification system used in the European Union. NACE uses four hierarchical levels: Level 1, which contains 21 sections identified by alphabetical letters A to U; Level 2 with 88 divisions identified by two-digit numerical codes (01 to 99), Level 3 containing 272 groups identified by three-digit numerical codes (01.1 to 99.0), and Level 4 that consists of 615 classes identified by four-digit numerical codes (01.11 to 99.00). Examples of Level 2 codes include “Crop and animal production, hunting and related service activities”, or “Manufacture of textiles”.

  23. As a robustness check we drop the joint earnings from the analysis. The omission does not significantly change the coefficients of interest. The results of this robustness check are available upon request.

  24. The results are robust to the inclusion of Bulgaria and Romania from the sample.

  25. See e.g. Hurst, Li & Pugsley (2014) or Lichard et al. (2019)

  26. This argument has been also made in the case of differences between macro and micro estimates of labor supply elasticities. See, for example, Chetty, Guren, Manoli & Weber (2011) or Peterman (2016).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Autor, D. H., & Lyle, D. (2004). Women, war, and wages: the effect of female labor supply on the wage structure at midcentury. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 497–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2013). On the origins of gender roles: women and the plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128, 469–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2011). Fertility and the plough. The American Economic Review, 101, 499–503

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Fuchs-Schündeln, N. (2007). Good-bye Lenin (or not?): the effect of communism on people’s preferences. American Economic Review, 97, 1507–1528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Álvarez, B., & Miles-Touya, D. (2019). Gender imbalance in housework allocation: a question of time? Review of Economics of the Household, 17, 1257–1287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartik, T.J. (1991) Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies? Kalamazoo, Mich, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research

  • Bertrand, M., Kamenica, E., & Pan, J. (2015). Gender identity and relative income within households. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130, 571–614

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Cortés, P., Olivetti, C. & Pan, J. (2016) Social norms, labor market opportunities, and the marriage gap for skilled women. Working Paper 22015, NBER

  • Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2017). The gender wage gap: extent, trends, and explanations. Journal of Economic Literature, 55, 789–865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borra, C., Browning, M., & Sevilla Sanz, A. (2017). Marriage and housework. Discussion Paper 10740, IZA

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2001). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 97, 298–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charmes, J. (2015) Time use across the world: findings of a world compilation of time use surveys. Background Paper, UNDP Human Development Report Office

  • Chetty, R., Guren, A., Manoli, D., & Weber, A. (2011). Are micro and macro labor supply elasticities consistent? A review of evidence on the intensive and extensive margins. American Economic Review, 101, 471–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cortés, P., & Pan, J. (2019). When time binds: substitutes for household production, returns to working long hours, and the skilled gender wage gap. Journal of Labor Economics, 37, 351–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de V. Cavalcanti, T. V., & Tavares, J. (2008). Assessing the “Engines of liberation”: home appliances and female labor force participation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90, 81–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Laat, J., & Sevilla-Sanz, A. (2011). The fertility and women’s labor force participation puzzle in OECD countries: the role of men’s home production. Feminist Economics, 17, 87–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2008). Occupational choice and the spirit of capitalism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123, 747–793

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domínguez-Folgueras, M. (2013). Is cohabitation more egalitarian? The division of household labor in five European countries. Journal of Family Issues, 34, 1623–1646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EVS. European Values Study 2008: Integrated Dataset (EVS 2008). Cologne, GESIS Data Archive (2016)

  • Garcia Roman, J., & Cortina, C. (2016). Family time of couples with children: shortening gender differences in parenting? Review of Economics of the Household, 14, 921–940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., Seshadri, A., & Yorukoglu, M. (2005). Engines of liberation. The Review of Economic Studies, 72, 109–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, A. (1984). A theory of allocation of time in markets for labour and marriage. The Economic Journal, 94, 863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith-Pinkham, P. (2018) Sorkin, I. & Swift, H. Bartik instruments: What, when, why and how. Working Paper 24408, NBER

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in financial development. The American Economic Review, 94, 526–556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastie, T., Tibshirani, R. & Friedman, J. (2009). The elements of statistical learning: data mining, inference, and prediction. Springer Series in Statistics (2nd ed.) New York, Springer-Verlag

  • Hamermesh, D.S. (1996). Labor Demand. Princeton University Press

  • Hurst, E., Li, G., & Pugsley, B. (2014). Are household surveys like tax forms? Evidence from income underreporting of the self-employed. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 96, 19–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichino, A., Olsson, M., Petrongolo, B. & Thoursie, P.S. (2019) Economic incentives, home production and gender identity norms. Discussion Paper 12391, IZA

  • Ichino, A., & Maggi, G. (2000). Work environment and individual background: explaining regional shirking differentials in a large Italian firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1057–1090

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, J.E. (2003). A User’s Guide to Principal Components. Hoboken, NJ, John Wiley & Sons

  • Johnson, M., & Keane, M. P. (2013). A dynamic equilibrium model of the US wage structure, 1968–1996. Journal of Labor Economics, 31, 1–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleven, H., Landais, C., & Søgaard, J. E. (2019). Children and gender inequality: evidence from Denmark. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 11, 181–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Knowles, J. A. (2012). Why are married men working so much? An aggregate analysis of intra-household bargaining and labor supply. Review of Economic Studies, 80, 1055–1085

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichard, T., Hanousek, J. & Filer, R. K. (2021). Hidden in plain sight: using household data to measure the shadow economy. Empirical Economics, 60, 1449–1476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (1996). Bargaining and distribution in marriage. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, 139–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lomazzi, V. (2017). Gender role attitudes in Italy: 1988–2008. A path-dependency story of traditionalism. European Societies, 19, 370–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lippmann, Q., Georgieff, A., & Senik, C. (2020). Undoing gender with institutions: lessons from the German division and reunification. The Economic Journal, 130, 1445–1470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lise, J., & Yamada, K. (2019). Household sharing and commitment: evidence from panel data on individual expenditures and time use. The Review of Economic Studies, 86, 2184–2219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pahl, J. (1983). The allocation of money and the structuring of inequality within marriage. The Sociological Review, 31, 237–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterman, W. B. (2016). Reconciling micro and macro estimates of the Frisch labor supply elasticity. Economic Inquiry, 54, 100–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roland, G. (2010) The long-run weight of communism or the weight of long-run history? Working Paper 2010/83, UNU-WIDER

  • Rogerson, R., & Wallenius, J. (2019). Household time use among older couples: evidence and implications for labor supply parameters. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134, 1079–1120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sevilla-Sanz, A., Gimenez-Nadal, J. I., & Fernández, C. (2010). Gender roles and the division of unpaid work in Spanish households. Feminist Economics, 16, 137–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigtländer, N. & Voth, H. (2012). Persecution perpetuated: the medieval origins of anti-semitic violence in Nazi Germany. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 1339–1392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinberg, B. A. (2000). Computer use and the demand for female workers. ILR Review, 53, 290–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West, C., & Zimmerman, D. H. (1987). Doing Gender. Gender & Society, 1, 125–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We offer our sincere thanks to David Card, Matias Cortes, Christian Dustmann, Hilary Hoynes, Andrea Ichino, Stěpán Jurajda, Klára Kalíšková, Shelly Lundberg, Vincenzo Merella, Nikolas Mittag, Barbara Pertold-Gębicka, and conference participants at the 2019 SOLE annual meeting for insightful comments and fruitful discussions. We are also grateful to the editor and three anonymous referees for suggestions that substantially improved the paper. Any remaining errors and omissions are the sole responsibility of the authors. TL gratefully acknowledges the support of the Czech Science Foundation, grant number 20-12023S. FP is thankful for the support of the Czech Science Foundation, grant number 17-09119Y. He worked on this research while being employed on Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Filip Pertold.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Gender values index

Fig. 9, Fig. 10, Table A.1

Fig. 9
figure 9

Distribution of GVI in the EVS data

Fig. 10
figure 10

Distribution of GVI in the EU-SILC

Table A.1 Determinants of the GVI

Descriptive statistics

Table B.1, Table B.2.

Table B.1 Household work in hours per week of working and nonworking couples
Table B.2 Descriptive statistics of the analyzed sample

First stage and robustness check

The following tables show first stage regressions for 2SLS estimations in Table 5. We have three endogenous variables in each specification in Table 5 that need to be instrumented. For example, in the specification with the interaction with the progressive dummy, we instrument the hourly-wage gap, the hourly-wage gap interacted with the progressive dummy, and monthly household-wage relative to the median in a given country. We construct an instrument based on the methodology described in Section 3 for all these variables. The instrument for the hourly-wage gap is the difference between the logarithm of predicted hourly-wage of the man minus the logarithm of the predicted hourly-wage of the woman. The instrument for interaction terms are the predicted hourly-wage gaps times the respective dummy. Finally, monthly household wage relative to the median are instrumented by the sum of male and female predicted monthly-wage. Table C.1, Table C.2, Table C.3, Table C.4, Table C.5

Table C.1 First stage regression—progressive interaction
Table C.2 First stage regression—college female interaction
Table C.3 First stage regression—college male interaction
Table C.4 First stage regression—South interaction
Table C.5 Robustness check: elasticity of substitution in home production—wage and salary workers without self-employed

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lichard, T., Pertold, F. & Škoda, S. Do women face a glass ceiling at home? The division of household labor among dual-earner couples. Rev Econ Household 19, 1209–1243 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-021-09558-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-021-09558-7

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation