Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The demise of the Roman Republic: a faulty constitution?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Roman Republic was one of the earliest and long-lasting democracies (510-27 BCE). To prevent the creation of dictatorship, it had a system of separation of powers but it failed to protect the Roman Republic. The ultimate cause of the fall of the Roman Republic was due to the immense wealth that Rome accumulated from its empire and the impact this wealth had on Rome’s institutions, especially its generals. Cicero proposed constitutional reforms to prevent its demise. His reforms were unnecessary because the Roman Senate already had the constitutional authority to prevent its demise. The problem was that Senators lacked an incentive to use their constitutional authority to save Rome’s democracy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is a debate as to the degree that the Roman Republic was a democracy. Syme (1939) argues that the democracy was a total facade for aristocratic rule. By contrast, Cicero, an elected official and keen observer of Roman life, clearly viewed the Roman Republic as a vibrant, but under attack, democracy.

  2. Before the Marius reforms, the armies were composed of farmers, who had to provide their own horse or armor. Hence, wealthy individuals were given higher rank.

  3. We do not know the average attendance at the Forum. Cicero indicates that it took about 5 hours to count the votes on legislation.

  4. Another unique Republic institution was that of Dictators. Dictators were elected and would serve for six months, or to the end of a military emergency. Their primary responsibility was to defend the Republic when it faced an external threat. They were absolute rulers with the authority to execute individuals, without trials, and to abrogate laws. This institution atrophied in use after the Punic Wars, because Rome no longer had a credible external threat. However, Sulla and Julius Caesar resuscitated the office and demanded that they be elected dictators for life, because of the extensive powers of dictators.

  5. This system gradually evolved over the nearly five hundred years of the Roman Republic. Hence, there is no single Roman Constitution, but a series of Roman Constitutions (Flower 2010). I focus on the Constitution as operative in the time of Cicero, and discuss historical changes only to the extent they impact my analysis.

  6. Cicero’s interpretation is common among Roman historians. Parenti (2003) goes so far as to argue that Caesar was a supporter of the plebians, and this is the reason he was assassinated by members of the Senate. However, Caesar cut the bread dole of the plebes in half, and forced many to relocate in Spain. Hence, most modern historians argue that the political competition was between elites over power and money (Dunstan 2010; Mouritsen 2001, 2017).

    Brunt (1988) and Mackay (2009) expand on Cicero’s list of opponents of the Senate to include the Italian allies. They fought in the Roman army, but did not get equal compensation with that of the Roman legions. But again, Cicero’s reforms of the Republic’s constitution would not have affected this problem, because the Senate already had the authority over military expenditures.

    I cannot in this paper resolve this dispute among Roman historians.

  7. The assassins of Caesar did not confiscate Caesar’s wealth, and hence, Octavian inherited it, and used Caesar’s wealth to defeat the assassins.

  8. Augustus understood the problem of controlling the military and government administration. He instituted a number of reforms to maintain power. He paid legionnaires out of government revenues and expanded the military to 26 legions, with no general commanding more than two legions. He also instituted the Praetorian guard for his personal protection (Wasson 2018). Furthermore, he created a permanent civil service and increased taxes to pay for these reforms (Eck, 2003; Salmon, 1962.)

  9. The relation of the Roman government with fellow Latin tribes varied over time. A crucial strategy employed by Rome was to conquer fellow Latin tribes and rule them at a distance. The conquered tribes were required to provide soldiers for the Roman armies. But they did not share in the booty from conquests and did not receive the rights of Roman citizenship. This relationship led to a series of rebellions by the Latin tribes (Samnites, Marsi and other Latin tribes and cities) referred to as the Social Wars (91-87 BCE). Rome defeated the rebelling tribes but conferred full Roman citizenship, including voting rights in the assemblies, to avoid future rebellions

  10. Buchanan and Tullock (1999) argue that the advantage of a bicameral legislature is that it approximates a supermajority vote.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 93863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorships and democracy. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Suresh N., Pascual, R., Robinson, J. A. (2014). Democracy Does Cause Growth? Paper presented at the 2014 AEA meetings.

  • Astin, A. (1985). “Cicero and the Censorship.” Classical Philology, 80(3), 233–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beard, M., & Crawford, M. (1999). Rome in the Late Republic (2nd ed.). Gerald Duckworth & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, K. (2011). Slavery in the Roman Republic. In K. Bradley & P. Cartledge (Eds.), The Cambridge World History of Slavery Vol. 1: The Ancient Mediterranean World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brunt, P. A. (1988). The fall of the Roman Republic. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunt, P. A., & Moore, J. M. (Eds.). (1967). Res GestaeDiviAugusti: The achievements of the divine augustus. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J., Gordon T. [1962] 1999. The Calculus of Consent: The Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. In The collected works of James M. Buchanan. Vol 3. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Chinard, G. (1940). Polybius and the American constitution. Journal of the History of Ideas, 1(1/4), 38–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. (2000). The strategic constitution. Princeton.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. R. (1964). Cicero and the Roman Republic. Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Blois, L. (1987). The Roman army and politics in the first century before christ. J.C. Gieben.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, L. (2016). Democracy in Decline: How Washington Can Reverse the Tide. Foreign Affairs, 95(4), 151–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, L. (1999). Developing democracy: toward consolidation. Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunstan, W. (2010). Ancient Rome. Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eck, W. (2003). The age of augustus. Blackwell Pub.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrill, A. (1977). Caesars private fortune: wealth and politics in the late Roman Republic. Indiana Social Studies Quarterly, 30, 101–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flower, H. (2010). Roman Republics. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldsworthy, A. (2011). The complete Roman army. Thames and Hudson Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawthorn, J. R. (1962). The senate after sulla. Greece & Rome, 9(1), 53–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holland, T. (2003). Rubicon: The Last Years of the Roman Republic. Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karl, T. L. (1997). The paradox of plenty: Oil booms and petro-States. University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Keaveney, A. (2007). The army in the Roman revolution. Routledge Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Keppie, L. (1998). The making of the Roman army, from Republic to Empire. Oklahoma University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keyes, C. W. (1921). Original elements in Ciceros ideal constitution. The American Journal of Philology, 42, 301–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levi, M. (1988). Of Rule and Revenue. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitsky, S., & Ziblatt, D. (2018). How democracies die. Crown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lintott, A. W. (1999). The constitution of the Roman Republic. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linz, J., & Stepan, A. (1996). Problems of democratic transition and consolidation. Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackay, C. (2009). The breakdown of the Roman Republic: from oligarchy to empire. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesquieu, C. [1748] 1950. De l’Esprit des Loix. (Avec Jean Brethe de La Gressaye, Editeur Scientific). Vol 1–4. Paris: Les Belles Lettres (Impr. de Bellenand).

  • Morley, N. (2011). Slavery under the principate. In K. Bradley & P. Carledge (Eds.), The Cambridge world history of slavery, Vol. 1: The Ancient Mediterranean World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mouritsen, H. (2001). Plebs and politics in the late Roman Republic. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mouritsen, H. (2017). Politics in the Roman Republic. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: evolution of the institutions governing public choice in 17th century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 80332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, J. (2010). The Roman constitution. In N. Rosenstein & M. M. Robert (Eds.), A Companion to the Roman Republic. Wiley-Blackwell: Chichester UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parenti, M. (2003). The assassination of Julius Caesar: A peoples history of ancient Rome. The New Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plutarch (1921). Lives. Tiberius and Gaius Gracchus. Loeb Classical Library 102: 144–45. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

  • Ross, M. L. (1999). The political economy of the resource curse. World Politics, 51(2), 297322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J., Warner, A.M. (1995). Natural resource abundance and economic growth. NBER Working Papers 5398, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Salmon, E. (1962). A history of the Roman world from 30 BC to AD 170. Methuen and Co., Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W. (2015). The early Roman monarchy. In M. Andrew & S. Walter (Eds.), Fiscal regimes and the political economy of premodern states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W. (1997). Quantifying the sources of slaves in the early Roman empire. The Journal of Roman Studies, 87(1997), 156–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shatzman, I. (1972). The Roman general's authority over booty. Historia: Zeitschrift für Alte Geschichte, Bd. 21, H. 2 (2nd Qtr.): 177–205.

  • Straumann, B. (2016). Crisis and constitutionalism: Roman political thought from the fall of the Republic to the age of revolution. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Syme, R. (1939). The Roman revolution. The Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tan, J. (2015). The Roman Republic. In M. Andrew & S. Walter (Eds.), Fiscal Regimes and the Political Economy of Premodern States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Leeuw, S. (1993). Decision-making in the Roman empire during the Republic. Memoires du Musee de Prehistoire d’Ile-de-France, #5.

  • Wasson, D. L. (2018). Roman emperor. Ancient History Encyclopedia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson, G.R. (1958). The Pay of the Roman Army, Historia: Zeitschrift für Alte Geschichte, Bd. 7, H. 1 (1st Qtr.): 113–120.

  • Yakobson, A. (2017). Cicero, the constitution and the Roman people. Ancient History Bulletin (3 and 4): 157–77.

  • Zetzel, J. (2013). Political Philosophy. In Catherine Steel (Ed.), The Cambridge Companion to Cicero. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zetzel, J. (Ed.). (1999). Cicero: On the Commonwealth and On the Laws. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard Jankowski.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jankowski, R. The demise of the Roman Republic: a faulty constitution?. Const Polit Econ 32, 218–232 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-021-09330-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-021-09330-0

Keywords

Navigation