Introduction

Not every apprenticeshipFootnote 1 in Germany ends successfully; i.e., with obtaining of the nationally standardized diploma. Uhly (2020b) calculates that currently one in four apprenticeship contracts is terminated before its end date. Moreover, the number of early contract terminationsFootnote 2 has increased almost continuously over the past decade.

Although apprenticeship non-completion can also be a good consequence of the occupational orientation of young apprentices (Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly 2015), the rise in early contract termination rates raises concerns, because apprenticeship non-completion may be costly for training firms and apprentices alike. Especially in light of increasing shortages of skilled labor and apprentices, reducing apprenticeship non-completion has been a common goal for policy-makers, employers, and unions (cf. Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly 2015).Footnote 3

Recently, apprenticeship non-completion has received public attention when German policy-makers called for a minimum wage for apprentices. The primary goal of such a policy is to increase the attractiveness of occupations that have problems filling their vacancies. Furthermore, increasing low apprenticeship wages is suggested to decrease apprenticeship non-completion, as for instance the Vice President of the German Trade Union Confederation (DGBFootnote 4) argued in a speech in favor of the minimum apprenticeship wage (DGB 2019). This paper investigates the actual existence of a correlation between the apprenticeship wage and non-completion. In addition, this study analyzes the relevance of wage prospects after completion.

In recent years, a strand of literature evolved studying the determinants of apprenticeship non-completion in Germany (Kotte 2019a, b; Wydra-Somaggio 2017; Bessey and Backes-Gellner 2015; Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly 2015; Kropp et al. 2014). However, with the exception of the study of Kropp et al. (2014), research has not focused on pecuniary factors as determinants of non-completion. In their study, Kropp et al. (2014) find a significantly negative association of apprenticeship wages and the share of early contract terminations, however only for a regionally restricted sample of apprenticeships in industrial and trade occupations in the Halle-Dessau area.

Although so far, no evidence exists for the relevance of wage prospects for apprenticeship non-completion in Germany, related studies provide some insight. Mangan and Trendle (2017, 2008) find a negative association of non-completion and wages after completion in Australia. For Switzerland, some studies also show that wage expectations influence turnover in related education and labor market situations. Rinawi and Backes-Gellner (2020) find evidence for significantly higher rates of apprentice retention after completion for establishments, which use performance pay schemes in Switzerland. According to the authors, performance pay increases the costs of leaving the firm for high-productivity workers such that the retention rate is higher. Similarly, Schweri and Hartog (2017) present evidence that Swiss nursing apprentices who expect higher wage premia from attending nursing college have a higher probability to continue their education at the tertiary level after completing their apprenticeship. In contrast, Bessey and Backes-Gellner (2015) do not find any significant evidence for an association of income prospects and the continuation of education after an early termination of the apprenticeship contract.

Furthermore, apprenticeship non-completion partly relates to dropping out of higher education at the tertiary level. The studies by Stinebrickner and Stinebrickner (2012, 2014) and Arcidiacono et al. (2012, 2020) find that wage expectations play an important role for dropping out and switching the major at US colleges. More specifically, the studies show that students learn about their own performance in the course of their studies, update their earnings expectations in consequence and continue their study only if it is still profitable.

The applicability of this previous evidence to apprenticeship non-completion in Germany, however, is not trivial. For one, in contrast to apprenticeship retention after completion and the transitioning to or continuation of a college education, apprenticeship non-completion is not only characterized by wage prospects but also the immediate pay-off from the apprenticeship wage. Moreover, non-completion of apprentices is likely to differ from that of college students, because they are mostly younger (cf. Bonin et al. 2016). Also, apprentices are employees of an establishment. Hence, there is a closer link between the selection of apprentices into apprenticeships and non-completion to skill demands at the labor market. Apprentices also observe their job suitability directly on the job, thereby granting them a different information access to update their earnings expectations.

This paper adds to the existing literature by analyzing the role of pecuniary benefits in this special case of apprenticeship non-completion in Germany and provides first evidence that both the apprenticeship wage and wages after completion are negatively associated with non-completion.

Apprenticeship non-completion in Germany

Despite an increase in the enrollment in academic programs, apprenticeships in the German system of dual vocational education and training (VET) are still the most common way to receive a vocational education in Germany. About 54.5% of the population starts an apprenticeship at some point in their life (Uhly 2020a).

An apprenticeship combines on-the-job training with school-based courses on both general and occupation-specific skills. While the municipality provides the latter in local trade schools (Berufsschulen), apprenticeship seekers apply directly to a training establishment for the former. When recruited, apprentices sign an apprenticeship contract, which outlines, among other things, the occupation title, the curriculum, working hours, and the apprenticeship wage and its progression over the course of the apprenticeship.

Depending on the occupation-specific curriculum and the applicant’s level of education, an apprenticeship usually lasts between two and three and a half years. At the end, apprentices take part in a final exam organized by their profession’s guild. Upon passing, apprentices receive a nationally standardized and recognized diploma, which completes their apprenticeship.

However, for the year 2018, Uhly (2020b) calculates that 26.5% of the apprenticeship contracts were terminated without successful completion. Since 2008, this share has been increasing and since 2016 it exceeds the usual range of fluctuation between 20% and 25% (see Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

(Source: Uhly (2020b), Vocational Education and Training Statistics of the Federal Statistical Office and the Statistical Offices of the Länder with survey date December 31, 1993 to 2018. Note: The new definition is a summation of the contract termination rates by apprenticeship year. The old definition could use this approach only by approximation. Note further, in 2007 the survey method was substantially changed, thereby enabling calculations according to the new definition. Consequently, however, rates before and after 2007 can only be compared with considerable caution.)

Early contract terminations in VET, 1993 to 2018.

There are several reasons for apprenticeship non-completion. The apprentice can quit or the establishment can terminate the contract (cf. Beicht and Walden 2013, p. 2). Also, Schöngen (2003) estimates that 12% of early contract terminations are a result of establishment relocation or shutdown.

Furthermore, non-completion does not necessarily have to raise concerns, as it also reflects the natural act of rematching between training establishments and apprentices to achieve more suitable matches (cf. Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly 2015). Notably, Wydra-Somaggio (2017) suggests that 72% of non-completers start another apprenticeship thereafter.

Nevertheless, non-completion may also adversely affect establishments and apprentices. For establishments, apprenticeship non-completion can be problematic for three reasons: First, non-completion leads to the loss of human capital, which especially harms establishments, which train to secure their skill supply. Note here, early contract termination varies largely across occupations. It is as high as 51.2% for hairdressers and, in contrast, as low as 5.5% for administrative clerks (Uhly 2020b). Moreover, Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly (2015) estimate that the occupation explains 14.5% of the variance in early apprenticeship contract termination. Furthermore, the authors find that occupations with higher numbers of apprenticeship vacancies have a significantly higher rate of early contract termination. Hence, non-completion may especially pose a threat to the skill supply in less attractive occupations.

Second, most German training establishments follow an investment motive meaning that apprenticeships incur substantial costs in the beginning and recoup them only later with tenure of the apprentice (cf. Schönfeld et al. 2016; Mühlemann and Wolter 2014; Mohrenweiser and Backes-Gellner 2010). For these establishments, non-completion equals high sunk costs. Wenzelmann and Lemmermann (2012) estimate a total of irrevocable net costs of 580 million EurosFootnote 5 from apprenticeship non-completion in the year 2007.

Third, repeated experience of non-completion may potentially lower the establishments’ participation in apprentice training in the long run. According to a study by Mohr et al. (2015), 18% of the surveyed establishments mentioned non-completion as a reason for reducing their apprenticeship offers.

For apprentices, on the other hand, non-completion jeopardizes future career paths as it could carry the stigma of an unproductive worker; i.e., a lemon (Akerlof 1970; Katz and Ziderman 1990), which other establishments do not want to train nor employ. If so, this limits the apprentice’s chances of finding a high quality alternative within the apprenticeship system. Furthermore, non-completion may bear the risk of entirely dropping out of the vocational system, which, according to Wolter and Ryan (2011), increases the risk of low pay and precarious employment in the future.

Theoretical considerations

The cost-benefit framework of turnover behavior provides the theoretical backdrop for the importance of pecuniary pay-offs from apprenticeships. It assumes that non-completion is a rational decision that reflects a cost-benefit analysis of the apprentice and the training establishment alike. For both, committing to an apprenticeship, similar to any other investment into education and training, is only worthwhile when its net present value is positive (cf. Becker 1962). Hence, they will end the apprenticeship when its benefits fall short of its costs. In line with Mortensen’s (1988) considerations regarding turnover decisions in the labor market, the possibility of quitting is a form of insurance against unfavorable developments in profitability of the current choice.

Mangan and Trendle (2008) express the importance of pecuniary benefits for apprenticeship non-completion in a utility model. According to this model, the utility \(U_{ijt}\) of an apprenticeship position j at time t for apprentice i essentially is a composite of two separate utilities, such that

$$\begin{aligned} U_{ijt}=U(u^{(1)}_{ijt},u^{(2)}_{ijt}), \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where the function \(U(\cdot ,\cdot )\) is common to all apprenticeships and determines the relative weight of the two components. The first component states that

$$\begin{aligned} u^{(1)}_{ijt}=u^{(1)}(W_{ijt},X_{ijt}), \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(W_{ijt}\) expresses the pecuniary pay-offs and \(X_{ijt}\) the non-pecuniary benefits from being in an apprenticeship at time t relative to those from the available outside options j. Hence, \(u^{(1)}_{ijt}\) captures the instantaneous net benefits of the apprenticeship.

Although apprentices in Germany do not pay tuition, following apprenticeship j also bears costs, which lower \(U_{ijt}\). One of these costs is the effort \(e_{ijt}\) that is required to complete apprenticeship j. \(e_{ijt}\) is increasing in the occupation’s task complexity \(c_j\), however decreasing in the apprentice’s productivity p, which itself is a function of ability \(a_i\), job suitability \(\eta _{ij}\), and accumulated specific human capital \(\kappa _{it}\). The first component of the utility can, thus, be written as

$$\begin{aligned} u^{(1)}_{ijt}=u^{(1)}\left( W_{ijt},X_{ijt}, \frac{c_{j}}{p(a_i,\eta _{ij},\kappa _{it})}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(3)

Apprenticeship wages are known at the beginning of the apprenticeship and defined by the apprenticeship contract. They, however, may affect non-completion because many aspects of \(u^{(1)}_{ijt}\) are a priori unknown. Apprentices are mostly young and new to the labor market. In fact, in 2018 apprentices below the age of 24 signed about 88% of new contracts (Uhly 2020a, p. 165). Hirschi (2011) finds that consolidating career choices, although highly dependent on individual characteristics, is a function of time. In addition, Stamm (2012) and Bohlinger (2002) point out that career orientation in school is often deficient. As a result, apprentices are often insufficiently informed about what to expect of an apprenticeship. In consequence, they reevaluate the appropriateness of the apprenticeship wage on the job. Therefore, even though apprenticeship wages are known from the start, there is an association of the apprenticeship wage and non-completion.

One unknown aspects, which is weighed against the apprenticeship wage, is job suitability \(\eta\), which can only be learned over time with observation of on-the-job performance (cf. Jovanovic 1979). Discovering low job suitability increases the costs of staying and, thus, the probability of non-completion if wages cannot offset the costs. Furthermore, the required effort is a priori unknown. Gambin and Hogarth (2016) argue that apprentices discover dislike of certain job tasks only on the job; they reevaluate the appropriateness of apprenticeship wages, which, in turn, affects work morale and ultimately non-completion behavior. Moreover, insufficient information also concern non-pecuniary benefits as, for example, working conditions, career chances and the quality of the apprenticeship program in the training establishment. Analyzing a survey of 2000 German establishments, Christ (2013) provides some evidence for the latter by showing that non-completion occurs less often in training establishments who see apprenticeships as an investment into their future labor supply.

Adding the costs of effort has two other implications for the importance of the apprenticeship wage. First, changing jobs and occupations comes at the cost of losing job-specific skills \(\kappa\) (cf. Garloff and Kuckulenz 2006; Becker 1962). As \(\kappa\) is increasing in t, non-completion becomes less likely over time regardless of the apprenticeship wage or other benefits. This may partly explain the decreasing rates of apprenticeship non-completion over tenure (cf. Uhly 2020b).Footnote 6 In contrast, apprenticeship wages are increasing with each completed apprenticeship year to reflect this gain in skills and increased job requirements. Therefore, not accounting for tenure may underestimate the association of the apprenticeship wage and non-completion.

Second, the relationship between pecuniary benefits of an apprenticeship and non-completion is biased by the selection on ability. Assuming apprentices are aware of their own ability at the start of the apprenticeship, high ability apprentices can select into comparably high-cost apprenticeships, which are more complex and take more effort. Because of their lower cost of staying in the apprenticeship, high-ability apprentices also have lower probabilities of non-completion. In fact, for Swiss apprenticeships, Schmid and Stalder (2012) document that the rate of early contract terminations is actually decreasing in task complexity. Assuming that wages partly compensate task complexity, indicates that quitting to upgrade to more complex and more profitable apprenticeships is a strong motive for non-completion and, thus, that pecuniary benefits matter. At the same time, the observation of Schmid and Stalder (2012) corresponds to less able apprentices selecting into less complex apprenticeships, thereby increasing non-completion. Hence, not controlling for selection on ability would lead to an overestimation of the association of non-completion and the apprenticeship wage.

Furthermore, the importance of pecuniary benefits for non-completion may differ according to ability. On the one hand, apprentices who graduated from lower tracks of high schoolFootnote 7 have lower possibilities of finding an apprenticeship in their dream occupation (Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly 2015; Protsch 2014). Hence, they may quit more often to search for better and more profitable apprenticeships; the association between pecuniary benefits and non-completion would then be stronger.

On the other hand, apprentices, who hold a high school diploma from the academic track and also could have decided to go to university, may more often strategically use an apprenticeship to continue to the academic system. In fact, Scheller et al. (2013) document that 22% of university entrants in 2011 already had obtained a VET degree. Bellmann and Stephani (2012), for example, show that a so-called double qualification, referring to the holding of a VET and additionally an academic diploma, positively affects several dimensions of job satisfaction. For Swiss graduates, Tuor and Backes-Gellner (2010) show that the combination of VET and academic education is associated with higher earnings after completion than both a purely VET or a purely academic education.

In addition, apprentices from the academic track may also more often end their apprenticeship before completion to transfer to university. Admission to popular university programs in Germany partly depends on waiting time; i.e., time passed after high school graduation. Hence, it is common practice in some fields of study to start an apprenticeship while waiting for university admission. Note however, that early contract termination rates are still lowest for apprentices from the academic track (15.6% in 2018 cf. Uhly 2020b). Furthermore, Schnitzler (2020) finds that only about a third of apprentices from the academic track who terminated their apprenticeship contract early continued to study at a university.Footnote 8

Whether or not the apprenticeship is completed, for graduates who actually strive for future benefits of jobs at the academic level the benefits of the apprenticeship may be of less or even no importance. Hence, the association of pecuniary benefits of an apprenticeship and the non-completion hazard may be lower for apprentices from the academic track on average.

The second component \(u^{(2)}_{ijt}\) denotes the utility from \(W_{ijt}\) given \(E(W_{ijt}^{(m)})\), such that

$$\begin{aligned} u^{(2)}_{ijt}=u^{(2)}(W_{ijt}|E(W_{ijt}^{(m)})), \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(W_{ijt}^{(m)}\) is the average wage after completion of an apprenticeship; i.e., that of skilled workers (m)Footnote 9 (Mangan and Trendle 2008). The second component, thus, captures the apprentice’s trade-off between current and future pecuniary benefits from completion. Notably, this trade-off is a vital concept of apprenticeship financing, where apprentices willingly accept a wage below their productivity as unskilled workers in exchange for apprenticeship training and expected larger profits in the future as skilled workers (cf. Stevens 1994). If wage prospects, however, fall short, the apprenticeship becomes less attractive and, thus, is prone to non-completion.

Unlike apprenticeship wages, which are predetermined by contract, wages after completion are unknown to the apprentice and wage expectations evolve during the apprenticeship. On the one hand, this happens due to misjudgments of earning possibilities. Using an experimental design, Wiswall and Zafar (2015a, b), demonstrate how US college students severely misjudge earning risks of college majors. In addition, expected wages after completion are a function of job suitability. Low job suitability decreases productivity, which effects wages in the occupation as a skilled worker (cf. Jovanovic 1979).Footnote 10 Note here that skilled workers with a completed apprenticeship in Germany are relatively immobile across occupations. Although Kropp and Schmillen (2012) estimate that one third of all individuals with completed apprenticeships worked in different occupations in 2008 as compared to 2005, they find that changes mostly occur in related occupations. Commitment to an apprenticeship, thus, strongly predicts future career paths and income streams. Because of learning about wage prospects, wages after completion are expected to be an important determinant for non-completion.

Finally, a third component has to be added to the utility function.

$$\begin{aligned} u^{(3)}_{ijt}=u^{(3)}(W_{ijt}|U_{i-jt}), \end{aligned}$$
(5)

states that the apprentice forgoes pecuniary profits of the available alternatives \((-j)\) within the apprenticeship system, other education tracks, or low skilled employment opportunities in the labor market. Thus, a plethora of high-utility outside options exerts upward pressure on the current and future pecuniary pay-offs of an apprenticeship.

A few studies outline the importance of outside options for apprenticeship non-completion. Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly (2015) find that a comparably large share of vacancies per apprenticeship seekers in German regions is significantly positively associated with non-completion. Similarly, Mühlemann et al. (2013) demonstrate how local monopsony power of training establishments significantly influences non-completion in Switzerland. More specifically, the authors estimate an increase in non-completion by 35% from a one standard deviation increase in the number of establishments. Hence, an abundance of apprenticeship offers facilitates transitions within the apprenticeship system and fosters non-completion.

Furthermore, Jaik and Wolter (2019) find evidence for Switzerland that an excess supply of apprenticeships at the beginning of an apprenticeship significantly increases the probability of an early contract termination in the first two years of that apprenticeship. Thus, the availability of apprenticeships is also correlated with match quality; if more apprentices apply per apprenticeship, establishments can select better candidates with a lower probability of non-completion.

Given that pecuniary benefits also partly increase with labor scarcity, a relatively high availability of apprenticeships, thus, corresponds to higher wages and higher non-completion. Hence, not controlling for the availability and profitability of outside options would underestimate the association of pecuniary benefits and non-completion.

Data and data preparation

The following analysis uses the Sample of Integrated Employment Biographies (SIAB) by the Institute of Employment Research (IAB;Footnote 11 for a detailed documentation see Antoni et al. 2016). SIAB is a 2% sample of all individuals in the registry of the Federal Employment Agency (BAFootnote 12) between 1975 and 2014. The registry combines process data of mandatory establishment reports on their employees who are subject to social security contributions, social benefit histories, participation in BA labor market measures, registered job seeking, and obtained unemployment benefits. SIAB provides all of this information as spell data in days and, thus, provides labor market biographies for the sample individuals. The data do not document times of self-employment, unregistered job seeking, or university enrollment, consequently creating biographical gaps. However, since April 1999, SIAB contains periods of marginal employment.

SIAB distinguishes regular employment from apprenticeshipsFootnote 13 and this analysis uses entries of solely firm-sponsored apprenticeships, which started between 2000 and 2013.

In contrast to other survey data, the large sample size of SIAB allows for the adequate control of heterogeneity of wages and non-completion by year, industry, and occupation. Furthermore, as SIAB is based on administrative records, it eliminates some common sources of bias in survey data. For one, SIAB is not subject to attrition bias, which would lead to an underrepresentation of non-completion late in the apprenticeship. Also, Uhly (2015, p. 49) point out, that survey respondents quite often do not report non-completion especially when the respective apprenticeship period was short.

Nevertheless, identification of apprenticeship non-completion is not trivial as discussed in the following.

Identification of apprenticeship non-completion

SIAB does not provide direct information on successful completion of apprenticeships or early contract termination. However, the information is indirectly accessible, namely by observing a change in the highest vocational education level at the end of an apprenticeship period. This identification strategy leads to an estimation of apprenticeship non-completion of 38.9%, which is very large.

Note that this rate excludes apprentices who already started with a previously completed apprenticeship, as it is impossible to observe a change in their education. Furthermore, the rate already corrects for breaks in the apprenticeship, when apprentices continue their apprenticeship in the same training establishment, for instance after parental leave, longer illness, or internships. In addition, changes of the occupation during the apprenticeship in the same training establishment are not counted as non-completion, because it is generally possible to decide on the actual training occupation later on. Moreover, establishments probably perceive occupational changes to a lesser extent as a loss in investments.

Despite this, the rate is overestimated because of two important identification problems. First, as information on education is voluntary in SIAB, they are often missing or contain inconsistent entries; i.e., a downgrade in the reported level of education (cf. Fitzenberger et al. 2005). Second, firms do not always report educational attainment as changes in degree often coincide with a change of the employer. Furthermore, it is possible to take the final exam after the end of the apprenticeship contract and even after leaving the training establishment.

To deal with these drawbacks, an elaborate verification procedure is applied. First, the information of education is cleaned. In cases of inconsistencies, the education level is verified following the procedure proposed by Fitzenberger et al. (2005, third variant of the imputation rules). In addition, reports on successful completion or quits from the unemployment registries is used to verify the education level. Similarly, changes in the education variable within 183 days of the end of the apprenticeship period are assumed to indicate its successful completion, because this time span is arguably too short to obtain another VET certificate elsewhere. Overall, cleaning the information on education lowers apprenticeship non-completion in the sample to 28.8%.Footnote 14

Second, the actual timing of the end of apprenticeship periods is cleaned to rule out late reports of successful completion. Increases in job requirement levelsFootnote 15 during the apprenticeship are assumed to indicate an unregistered completion of an apprenticeship. Similarly, sudden increases in the daily wage are interpreted as an end of an apprenticeship. Accordingly, an apprenticeship is assumed to have come to successful completion when the wage increases by at least two thirds of its sample mean, while accounting for differences in education premia by the two-digit occupations of the Classification of Occupations (KldBFootnote 16) 2010, 10 industrial sectors, small, medium and large establishments and East and West Germany. The cleaning of the apprenticeship’s end date leads to a lowering of non-completion to 26.9%.Footnote 17

Third, the sample is limited to regular apprenticeships, by reducing it to full-time and first-time apprenticeships. The sample is further limited to apprentices aged 16 to 25 at the start of the apprenticeship.Footnote 18 Notably, this restriction excludes about 21% of the original sample and lowers non-completion further by 2.0 percentage points.Footnote 19

Finally, the analysis time is censored after 1000 days. Thereafter, the incidence of non-completion rises again in correspondence with the timing of final exams. Hence, by censoring before 1,000 days, this analysis largely excludes repeatedly failed exams and focuses on non-completion decisions during the apprenticeship. This restriction lowers non-completion by 4.0 percentage points.

In the end, the sample consists of information of 94,223 apprenticeships of which 19,697 end in non-completion. This yields a rate of non-completion of 20.9% for solely firm-sponsored apprenticeship, which started between 2000 and 2013. Notably, this number is smaller than Uhly’s (2020b) calculation of the contract termination rate of 26.5%. This difference, however, is reasonable given the exclusion of occupation changes within establishments and the restriction to younger first-time apprentices, who have a lower non-completion rate (also see Kropp et al. 2014, pp. 19). On the other hand, the rate is much higher than the estimation of 12% apprenticeship non-completion based on the BIBB Transition surveyFootnote 20 2011. Uhly (2015, p. 49), however, shows that the Transition Survey underestimates non-completion of very short apprenticeship periods.

Figure 2 portrays the smoothed Kaplan-Meier estimate of the hazard function of non-completion. Note that the non-completion hazard peaks towards the usual end of the trial period of four months.Footnote 21 Thereafter, it decreases in a step-wise manner over the observation window. The plateaus towards the end of the first and second year of the apprenticeship coincide with usual timing of mid-term exams.

Fig. 2
figure 2

(Source: SIAB 2000-2013. Note: N = 94,223 apprenticeships with 19,697 incidences of non-completion.)

Smoothed Kaplan-Meier estimate of the hazard function

Model variables

The approximation of wages after completion (\(W^{(m)}\)) uses the wage information in SIAB.Footnote 22 Specifically, \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\) denotes the natural logarithm of the mean daily wages of workers with a VET certificate distinguished by the two-digit level occupations of the KldB 2010, sex, industry, establishment size category, and location in East or West Germany (region) in the respective yearFootnote 23. Furthermore, \(W^{(m)}\) only uses information on wages of full-time workers aged 30 to 64 to filter out starting wages and those of workers past retirement age.

The daily apprenticeship wage W is directly available in SIAB. However, following Bessey and Backes-Gellner (2015), the relation between the individual apprenticeship wage and average wages of low skilled workers aged 18 to 30 in the same occupation and region (\(W^{(l)}\)) is included. In this way, the variable captures the instantaneous pecuniary benefit of the apprenticeship given its immediate outside option of low skilled work in the same occupation.

Further controls concern individual and training establishment characteristics. Furthermore, a number of labor market controls are included, which describe future career chances after apprenticeship completion and are likely correlated with \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\). Table 1 provides an overview and brief description of the variables.

Table 1 Description of the model variables

Sample descriptives

Table 2 summarizes the sample means and standard deviations of the covariates for the entire sample and cases of non-completion. On average, apprentices in the sample earn 21.42 euro per day and have the prospects of earning 77.06 euro per day after apprenticeship completion. In contrast, apprentices not completing their apprenticeship only earn 17.03 euro per day and later have daily wages of 73.73 euro on average.Footnote 24 Similarly, the relation with respect to low skilled worker wages is considerably lower for non-completion. On average, apprentices are paid 30% of low skilled worker wages in cases of non-completion, while it is 33% in the entire sample. This descriptive evidence, however, also reflects the shorter tenure for cases of non-completion, which corresponds to a smaller progression of the yearly apprenticeship wage.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics by non-completion.

Further, note that there is a higher share of apprenticeships in service occupations and industries among the cases of non-completion. Moreover, the cases of non-completion comprise a higher share of graduates from the lowest track of high school and apprenticeships in small businesses. Considering the labor market controls, note that although the share of marginally employed individuals in the training establishment is higher on average in cases of non-completion, the difference in the supply-to-demand-ratio of apprenticeships (SDR) and unemployment risk variables (\(u^{(l)}/u^{(m)}\) and \(u^{(h)}/u^{(m)}\)) are considerably small.

Method

For this analysis a piecewise exponential (PWE) survival model estimates the non-completion hazard for apprenticeships. The PWE model assumes constant baseline hazards over specified time intervals. In contrast to the conventional exponential model, which assumes a constant baseline hazard of apprenticeship non-completion over the entire apprenticeship duration, the PWE model, therefore, allows for a more flexible functional form of the baseline hazard, which varies over the intervals.

The functional form of the PWE model is

$$\begin{aligned} log(\lambda _{s,ijt})=log{\lambda _s}+\alpha _j+x_{ijt}^\prime \beta , \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\lambda _{s,ijt}\) denotes the hazard corresponding to individual i, in occupation j, and at tenure t in time interval s. \(x_{ijt}\) comprises a number of explanatory variables and \(\beta\) is a vector of corresponding coefficients. The baseline hazard \(\lambda _s\) is a constant over the specified interval of tenure.

For this analysis, the intervals defined by s split the duration of the apprenticeship at 60, 121, 212, 425, and 547 days of tenure. Following the common approach (cf. Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal 2012), the interval cut-off days were chosen according to the non-parametric Kaplan-Meier estimate of the hazard function (see Fig. 2) and cut the hazard function into monotonous pieces with significantly different incidence ratesFootnote 25 (see Appendix: Table 5). Note that a similar estimation assuming the fully non-parametric functional form of the baseline hazard of the Cox survival model produces almost identical results (see Appendix: Table 6). Therefore, the appropriateness of the chosen intervals is assumed. Furthermore, the estimation of a random intercept logit model support the significance and sign of the estimated associations.

The occupation-specific shared frailty, \(\alpha _j\), is a gamma-distributed random component with mean one and variance \(\theta\). It captures unobserved heterogeneity between the occupations and, thus, accounts for the high variation of apprenticeship non-completion across occupations. As wage profiles are very occupation-specific (cf. Bol and Weeden 2015), accounting for occupation-specific shared frailties allows disentangling the effect of wages from the occupation-specific effects.

In all of the tested model specifications, the variation between the shared frailties of the 35 occupational clusters, as measured by \(\theta\), is significantly different from zero. The likelihood-ratio test compares the shared frailty against a fixed-effects model and supports the shared frailty model, meaning there is a significant heterogeneity between occupations.

Throughout, standard errors are adjusted for shared frailties in the 35 occupation clusters.

Results and Discussion

Table 3 presents the estimation results of three shared frailty PWE models. To observe the effect of adding control variables on the estimated hazard ratios of \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\), column 1, 2 , and 3 contain the results from estimating a model without any control variables, a model considering a reduced set of only individual and establishment-level controls, and a model considering all controls including those characterizing the state of the labor market, respectively.

Table 3 Estimated hazard ratios for the piecewise exponential models of the apprenticeship non-completion hazard

The table reports conditional hazard ratios (HR). This means that a value below (above) one indicates a negative (positive) association; i.e, a lower (higher) probability of non-completion in a given period. In turn, a hazard ratio of exactly one indicates that the respective variable is not associated with deviations from the average non-completion hazard.

Wages and non-completion

The results indicate for both \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\) that hazard ratios are significantly below one at a 5% significance level (see Table 3). Given the results from estimating the full model considering all control variables, the hazard ratio corresponding to \(W/W^{(l)}\) is 0.023 and that corresponding to \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\) is 0.456. As expected, this indicates that both a higher apprenticeship wage given a fixed low skilled worker wage and higher wages after completion are associated with a lower non-completion hazard.

This relationship is very robust throughout the three different model specifications. Especially, the hazard ratio of \(W/W^{(l)}\) barely changes when including control variables. However, the hazard ratio of \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\) declines when including apprentice and establishment-level controls (see Table 3, column 2). This suggests that not accounting for these characteristics understates the relationship between wages after completion and the non-completion hazard.

To illustrate, the size of the estimated hazard ratios for \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\), Fig. 3 shows the predicted survival functions corresponding to the estimation of model 3 in Table 3 for different values of the two variables. The black solid line represents the survival function at the mean of the two variables and all other covariates at the respective time interval. The graph shows that the predicted survival rate at the end of the observation period of 1000 days is 79.4%. This number includes apprenticeship completion and apprentices, who are still in their apprenticeship after censoring.

Fig. 3
figure 3

(Note: Estimation of the survival function of the model in Table 3, column 3 at means of all variables (at means), a 5% above average apprenticeship wage relative to unskilled worker wage (mean \(W/W^{(l)}\) plus 5%), and a 5% above average natural logarithm of daily skilled worker wages (mean \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\) plus 5%); N = 94,223 apprenticeships with 19,697 incidences of non-completion.)

Estimated survival function at different wage levels

The dashed line shows the estimated survival function when \(W/W^{(l)}\) is 5% above its average while \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\) and all other covariates are at their mean. Here, the estimated survival rate is approximately 80.2%. These results suggest that apprenticeships, which pay 5% above average, have on average a 0.8 percentage points higher survival within 1,000 days; i.e., a 0.8 percentage points lower non-completion rate.

The dash-dotted line represents the estimated survival function when \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\) is 5% above its average, while all other variables are at their mean. In this case, the estimated survival rate is 82.5%. This suggests that apprentices with the prospect of having a 5% above-average wage after completion have on average a 3.1 percentage points higher survival rate.

Hence, not only higher levels of apprenticeship wages are associated with a higher survival rate, but also higher levels of skilled worker wages are significantly associated with lower apprenticeship non-completion. This suggests that apprentices are not short-sighted in regards to non-completion, but consider their future pay-offs from continuing within the apprenticeship program.

However, these results cannot be interpreted as causal effects. For one, selection of apprentices into apprenticeships cannot be sufficiently controlled. Arguably, controlling for the occupation, industry, establishment size, region, and prior education of the apprentice partly captures selection, thereby reducing the selection bias of the estimated hazard ratios of \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\). Nevertheless, a different analytical design is needed to establish causality, which goes beyond the scope of this paper.

Another aspect, which limits a causal interpretation, is the omission of unobserved factors, which are likely correlated with apprenticeship wages, and wages after completion and at the same time influence non-completion. For example, establishments, which offer high apprenticeship wages may also be more likely to offer a well-structured, high quality apprenticeship program and general support. Hence, the association of the non-completion hazard and apprenticeship wages may partially reflect that apprentices stay for better learning opportunities rather than higher wages. Also, higher wages after completion may partially reflect better career prospects within the firm, which are an incentive to complete. Moreover, higher apprenticeship wages and wages after completion may correlate with a lower incidence of monotonous tasks or those that require physical strength (cf. Autor and Handel 2013). The investigation of the impact of these unobserved factors on the relationship between pecuniary benefits and apprenticeship non-completion has to be left for future research.

Besides these limitations, the results highlight the importance of apprenticeship wages and wages after completion for non-completion behavior. Although the results do not allow for a causal interpretation, they do indicate that not only instantaneous but also future pay-offs of an apprenticeship are an important factor when describing the non-completion hazard. Policies aiming at reducing the rate of apprenticeship non-completion, therefore, should consider the (pecuniary and correlated non-pecuniary) benefits of an apprenticeship after completion instead of solely focusing on the regulating (instantaneous) apprenticeship wages.

Robustness

To check the robustness of the results, Appendix: Table 7 presents model estimations based on some alternative sample restrictions. First, the sample is restricted to apprentices aged 23 and younger (instead of 25 and younger) as suggested by Kotte (2019a, b); this does not alter the results by much (see Table 7, column 1).

Second, the contract termination rate started to continuously increase in 2006 (see Fig. 1). To check whether this increase is associated with changes in the role of the apprenticeship wage and wages after completion, the model is estimated using the split samples before and after 2006, respectively, in Table 7 (columns 2 and 3). The estimated hazard ratios for \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln \text { }W^{(m)}\) are largely unaffected by this sample split.

Third, the observation period covers two major recessions, the dot-com bubble, which lead to a decrease in GDP growth from 2000 to 2003 and the financial crisis of 2008 and 2009. In recessions, non-completion may increase due to mass layoffs. Furthermore, some studies find a small but significant decline of offered apprenticeships in economic downturns (measured in GDP growth, unemployment, or business cycle expectations; cf. Mühlemann et al. 2020; Lüthi and Wolter 2020; Bellmann et al. 2014; Mühlemann et al. 2009). With fewer outside option within the apprenticeship market, apprentices may more often choose to stay with their training company irrespective of the pecuniary benefits. In addition, apprentices that start during an economic downturn may be select. With higher numbers of applicants per apprenticeship, training establishments may decrease non-completion by screening a comparably larger pool of applicants for more suitable candidates (Rohrbach-Schmidt and Uhly 2015). Weßling et al. (2015) also show that in periods of higher unemployment, high school graduates more often turn to attending school-based education programs rather than starting an apprenticeship. If only apprentices without alternatives enter apprenticeships, non-completion should be lower.

To check whether the state of the economy influences the role of pecuniary benefits for non-completion, the sample is split into apprenticeships, which took place entirely in years of economic upturn (2004–2007 and after 2009) and those which had overlap with at least one year of economic downturns (2000–2003 and 2008–2009). The results in Appendix: Table 7 (columns 5 and 6) suggest that the estimated hazard ratios for the apprenticeship wage and wages after completion are largely unaffected by the sample split.

Finally, the dependence of the results on the censoring after 1,000 days is checked. Appendix: Table 8 presents results based on alternative censoring times at 914 days (2.5 years) and 731 days (2 years), respectively. Again, both estimations confirm the negative relationship of \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\) with the non-completion hazard.

Further results

Considering the other covariates, the results in Table 3 indicate a significantly higher non-completion hazard towards the end of the trial period (between 60 and 121 days of tenure) and right afterwards (between 121 and 212 days of tenure). Note that there is no sufficient evidence that the non-completion hazard within the first 60 days of the apprenticeship differs from that of day 547 to 1000 when accounting for further covariates. However, results in Appendix: Table 7 (column 3 and 4) suggest that the importance of this time span may have changed over the years. Only analyzing apprenticeships, which started before 2006, the results indicate a significantly lower hazard ratio in the first 60 days. In turn, it is significantly higher when only looking at apprenticeships, which started after 2006. A similar result appears for the period of 425 to 547 days. Moreover, the results of Appendix: Table 7 (column 5 and 6) suggest that the non-completion hazard is only decreasing with time in upturns. In downturns, it is always lower before day 547. This may indicate that apprentices try harder to hold on to their apprenticeship in downturns, such that unsuitable matches result in non-completion only later, for example, when the apprentices repeatedly fail exams.

Furthermore, the hazard ratios suggest that the non-completion hazard is lower for larger establishments. Similarly, it appears to decrease with higher levels of education; also, it is significantly lower for school leavers, who have not obtained a certificate from the lowest high school track as compared to those who did. The results further suggest that female apprentices have a lower hazard of non-completion.

Concerning the additional labor market controls, the correlation of the non-completion hazard and SDR is not significant at the 5% significance level. In turn, higher rates of marginal employment within the training establishment are associated with higher non-completion hazards. Similarly, higher unemployment risks of unskilled as compared to skilled workers (\(u^{(l)}/u^{(m)}\)) is associated with lower non-completion hazards. Hence, it appears that lower prospects of regular employment positively correlate with non-completion.

In turn, the hazard ratio of the unemployment risk of high skilled workers as compared to skilled workers (\(u^{(h)}/u^{(m)}\)) shows a significant positive association with non-completion. This result probably indicates the importance of career prospects also in jobs, which require an academic education. Apprentices may continue in education to either obtain a specialized VET certificate (for example the master craftsman title) or a university degree after completing the initial apprenticeship. Note that here the high skilled workforce includes employees with either type of degree. Furthermore, this result can only be confirmed for apprenticeships in economic upturns, while the hazard ratio is not significant for apprenticeships in economic downturns. An explanation could be that in down-turns school-based programs increase in popularity with regards to entering the labor market (cf. Clark 2011). Weßling et al. (2015) provide evidence that lower track school graduates in Germany more often attend school-based VET programs when local unemployment is high. Similarly, school graduates from the academic track may more often attend university directly after high school instead of (first) opting for an apprenticeship when graduating in a recession.

Accounting for interactions

Arguably, the relationship of the apprenticeship wage and wage prospects and non-completion depends on timing, apprentice’s sex and level of education, and establishment size. Considering the timing of non-completion, the valuation of current and future wages may change while gathering information on the job. Furthermore, men and women may value monetary pay-offs differently. Lastly, the level of education and the size of the training establishment indicate outside options and future career chances. Therefore, it is reasonable to believe that the correlations of non-completion and apprenticeship wages and wages after completion depend on these characteristics. To investigate potential heterogeneity, a model is estimated, which includes interaction effects of \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\) with these variables.

Table 4 presents average marginal effects (AME) on the survival rate of a 1% increase in \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\), respectively, at different values of the interacting characteristics. Appendix: Table 9 presents the full results of this estimation. Note that the estimated average marginal effects of \(W/W^{(l)}\) and \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\) on the survival rate from the model in Table 3 (column 3) do not significantly differ when including interaction terms.Footnote 26 However, they do reveal some differences according to the interacting characteristics.

Table 4 Average marginal effects on the survival rate in % when accounting for interaction effects

The results suggest considerable heterogeneity. \(W/W^{(l)}\) has a larger association with the survival rate in the apprenticeship period between 212 and 425 days; this time window covers the transition to the second year of the apprenticeship, which comes along with an increase in the apprenticeship wage. A possible explanation: apprentices reevaluate whether apprenticeship wages appropriately develop over time depending on the job content.

Furthermore, the effect on the survival rate is significantly lower for women. Female apprentices may have higher thresholds of apprenticeship wages or are more affected than men by correlated non-pecuniary factors when considering non-completion.

Moreover, the relationship between \(W/W^{(l)}\) and the survival rate is lower for apprenticeships in larger establishments. Fewer profitable outside options, better perceived future employment possibilities, or other non-pecuniary benefits (like higher quality training programs and better support structures) may explain the lower association with the non-completion hazard.

The relationship between \(W/W^{(l)}\) and the survival rate is also less pronounced for apprentices with an academic track diploma (so-called Abitur). As previously explained, graduates from the academic track may use the apprenticeship system to continue to the academic system. Thus, for these apprentices apprenticeship wages and skilled worker wages may be less important when considering non-completion, because they may strive for jobs and respective pecuniary and non-pecuniary benefits at the academic level. Selection presents another explanation, if apprentices from the academic track, for example, select into apprenticeships, which grant more non-pecuniary benefits and a better employment outlook. In this case, other benefits may be more important than the apprenticeship wage.Footnote 27

Overall, the association of the apprenticeship wage and the non-completion hazard seems to depend on the apprentice’s and establishment’s characteristics; an increase in apprenticeship wages may not affect the non-completion hazard of each apprenticeship in the same way.

Concerning \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\), the estimated AMEs do not significantly differ by sex, level of education, or establishment size at the 5% level. However, the association of the survival rate with \(ln\text { }W^{(m)}\) seems to be much stronger in the first 121 days of an apprenticeship; i.e, in the trial period. A likely explanation lies in the speed with which apprentices gather information on the job, especially in regards to the expected wages after completion and their perceived adequacy in light of other job characteristics. Stronger associations of wages after completion and the survival rate during the trial period suggest that most of this information is, in fact, gathered early on, while the legal requirements for ending an apprenticeship are lower in order to move on to more suitable and profitable jobs. Hence, this finding underlines the importance of apprenticeship non-completion in the occupational choice process of young people.

Conclusion

The number of German apprentices, who terminate their apprenticeship early, has been growing for years. Although the literature has acknowledged this development, there still are substantial blind spots in regards to the determinants of apprenticeship non-completion. This paper closes a research gap by analyzing how non-completion is associated with apprenticeship wages and wage prospects after completion.

The paper identifies non-completion of apprenticeships in the SIAB data. Estimating piecewise exponential survival models with shared frailties by occupation, the results show a significant and robust negative association of both the apprenticeship wage and skilled worker wages with the non-completion hazard. The findings also suggest that apprenticeships, which pay 5% above average, have a 0.8 percentage points higher estimated survival rate on average. An apprenticeship leading to a skilled job that is paid 5% above average has an estimated survival rate that is 3.1 percentage points higher on average. Especially in light of the proposed policy for a minimum apprenticeship wage, the results could indicate that such a policy may be ineffective without paying attention to developments of skilled worker wages in occupations and industries, which suffer from high rates of apprenticeship non-completion.

Given the limitations of this paper, however, the results do not allow for a causal interpretation. Although many important parameters of the selection process (occupation, industry, prior education, establishment size, and apprenticeship market tightness) are controlled for, the results still cannot be fully separated from the effect of the selection of apprentices that initially chose the occupation. Furthermore, all results have to be understood in context of other unobserved factors, which are correlated with the apprenticeship wage and wages after completion; for instance the quality of apprenticeships or the task profile of the respective job. The results show a differential association of the apprenticeship wage and the non-completion hazard depending on apprentice’s sex and level of education and the size of the establishment. This indicates that wage policy is unlikely to affect all apprenticeships in the same manner. To shed light on the actual effectiveness of wage policies for the reduction of apprenticeship non-completion, further research is needed concerning the role of occupational sorting and the influence of non-pecuniary characteristics of apprenticeships.

Finally, the results indicate a stronger association of the wages after completion and the non-completion hazard in the first four month of an apprenticeship. This hints at the importance of how quickly apprentices gather information regarding future wages for non-completion and, thus, show that apprenticeship non-completion is a vital part of the occupational choice process of young people by directing them to more suitable (and more profitable) alternatives.