Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal contract under double moral hazard and limited liability

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates optimal contracts between risk-neutral parties when both exert efforts and the agent faces limited liability. We identify a sufficient and necessary condition for any contract to implement the second-best outcome, i.e., the best possible outcome in double moral hazard even when the agent faces unlimited liability. It is shown that a simple share-or-nothing with bonus contract (SonBo for short) is optimal and implements the second-best outcome when the condition holds. SonBo contracts have one degree of freedom, which is very useful in dealing with heterogeneous circumstances while still maintaining consistency in contracting. SonBo admits as special cases the option-like and step bonus contracts, which are widely used in dealing with limited liability. Nevertheless, we demonstrate that a step bonus contract is more powerful because an option-like contract can be problematic in some situations. The paper also discusses the performance of SonBo when the principal also faces liability constraint and investigates the optimal contract when the second-best outcome is not achievable.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Not applicable.

Code availability

Not applicable.

Notes

  1. Franchise laws in most states are primarily concerned with termination, renewal and transfer of franchise rights, but Washington, Michigan, Indiana, and Iowa go well beyond these requirements. States may differ substantially even in the definition of key elements such as franchise fees (Pitegoff Thomas and Michael Garner 2008). In response, franchisors headquartered in states that restrict termination or renew rights usually charge significantly higher royalty rates and lower franchise fees than franchisors in other states (Brickley 2002).

  2. In a live-or-die contract, the agent’s compensation is zero when the output is below a threshold, jumps at the threshold by an amount that equals the threshold output level, and increases with output one-for-one. In SonBo, the agent’s compensation is zero when the output is below a threshold, but the jump at the threshold and the slope beyond the threshold are endogenously and jointly determined.

  3. Compared with the more general specification of f(x|ae), the introduction of composite effort simplifies the analysis. Most studies including Romano (1994), Kim and Wang (1998), Wang and Zhu (2005), and Suzuki (2007) adopt the composite effort.

  4. To simplify notations, we use \(h_{e}\), \(h_{a}\), f(x|h), \(f_{h}(x|h)\), F(x|h), \(F_{h}(x|h)\), v(a), \(v^{\prime }(a)\), c(e), \(c^{\prime }(e)\) to refer to functions evaluated at general values a and e, and will be specific when a or e takes the second-best level.

  5. The reason why \((a^{*},e^{*})\) is not the first-best can be understood from the perspective of team production. Double moral hazard problem is essentially team production, with one team member being chosen as the principal and residual claimant (Suzuki 2007). The impossibility of achieving the first-best outcome is related to balancing-budget problem studied by Hölmstrom (1982). No matter what the output is, the sum of the principal’s payment and the agent’s payment is always equal to the whole output. As Hölmstrom (1982) shows, team production with balancing-budget condition cannot achieve the first-best outcome.

  6. The intuition is that \((a^{*},e^{*})\) satisfies Eq. (6), which is the sum of agent-IC and principal-IC. This means that if a contract gives the agent a part of the output such that the agent would choose \(e^{*}\), the remaining output must induce the principal to choose \(a^{*}\).

  7. Refer to Section 4 of online appendix for the proof of \(\lim _{{\widehat{x}} \rightarrow {\overline{x}}}\gamma ^{*}({\widehat{x}})=-\infty \). This conclusion serves as a necessary technical condition to prove Proposition 3.

  8. Suppose \((a^{*},e^{*})\) are optimal for the new problem. Based on agent-PC and agent-IC, we have

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \,dx}{\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }w(x)f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{ c\left( e^{*}\right) +{\overline{U}}_{e}+R}. \end{aligned}$$

    Since the left hand side is not greater than \(\frac{f_{h}({\overline{x}} |h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\), we have \(\frac{f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}+R}\), which violates the fact that \(\frac{f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}<\frac{ c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}+R}\) for \(R<{\widehat{R}}\).

  9. Refer to Section 6 of the Online Appendix for the proof of Proposition 5.

  10. Refer to Section 5 of the Online Appendix for the proof.

  11. This is because \(\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))\,dx=1\), we can have \(\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\frac{ f_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}{f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))\,dx=0\). Due to MLRP, we conclude that there exists a \(x_{0}\in ({\underline{x}},{\overline{x}})\) such that \(\frac{f_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}{f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}<0\) for \(x<x_{0} \), \(\frac{ f_{h}(x_{0}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}{f(x_{0}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}=0\), and \(\frac{f_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}{f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}>0\) for \(x>x_{0}\). So \(f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))>0\) and the result of the limit problem is valid.

References

  • Bhattacharyya S, Lafontaine F (1995) Double-sided moral hazard and the nature of share contracts. Rand J Econ 26(4):761–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley JA (2002) Royalty rates and upfront fees in share contracts: evidence from franchising. J Law Econ Organ 18(2):511–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griva K, Vettas N (2015) On two-part tariff competition in a homogeneous product duopoly. Int J Ind Organ 41:30–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hölmstrom B (1982) Moral hazard in teams. ACA Trans 13(2):324–340

    Google Scholar 

  • Innes RD (1990) Limited liability and incentive contracting with ex-ante action choices. J Econ Theory 52(1):45–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jewitt I (1988) Justifying the first-order approach to principal-agent problems. Econometrica 56(5):1177–1190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jewitt I, Kadan O, Swinkels JM (2008) Moral hazard with bounded payments. J Econ Theory 143(1):59–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kadan O, Swinkels JM (2013) Minimum payments and induced effort in moral hazard problems. Games Econ Behav 82:468–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim SK (1997) Limited liability and bonus contracts. J Econ Manag Strategy 6(4):899–913

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim SK, Wang S (1998) Linear contracts and the double moral-hazard. J Econ Theory 82(2):342–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom PR (1981) Good news and bad news: representation theorems and applications. Bell J Econ 12(2):380–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park E-S (1995) Incentive contracting under limited liability. J Econ Manag Strategy 4(3):477–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitegoff TM, Michael GW (eds) (2008) Fundamentals of franchising. American Bar Association

  • Poblete J, Spulber D (2012) The form of incentive contracts: agency with moral hazard, risk neutrality, and limited liability. Rand J Econ 43(2):215–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson WP (1985) The first-order approach to principal-agent problems. Econometrica 53(6):1357–1367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romano RE (1994) Double moral hazard and resale price maintenance. Rand J Econ 25(2):455–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzuki Y (2007) Commitment problem, optimal incentive schemes, and relational contracts in agency with bilateral moral hazard. J Int Econ Stud 21:103–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang S, Zhu T (2005) Control allocation, revenue sharing, and joint ownership. Int Econ Rev 46(3):895–915

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research is sponsored by Shanghai Pujiang Program (2019PJC007) and National Natural Science Foundation of China (Project 72003035). We would like to thank Wing Suen, Steve Xu, Yujing Xu, and seminar participants at the University of Hong Kong and Nanjing Audit University for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Solve the optimal contract under double moral hazard and limited liability for the first time in the literature.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jiajia Cong.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

No conflicts of interest need to be disclosed.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 261 KB)

Appendix

Appendix

This appendix collects the proofs of Propositions 1 and 2 in the paper. The proof of Proposition 5 is similar with the proof of Proposition 1 and Proposition 2 if we treat the agent’s outside option as \( {\overline{U}}_e+R_b\). Its proof is in the Section 6 of the Online Appendix.

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Name \(\eta ^{*}=B-\gamma ^{*}{\widehat{x}}\). Then \(w^{*}(x)=\gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\) when \(x\ge {\widehat{x}}\). Next, we prove the SonBo contract \(w^{*}(x)\) can make agent-IC, principal-IC and agent-PC hold at the second-best effort levels \((a^{*},e^{*})\).

Step 1: Agent-IC holds

In this section, we prove the contract \(w^{*}(x)\) can make agent-IC hold. Given the principal chooses \(a^{*}\), the marginal expected compensation of agent choosing effort \(e\in R_{+}\) divided by \(h_{e}(a^{*},e)\) is:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e\right) \right) \,dx \\&=\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) F_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e))\Big |_{ \widehat{x }}^{{\overline{x}}}-\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\gamma ^{*}F_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e\right) \right) \,dx \\&=-B\cdot F_{h}\left( {\widehat{x}}|h\left( a^{*},e\right) \right) -\frac{\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }+B\cdot F_{h}\left( {\widehat{x}} |h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) }{-\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }F_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}F_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e\right) \right) \,dx. \end{aligned}$$

The above equations hold because \(F_{h}({\overline{x}}|h)=0\) and \(\gamma ^{*}{\widehat{x}}+\eta ^{*}=B\). When \(e=e^{*}\), the above expression is equal to \(\frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}\), implying agent-IC holds.

Step 2: Principal-IC holds

Given the agent chooses \(e^{*}\), the marginal expected compensation of principal choosing \(a\in R_{+}\) divided by \(h_{a}(a,e^{*})\) is:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\widehat{x}}}xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a,e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx+\int _{ {\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left[ \left( 1-\gamma ^{*}\right) x-\eta ^{*}\right] f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a,e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx \nonumber \\&\quad =\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a,e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx+\frac{ \frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }+B\cdot F_{h}\left( {\widehat{x}}|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) }{\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }F_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}\cdot \int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{ {\overline{x}} }xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a,e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx\nonumber \\&\quad -\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\eta ^{*}f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a,e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

To prove \(w^{*}(x)\) induces principal to choose \(a^{*}\), we need to prove Eq. (20) is equal to \(\frac{ v^{\prime }(a^{*})}{h_{a}(a^{*},e^{*})}\) when principal chooses \(a=a^{*}\). Since

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) dx=\frac{ v^{\prime }\left( a^{*}\right) }{h_{a}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }+\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }, \end{aligned}$$

to prove Eq. (20) is equal to \(\frac{ v^{\prime }(a^{*})}{h_{a}(a^{*},e^{*})}\), we need to prove:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }+B\cdot F_{h}\left( {\widehat{x}}|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) }{\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{ {\overline{x}} }F_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}\cdot {\int _{{\widehat{x}} }^{{\overline{x}} }xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}\nonumber \\&\qquad -\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\eta ^{*}f_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))\,dx=-\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{ h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) } \nonumber \\&\quad \iff \gamma ^{*}{\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}+\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\eta ^{*}f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx=\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{ h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Since \(w^{*}(x)\) can induce the agent to choose \(e^{*}\) when the principal chooses \(a^{*}\), we can easily get:

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma ^{*}\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}xf_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx+\eta ^{*}\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx=\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{ h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

So Eq. (21) is true, which implies that the proposed \(w^{*}(x)\) can induce the principal to choose \(a^{*}\) given the agent chooses \(e^{*}\).

Thus we have proved, given there exists \(w^{*}(x)\) to make agent-PC binding, the \(w^{*}(x)\) can implement second-best effort choices.

Step 3: Conditions for binding Agent-PC

Under SonBo \(w^{*}(x)\), agent’s expected compensation, denoted as \(G(B, {\widehat{x}})\), is:

$$\begin{aligned} G(B,{\widehat{x}})=\gamma ^{*}\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}(x- {\widehat{x}})f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx+B\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx. \end{aligned}$$

\(G(B,{\widehat{x}})\) can be factored into two parts: \(G(B,{\widehat{x}})=H( {\widehat{x}})+B\cdot L({\widehat{x}})\).

The function \(H({\widehat{x}})\) is strictly decreasing on \([{\underline{x}}, {\overline{x}})\). The function \(L({\widehat{x}})\) is the weight on bonus B. The domain of \(H({\widehat{x}})\) and \(L({\widehat{x}})\) is \([{\underline{x}}, {\overline{x}})\). We extend the domain of these two functions to \([\underline{x },{\overline{x}}]\) by defining: \(H({\overline{x}})=\lim _{ {\widehat{x}}\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}H({\widehat{x}})\) and \(L({\overline{x}})=\lim _{{\widehat{x}} \rightarrow {\overline{x}}}L({\widehat{x}})\). These extensions make \(H(\widehat{x })\) and \(L({\widehat{x}}) \) continuous on \([{\underline{x}},{\overline{x}}]\).

Step 3.1

Define \(\eta ^{\star }=-\gamma ^{\star }{\widehat{x}}^{\star }\). Given a feasible B, \(G(B,{\underline{x}})=H({\underline{x}})+B\) because \(L({\underline{x}})=1\), and

$$\begin{aligned} H({\underline{x}})&=\gamma ^{\star }\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}(x- {\underline{x}})f\left( x|h(a^{*},e^{*})\right) \,dx \\&=\gamma ^{\star }\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}xf\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx+\eta ^{\star }\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx\\&\quad -\eta ^{\star }\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{ {\overline{x}}}f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx\\&\quad -\gamma ^{\star }{\underline{x}} \int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx \\&=\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left[ \gamma ^{\star }x+\eta ^{\star }\right] f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx\\&\quad -\eta ^{\star }-\gamma ^{\star }{\underline{x}}. \end{aligned}$$

We have proved that without limited liability, the optimal contract \( w^{\star }(x)=\gamma ^{\star }x+\eta ^{\star }\) can make the agent-PC binding, that is \(\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}[\gamma ^{\star }x+\eta ^{\star }]f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))\,dx=c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}\). So

$$\begin{aligned} G(B,{\underline{x}})=c\left( e^{*}\right) +{\overline{U}}_{e}-\eta ^{\star }-\gamma ^{\star }{\underline{x}}+B. \end{aligned}$$

Given Assumption 4 that the linear sharing contract is not feasible, i.e. \( \gamma ^{\star }{\underline{x}}+\eta ^{\star }<0\),

$$\begin{aligned} G(B,{\underline{x}})-c\left( e^{*}\right) -{\overline{U}}_{e}=B-\left( \gamma ^{\star } {\underline{x}}+\eta ^{\star }\right) >0. \end{aligned}$$

So \(G(B,{\underline{x}})>c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}\).

Step 3.2

Next, we prove \(G(B,{\overline{x}})\le c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}\) if and only if \(\frac{f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}\). Given a feasible B, \(G(B, {\overline{x}})=H({\overline{x}})\) because \(L({\overline{x}})=0\). We will prove \(H( {\overline{x}})\le c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}\) is equivalent to \(\frac{ f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f( {\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{ c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}\).

\(H({\overline{x}})\) is solved from the following limit problem.

$$\begin{aligned} H({\overline{x}})&=\lim _{{\widehat{x}}\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}H({\widehat{x}}) =\lim _{{\widehat{x}}\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}\frac{\int _{{\widehat{x}} }^{ {\overline{x}}}(x-{\widehat{x}})f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx }{ \int _{\widehat{x }}^{{\overline{x}}}F_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx } \frac{ c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }\\&=\frac{f\left( {\overline{x}} |h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) }{f_{h}\left( {\overline{x}} |h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) } \frac{ c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

The above process uses L’Hospital’s rule and \(F_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))=0\). It should be noticed that \(f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))>0\).Footnote 11

So

$$\begin{aligned} H({\overline{x}})\le c\left( e^{*}\right) +{\overline{U}}_{e}\iff \frac{f_{h}\left( \overline{ x }|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) }{f({\overline{x}} |h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) )}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{c\left( e^{*}\right) + {\overline{U}}_{e}}. \end{aligned}$$

Combining step 3.1 and step 3.2, there must exist one \({\widehat{x}}\in [{\underline{x}},{\overline{x}}]\) to make agent-PC hold.

Step 3.3

Next, we prove given a feasible B, if there exists one \({\widehat{x}}\in [ {\underline{x}},{\overline{x}}]\) to make \(G(B,{\widehat{x}})=c(e^{*})+\overline{ U}_{e}\) hold, the condition \(\frac{f_{h}( {\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{ *}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f({\overline{x}} |h(a^{*},e^{*}))} \ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+ {\overline{U}}_{e}}\) must hold.

If there exists such \({\widehat{x}}\), SonBo achieves the second-best outcome, so agent-IC holds and agent-PC binds. The binding agent-PC and agent-IC are

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \,dx=c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) , \\&\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx=c\left( e^{*}\right) +{\overline{U}}_{e}. \end{aligned}$$

Combing these two equations,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int _{{\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \,dx}{ \int _{ {\widehat{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}=\frac{c^{\prime }\left( e^{*}\right) }{ c\left( e^{*}\right) +{\overline{U}} _{e}}. \end{aligned}$$

Define

$$\begin{aligned} \psi (z)=\frac{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \,dx}{ \int _{z}^{ {\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx} ,\,z\in [{\widehat{x}},{\overline{x}}]. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(h^{*}=h(a^{*},e^{*})\) and \(h_{e}^{*}=h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})\).

$$ \psi ^{\prime }(z)=\frac{-\left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z|h^{*}\right) h_{e}^{*}\cdot \int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h^{*}\right) \,dx+\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}} }\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h^{*}\right) h_{e}^{*}\,dx\cdot \left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z|h^{*}\right) }{ \left[ \int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx\right] ^{2}}. $$

SonBo achieves second-best outcome under agent’s limited liability, so it gives the agent non-negative payment at any possible output. Thus, given a feasible B, when \(z\ge {\widehat{x}}\), \(\gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}>0\), so \(\psi ^{\prime }(z)\ge 0\) is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h^{*}\right) \,dx}{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h^{*}\right) \,dx}\ge \frac{\left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z|h^{*}\right) }{ \left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z|h^{*}\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Based on MLRP, for any \(z_{1}\ge z_{2}\ge z\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) }{\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) }\ge \frac{\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{2}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z_{2}|h^{*}\right) }{ \left( \gamma ^{*}z_{2}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z_{2}|h^{*}\right) } \\&\quad \iff \left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) \left( \gamma ^{*}z_{2}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z_{2}|h^{*}\right) \\&\quad \ge \left( \gamma ^{*}z_{2}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z_{2}|h^{*}\right) \left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Since \(z_{1}\) and \(z_{2}\) are arbitrary, integrate \(z_{1}\) from \(z_{2}\) to \( {\overline{x}}\) and let \(z_{2}=z\):

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) \,dz_{1}\cdot \left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z|h^{*}\right) \\&\quad \ge \left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z|h^{*}\right) \cdot \int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) \,dz_{1} \\&\quad \iff \frac{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) \,dz_{1}}{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}z_{1}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z_{1}|h^{*}\right) \,dz_{1}}\ge \frac{ \left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z|h^{*}\right) }{\left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z|h^{*}\right) } \\&\quad \iff \frac{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( x|h^{*}\right) \,dx}{\int _{z}^{{\overline{x}}}\left( \gamma ^{*}x+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( x|h^{*}\right) \,dx}\ge \frac{\left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( z|h^{*}\right) }{\left( \gamma ^{*}z+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( z|h^{*}\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, we have proved \(\psi ^{\prime }(z)\ge 0\) for \(z\in [{\widehat{x}}, {\overline{x}}]\). Since the function \(\psi (z)\) is increasing, \( \lim \limits _{z\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}\psi (z)\ge \psi ({\widehat{x}})=\frac{ c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}\).

Notice that

$$\begin{aligned} \lim \limits _{z\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}\psi (z)=\frac{\left( \gamma ^{*} {\overline{x}}+\eta ^{*}\right) f_{h}\left( {\overline{x}}|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \,dx}{\left( \gamma ^{*}{\overline{x}}+\eta ^{*}\right) f\left( {\overline{x}}|h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}=\frac{f_{h}\left( {\overline{x}} |h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) h_{e}\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \,dx}{f\left( {\overline{x}} |h\left( a^{*},e^{*}\right) \right) \,dx}. \end{aligned}$$

So if there exists any \({\widehat{x}}\in [{\underline{x}},{\overline{x}}]\) to make agent-PC binding, we should have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{f_{h}({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{ f({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{ c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}. \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

Suppose contract w(x) is an optimal solution to [P(LL)]. Next, we prove this contract must satisfy condition (11). Contract w(x) achieves second-best outcome means that it can make agent-PC binding and agent-IC and principal-IC hold when effort levels are \((a^{*},e^{*})\). Based on the binding agent-PC and agent-IC:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))\,dx=c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e} , \\&\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})\,dx=c^{\prime }(e^{*}) , \end{aligned}$$

which implies

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})\,dx}{\int _{{\underline{x}}}^{{\overline{x}} }w(x)f(x|h(a^{*},e^{*}))\,dx}=\frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{ c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Step 1

If w(x) is an optimal solution of [P(LL)], (22) should hold. Next we prove if (22) holds, condition (11) should hold.

Define \(V(x_{c})=\frac{\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}} }w(x)f_{h}(x|h(a,e))h_{e}(a,e)\,dx}{\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}} }w(x)f(x|h(a,e))\,dx}\). The effort choices (ae) in \(V(x_{c})\) can be any feasible effort choices including \((a^{*},e^{*})\). Notice that the left-hand side of (22) is equal to \(V({\underline{x}})\) when \( (a,e)=(a^{*},e^{*})\). We write f(x|h(ae)) as f(x|h) and \( h_{e}(a,e)\) as \(h_{e}\) for short. In this step, we prove \(V(x_{c})\) is an increasing function of \(x_{c}\) for any pair of (ae) , i.e., \({\frac{ dV(x_{c})}{dx_{c}}}\ge 0\) for any (ae). We have

$$\begin{aligned} {\frac{dV(x_{c})}{dx_{c}}}=\frac{w(x_{c})h_{e}\big [f(x_{c}|h)\int _{x_{c}}^{ {\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}(x|h)\,dx-f_{h}(x_{c}|h)\int _{x_{c}}^{ {\overline{x}} }w(x)f(x|h)\,dx\big ]}{\big [\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}} }w(x)f(x|h)\,dx\big ] ^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

When \(w(x_{c})=0\), \({\frac{dV(x_{c})}{dx_{c}}}=0\).

When \(w(x_{c})>0\), since \(h_{e}>0\), \({\frac{dV(x_{c})}{dx_{c}}}\ge 0\) is equivalent to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}(x|h)\,dx}{\int _{x_{c}}^{ {\overline{x}}}w(x)f(x|h)\,dx}\ge \frac{f_{h}(x_{c}|h)}{f(x_{c}|h)}. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Notice that when \(w(x_{c})>0\), \(\frac{f_{h}(x_{c}|h)}{f(x_{c}|h)}=\frac{ w(x_{c})f_{h}(x_{c}|h)}{w(x_{c})f(x_{c}|h)}\). Then (23) is equivalent to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}(x|h)\,dx}{\int _{x_{c}}^{ {\overline{x}}}w(x)f(x|h)\,dx}\ge \frac{w(x_{c})f_{h}(x_{c}|h)}{ w(x_{c})f(x_{c}|h)}. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Next, we prove (24) holds. Based on MLRP, the function \(\frac{ f_{h}(x|h)}{f(x|h)}\) is increasing with \(x\ge x_{c}\) when \(w(x)\ne 0\). Pick \(x_{1}\) and \(x_{2}\) such that \(x_{1}\ge x_{2}\ge x_{c}\). If \( w(x_{1})\ne 0\) and \(w(x_{2})\ne 0\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{w(x_{1})f_{h}(x_{1}|h)}{w(x_{1})f(x_{1}|h)}\ge \frac{ w(x_{2})f_{h}(x_{2}|h)}{w(x_{2})f(x_{2}|h)} \\&\quad \iff w(x_{1})f_{h}(x_{1}|h)w(x_{2})f(x_{2}|h)\ge w(x_{2})f_{h}(x_{2}|h)w(x_{1})f(x_{1}|h). \end{aligned}$$

If \(w(x_{1})=0\) or \(w(x_{2})=0\) or both,

$$\begin{aligned} w(x_{1})f_{h}(x_{1}|h)w(x_{2})f(x_{2}|h)\ge w(x_{2})f_{h}(x_{2}|h)w(x_{1})f(x_{1}|h). \end{aligned}$$

So for \(x_{1}\ge x_{2}\ge x_{c}\),

$$\begin{aligned} w(x_{1})f_{h}(x_{1}|h)w(x_{2})f(x_{2}|h)\ge w(x_{2})f_{h}(x_{2}|h)w(x_{1})f(x_{1}|h). \end{aligned}$$

Since \(x_{1}\) and \(x_{2}\) are arbitrary, integrate \(x_{1}\) from \(x_{2}\) to \( {\overline{x}}\) and let \(x_{2}=x_{c}\). Then

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x_{1})f_{h}(x_{1}|h)\,dx_{1}\cdot w(x_{c})f(x_{c}|h)\ge w(x_{c})f_{h}(x_{c}|h)\cdot \int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}} }w(x_{1})f(x_{1}|h)\,dx_{1} \\&\quad \iff \frac{\int _{x_{c}}^{{\overline{x}}}w(x)f_{h}(x|h)\,dx}{ \int _{x_{c}}^{ {\overline{x}}}w(x)f(x|h)\,dx}\ge \frac{w(x_{c})f_{h}(x_{c}|h)}{ w(x_{c})f(x_{c}|h)}. \end{aligned}$$

Thus (24) is true. So the function \({\frac{dV(x_{c})}{dx_{c}}} \ge 0\) when \(w(x_{c})>0\).

So far we have proved that given the contract \(w(x)\ge 0\) for any \(x\ge x_{c}\), \({\frac{dV(x_{c})}{dx_{c}}}\ge 0\).

Step 2

The (ae) in \(V(x_{c})\) is arbitrary. Now let \((a,e)=(a^{*},e^{*})\). Since \(V(x_{c})\) is increasing, \(V(x_{c})\ge V({\underline{x}})\) for \(x_{c}> {\underline{x}}\). Condition (22) implies that \(V(x_{c}) \ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}\) for \(x_{c}> {\underline{x}}\). Furthermore, we should have

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{x_{c}\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}V(x_{c})\ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*}) }{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}}_{e}}. \end{aligned}$$

Based on L’Hospital’s rule,

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{x_{c}\rightarrow {\overline{x}}}V(x_{c})= & {} \lim _{x_{c}\rightarrow {\overline{x}}} \frac{w(x_{c})f_{h}(x_{c}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{w(x_{c})f(x_{c}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\\= & {} \lim _{x_{c} \rightarrow {\overline{x}}} \frac{f_{h}(x_{c}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f(x_{c}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}=\frac{f_{h}( {\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{ f(\overline{ x}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}. \end{aligned}$$

So given the contract w(x) implements the second-best outcome, i.e. condition (22) holds, \(\frac{f_{h}({\overline{x}} |h(a^{*},e^{*}))h_{e}(a^{*},e^{*})}{f({\overline{x}}|h(a^{*},e^{*}))}\ge \frac{c^{\prime }(e^{*})}{c(e^{*})+{\overline{U}} _{e}}\) holds.

Next, we prove when condition (11) holds, there must exist contracts to implement the second-best outcome of [P(LL)]. The proof is simple as we have proved when condition (11) holds, SonBo contract exists and it implements the second-best outcome.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cong, J., Zhou, W. Optimal contract under double moral hazard and limited liability. J Econ 134, 49–71 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00737-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00737-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation