Skip to main content
Log in

Growth, innovation, credit constraints, and stock price bubbles

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the potential for rational bubbles in the innovation sector to affect long term economic growth. We show that stock market prices of research and development (R&D) firms can include a bubble component when credit constraints are present. Bubbles are self-sustained in equilibrium by a “liquidity” premium that originates when credit constraints are relaxed. Bubbles expand the borrowing and production capacities of R&D firms, stimulate innovation, and increase the growth rate. Small firms benefit more from bubbles than big firms. Bubbles are magnified by tighter credit constraints and scarce investment opportunities. Thus, financially underdeveloped countries benefit more from bubbles. Finally, we show that bubbles can create permanent reallocation effects that benefit the innovation sector over other sectors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Since we only want to provide a theoretical model to think about growth with bubbles and the numerical results are just used to show the mechanism of our model, we do not calibrate the model by using real data. These parameters are picked to generate BGPs which have a reasonable growth rate (1–5%). We do make sure that they are in the reasonable range. Notably, our results are robust qualitatively. We also do robustness tests in this paper.

References

  • Amable B, Chatelain J-B, Ralf K (2010) Patents as collateral. J Econ Dyn Control 34(6):1092–1104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2):323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Demirguc-Kunt A (2006) Small and medium-size enterprises: access to finance as a growth constraint. J Bank Finance 30(11):2931–2943

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown JR, Martinsson G, Petersen BC (2012) Do financing constraints matter for R&D. Eur Econ Rev 56(8):1512–1529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Farhi E, Hammour ML (2006) Speculative growth: hints from the U.S. economy. Am Econ Rev 96(4):1159–1192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordoba JC, Marla R (2004) Credit cycles redux. Int Econ Rev 45(4):1011–1046

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil PM (2013) Animal spirits and the composition of innovation in a lab-equipment R&D model with transition. J Econ 108(1):1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z, Frank L (1984) Interindustry technology flows and productivity growth: a reexamination. Rev Econ Stat 66(2):324–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Rev Econ Stud 58(1):43–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirano T, Yanagawa N (2017) Asset bubbles, endogenous growth, and financial frictions. Rev Econ Stud 84(1):406–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iacoviello M (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. Am Econ Rev 95(3):739–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki N, Moore J (1997) Credit cycles. J Polit Econ 105(2):211–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki N, Moore J (2005) Liquidity and asset prices. Int Econ Rev 46(2):317–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Z, Wang P, Zha T (2013) Land-price dynamics and macroeconomic fluctuations. Econometrica 81(3):1147–1184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin A, Ventura J (2012) Economic growth with bubbles. Am Econ Rev 102(6):3033–3058

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miao J, Wang P (2014) Sectoral bubbles, misallocation and endogenous growth. J Math Econ 53:153–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miao J, Wang P (2018) Asset bubbles and credit constraints. Am Econ Rev 108(9):2590–2628

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olivier J (2000) Growth-enhancing bubbles. Int Econ Rev 41(1):133–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98(5):71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1958) An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. J Polit Econ 66(6):467–482

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiller RJ (2015) Irrational exuberance. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sorescu A, Sorescu SM, Armstrong WJ, Devoldere B (2018) Two centuries of innovations and stock market bubbles. Market Sci 37(4):507–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorger G (2019) Bubbles and cycles in the Solow–Swan model. J Econ 127(3):193–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1982) On the possibility of speculation under rational expectations. Econometrica 50(5):1163–1181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1985) Asset bubbles and overlapping generations. Econometrica 53(6):1499–1528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zachariadis M (2003) R&D, innovation, and technological progress: a test of the Schumpeterian framework without scale effects. Can J Econ 36(3):566–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Z (2007) Innovation technological, turbulence market: the Dot-com experience. Rev Econ Dyn 10(1):78–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is a revised version of Chapter 2 of my Ph.D. dissertation. I thank Juan Carlos Cordoba for his valuable guidance. I am grateful to the anonymous referee and the editor for their insightful comments. I also thank Joydeep Bhattacharya, Rajesh Singh, Quinn Weninger, and participants of the 2019 Asian Meeting of the Econometric Society and 2019 China Meeting of the Econometric Society for their valuable advice. All errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sicheng He.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 6

Assume that the solution of R&D firm j’s problem is \(V_{t}\left( K_{t} ^{j}\right) =a_{t}K_{t}^{j}+B_{t}\). Substituting (6)–(9), and the solution we guess into (32), we have the following:

$$\begin{aligned} a_{t}K_{t}^{j}+B_{t}&=\max _{K_{t+1}^{j},K_{It+1}^{j},I_{t}^{j},B_{t}^{j} }\left( 1-\theta \right) r_{t}K_{t}^{j}+\left( 1-\theta \right) q_{t}\left( 1-\delta \right) K_{t}^{j}\\&\quad +\,\left( 1-\theta \right) \rho _{t+1}BB_{t+1}+\left( 1-\theta \right) (1-\pi ) \left[ -q_{t}K_{t+1}^{j}+\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1}K_{t+1}^{j}\right] \\&\quad +\,\left( 1-\theta \right) \pi \left[ \begin{array}{c} \left( q_{t}-1\right) \left( r_{t}K_{t}^{j}+\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1}\xi \left( 1-\delta \right) K_{t}^{j}+\rho _{t+1}B_{t+1}\right) \\ -q_{t}K_{It+1}^{j}+\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1}K_{It+1}^{j} \end{array} \right] \\&\quad +\,\theta a_{t}^{\#}K_{t}^{j} \end{aligned}$$

By taking first order derivative of \(K_{t+1}^{j}\), we have the following:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{t}=\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1} \end{aligned}$$

By comparing the left-hand and right-hand sides, we obtain the following:

$$\begin{aligned} a_{t}& {}= \left( 1-\theta \right) r_{t}+\left( 1-\theta \right) q_{t}\left( 1-\delta \right) +\left( 1-\theta \right) \pi \left( q_{t}-1\right) \left[ r_{t}+\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1}\xi \left( 1-\delta \right) \right] +\theta a_{t}^{\#}\\ B_{t}& {}= \left( 1-\theta \right) \left[ 1+\pi \left( q_{t}-1\right) \right] \rho _{t+1}B_{t+1} \end{aligned}$$

This is the proposition.

Appendix 2:Derivation of reallocation effects model

1.1 Households

The only difference is the budget constraints are now as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{t}+ {\int } \left( V_{t}^{j}-D_{t}^{j}\right) \psi _{t+1}^{j}dj= {\int } V_{t}^{j}\psi _{t}^{j}dj+W_{t}\overset{\_}{L}. \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Final goods producer

The technology is represented as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}=A \int \nolimits _{n=0}^{N_{t}} \left( X_{t}^{n}\right) ^{\sigma }(L_{t}^{Y})^{1-\sigma }dn,0<\sigma <1 \end{aligned}$$

Then, the profit maximization problem of the final goods producer, subject to the production function, is expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{X_{t}^{n},L_{t}^{Y}}A {\int \nolimits _{n=0}^{N_{t}}} \left( X_{t}^{n}\right) ^{\sigma }(L_{t}^{Y})^{1-\sigma }dn- {\int \nolimits _{n=1}^{N_{t}}} P_{t}^{n}X_{t}^{n}dn-W_{t}L_{t}^{Y} \end{aligned}$$

It is easy to solve the profit maximization problem, and we have the demand function for intermediate goods n as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}^{n}& {}= \sigma A\left( X_{t}^{n}\right) ^{\sigma -1}(L_{t}^{Y})^{1-\sigma }\\ W_{t}& {}= \left( 1-\sigma \right) A {\int \nolimits _{n=1}^{N_{t}}} \left( X_{t}^{n}\right) ^{\sigma }(L_{t}^{Y})^{-\sigma }dn. \end{aligned}$$

1.3 Intermediate goods producers

The intermediate goods producer n has the following profit:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( P_{t}^{n}-1\right) X_{t}^{n}=\sigma A\left( X_{t}^{n}\right) ^{\sigma }(L_{t}^{Y})^{1-\sigma }-X_{t}^{n} \end{aligned}$$

Since we already have the intermediate goods producer n’s demand function, we can find the price of goods that the intermediate goods producer n sets.

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}^{n}=\frac{1}{\sigma } \end{aligned}$$

The amount the producer produces is expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} X_{t}^{n}=\sigma ^{\frac{2}{1-\sigma }}A^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}L_{t} ^{Y} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Then, the profit of producing goods for producer n in every period is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{1-\sigma }{\sigma }\right) \sigma ^{\frac{2}{1-\sigma }}A^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}L_{t}^{Y} \end{aligned}$$

The discounted total profits from selling goods n must be equal to the license fee to produce goods n. This implies,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{s=t}^{\infty }\rho \left( s,t\right) \left( \frac{1-\sigma }{\sigma }\right) \sigma ^{\frac{2}{1-\sigma }}A^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}L_{t}^{Y}=\eta _{n}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(\rho \left( s,t\right) = {\prod \nolimits _{v=t+1}^{s}} \left( \rho _{v+1}\right)\) if \(s\ne t\), \(\rho \left( s,t\right) =1\) if \(s=t\). Since only variables in \(\eta _{n}\) are time varying, patents created in the same period have the same price. This result gives us the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{s=t}^{\infty }\rho \left( s,t\right) \left( \frac{1-\sigma }{\sigma }\right) \sigma ^{\frac{2}{1-\sigma }}A^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}L_{t}^{Y}=\eta _{n}=\eta _{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(36)

1.4 R&D sector

Same as the baseline model.

1.5 Competitive equilibrium

Definition 7

A competitive equilibrium is defined as allocations.

\(\left\{ Y_{t},K_{t},C_{t},I_{t},N_{t},E_{t}^{j},T_{t},L_{t}^{j},L_{t} ^{Y},I_{t}^{j},K_{t}^{j},T_{t}^{j},Y_{t}^{i},\psi _{t}^{j},X_{t}^{n}\right\}\) and prices

\(\left\{ w_{t},P_{n}^{t},R_{t}^{j},q_{t},\eta _{t},r_{t},V_{t}^{j}\right\}\) such that a household maximizes its utility, firms in all three sectors maximize their profits, and market clearing conditions are satisfied as follows: stock market is clearing \(\psi _{t}^{j}=1\), labor market is clearing \(\int _{0}^{1}L_{t}^{j}dj+L_{t}^{Y}=\overset{\_}{L}\), debt market is clearing \(\int _{0}^{1}E_{t}^{j}dj=0\), capital market is clearing \(K_{t+1}=\left( 1-\delta \right) K_{t}+I_{t}\), goods market is clearing \(C_{t}+\int _{n=0}^{N_{t}} {\int _{0}^{1}} X_{t}^{n}dn+I_{t}=Y_{t}\), and the amount of patent follows \(N_{t+1} =N_{t}+T_{t}\).

1.6 Detrended dynamic system

The detrended dynamic system now becomes:

$$\begin{aligned}&X_{t}=\sigma ^{\frac{2}{1-\sigma }}A^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}L_{t}^{Y}\\&\sum _{s=t}^{\infty }\rho \left( s,t\right) \left( \frac{1-\sigma }{\sigma }\right) \sigma ^{\frac{2}{1-\sigma }}A^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}L_{t}^{Y}=\eta _{n}=\eta _{t}\\&\rho _{t+1}=\beta \frac{c_{t}}{c_{t+1}\left( 1+g_{t+1}^{c}\right) }\\&r_{t}k_{t}=Z\eta _{t}\left( k_{t}\right) ^{\alpha }-w_{t}\left( \overset{\_}{L}-L_{t}^{Y}\right) \\&a_{t}=r_{t}+q_{t}\left( 1-\delta \right) +\pi \left( q_{t}-1\right) \left( r_{t}+\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1}\xi \left( 1-\delta \right) \right) \\&q_{t}=\rho _{t+1}a_{t+1} \\&b_{t}=\left[ 1+\pi \left( q_{t}-1\right) \right] \rho _{t+1}\left( 1+g_{t+1}\right) b_{t+1} \\&g_{t+1}^{N}=t_{t} \\&t_{t}=Zk_{t}^{\alpha }\left( \overset{\_}{L}-L_{t}^{Y}\right) ^{1-\alpha }\\&(1+g_{t+1}^{N})k_{t+1}=\left( 1-\delta \right) k_{t}+\pi r_{t}k_{t}+\pi \rho _{t+1}\left[ a_{t+1}\left( \xi \left( 1-\delta \right) \right) k_{t}+(1+g_{t+1}^{N})b_{t+1}\right] \\&r_{t}=\alpha \left( Z\eta _{t}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\alpha }}\left( \frac{w_{t}\left( \overset{\_}{L}-L_{t}^{Y}\right) ^{\alpha }}{1-\alpha }\right) ^{\frac{\alpha -1}{\alpha }}\\&c_{t}+X_{t}+\pi r_{t}k_{t}+\pi \rho _{t+1}\left[ a_{t+1}\left( \xi \left( 1-\delta \right) \right) k_{t}+(1+g_{t+1}^{N})b_{t+1}\right] =AX_{t} ^{\sigma }\\&w_{t}=\left( 1-\sigma \right) A\left( X_{t}\right) ^{\sigma }(L_{t} ^{Y})^{-\sigma } \end{aligned}$$

1.7 Stochastic bubbles burst

We also study the case when bubbles burst stochastically. The setting is similar to stochastic bubbles in the baseline model. We only report the simulation result here in Fig. 10. Similar to the relationship between stochastic and unanticipated bursts in baseline model, the pattern of both these bursts are similar. The intuition is also similar to the one discussed before.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Burst of stochastic bubbles in reallocation effects model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

He, S. Growth, innovation, credit constraints, and stock price bubbles. J Econ 133, 239–269 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00734-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00734-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation