1 Introduction: General and Sector-specific Corporate Governance

1.1 Corporate Governance of Private Listed Corporations

Corporate governance has become a key topic in international practice and economic and legal theory.Footnote 1 The definitions of corporate governance vary. Corporate governance is certainly not just corporate law.Footnote 2 The short-form definition used by the Cadbury Commission in 1992 is to the point and internationally agreed upon: Corporate governance refers to ‘the system by which companies are directed and controlled’.Footnote 3 Direction and control can come from inside or outside. Internal corporate governance refers to government and control by the organs of the corporations, the board in the one-tier system or the management and supervisory boards in the two-tier system. Accordingly, it is hardly astonishing that much of the corporate governance literature deals with the board.Footnote 4 External corporate governance can be understood as the disciplinary effects exercised in particular by the takeover market on the directors but also, to a certain degree, effects exercised by the markets for directors, products and services.Footnote 5 External corporate governance is weaker for financial institutions than for corporations in general since there is no well-developed market for corporate control as regards financial institutions. Until recently, takeovers did not have a significant corporate control effect for banks,Footnote 6 at least not in Europe. Yet under the pressure of globalization, shrinking returns, digitalization and in particular fierce competition from non-bank institutions, this may change soon.

1.2 Other Varieties of Corporate Governance for Other Enterprises and Sectors (Non-listed, State-owned, Non-profit, Insolvency, Banking and Insurance)

Corporate governance was first developed as a concept and field of research for private listed corporations. This was due to the self-regulatory efforts of stock exchanges and other private institutions that either had certain requirements for admission or set up recommendations on good corporate governance, usually with corporate governance codes, sometimes with the help of the comply or explain-principle set up by legislators. The idea of developing corporate governance standards spread quickly to other sectors, such as to non-listed companies (among them in particular family companies,Footnote 7 state-owned enterprises (SOEs) with public corporate governance codes,Footnote 8 non-profit organizations and foundationsFootnote 9), insolvent companies and companies in serious financial crisisFootnote 10; the notion of corporate governance was also extended to banks, insurance companies and other financial institutions such as rating agencies.Footnote 11 While corporate governance principles for listed corporations have been and are still a major source of inspirations for corporate governance in these other sectors, there is very little cross-fertilization as regards the corporate governance efforts in these other sectors. Therefore, this article basically compares the governance of financial institutions—with banks taken as an example—with general corporate governance, and it will make the point that the corporate governance of banks is different in many respects.

1.3 ‘Banks are Special’: Particular Economic Features of Banks and Other Financial Institutions

The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, the world’s leading authority on banking regulation and banking supervision, begins its 2015 Guidelines on Corporate Governance Principles for Banks with the words: ‘Effective corporate governance is critical to the proper functioning of the banking sector and the economy as a whole.’Footnote 12 The corporate governance of banks and other financial institutionsFootnote 13 has gained much attention after the financial crisis.Footnote 14 From 270 economic and legal submissions from 2012 to 2016 in the ECGI Working Paper Series of the European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI), roughly half address corporate governance questions, and more than a quarter of these look at the regulation and corporate governance of banks (in the broad sense).Footnote 15 The financial crisis certainly contributed to this, yet whether the financial crisis can really be attributed mainly to financial institutions’ shortcomings in corporate governance, as some authors assert, is doubtful.Footnote 16

In theory, practice and supervision, it is a truism that banks are special as compared to non-banking institutions. This is the very basis for the targeted regulation and supervision of banking as a regulated industry. The unique aspects of banks include the very low capitalization of banks as compared to non-banking entities (particularly when short and long financial maturity periods are matched); the complexity and non-transparency of banks’ business activities and structures; the fundamental need for trust and the associated danger of bank runs; and in particular the macroeconomic function of banks as manifested in their central importance for the economy, which in turn gives rise to their being subject to far-reaching legislation and state regulation.Footnote 17 Their uniqueness is reflected in frequently recurring banking crises and the structural flaw whereby banks are seen as ‘too big to fail’ and ‘too interconnected to fail’, such that state rescue is needed whenever a bail-in is either not an option or proves ineffective.Footnote 18 One cannot dispute that these unique characteristics are of course of particular importance for systemically important banks (SIFIs). But they are not limited to such entities. Instead these attributes are of more general relevance, even if they are naturally more consequential and visible in the case of SIFIs.Footnote 19

It is hardly astonishing that these special characteristics of banks demand, in turn, a special variety of corporate governance. Yet what is surprising is that particular attention to this has traditionally been absent and that economic research as to the special governance of banks has commenced relatively late. One of the earliest contributions to the field dates from the 1980s.Footnote 20 Several factors seem to have contributed to this delay in research. Empirical studies, found mostly in US academic literature, usually focused on the principal-agent dilemma and were oriented on the conflict between directors and shareholders, this corresponding to the US shareholder structure (mostly dispersed shareholdings and relatively few major block-holdings).Footnote 21 Consequently, given this focus and in accord with the available data, the natural object of inquiry tended to be publicly-traded companies. Even where banks were the topic of inquiry, earlier studies focused on principal-agent theory as framed by studies in non-banking contexts. By contrast, empirical studies looking specifically at corporate governance in the banking context—and demonstrating the unique characteristics which ensue—are only a more recent development. In the context of this present paper, only a few important findings can be discussed.Footnote 22

Fahlenbrach and StulzFootnote 23 report that worse results were achieved by bank CEO’s whose actions were primarily motivated by shareholder interests. Similar findings were reached by Beltratti and StulzFootnote 24 as regards bank boards. Banks with shareholder-friendly boards had significantly poorer results. According to other studies, the composition and characteristics of bank boards had significant effects,Footnote 25 and boards with relatively higher shareholder representation undertook more and greater risks.Footnote 26 Apparently bank boards charted a course more aligned with the preferences of shareholders,Footnote 27 who—if sufficiently diversified in their holdings—embrace risk more readily than, for instance, a bank’s creditors.Footnote 28 Beltratti und Stulz thus doubt the hypothesis that bad corporate governance was a significant cause of the financial crisis.Footnote 29 Banks with independent boards were run more poorly.Footnote 30 Banks that were controlled by shareholders saw higher profits before the crisis as compared to banks that were controlled by directors.Footnote 31 Enterprises in which institutional investors held stocks correspondingly fared worse.Footnote 32 In general, studies showed that the shareholder structure of a bank correlated strongly to the bank’s insolvency, particularly where low-level management was significantly involved in the decision-making process.Footnote 33

These and further empirical studies suggest that it is erroneous to conclude that traditional—even if empirically established—approaches to the corporate governance of corporations can be seamlessly applied to the corporate governance of banks; in fact, exactly the opposite may be true. This is the case, for example, as regards director independence, which according to recent studies can carry negative effects also in the case of non-financial corporations,Footnote 34 whereas expertise and experience are of much greater value, at least when obvious conflicts of interest are avoided. Still, it bears emphasis that sound judgment is called for when evaluating empirical findings. Often, findings warranting a differentiated assessment are held up against one another despite their embodying nuanced differences that may reflect a dissimilar time horizon in the studies, an inadequate account of the interdependence of certain factors and, above all, country- and path-dependent differences resulting from legal regulation and cultural circumstances.Footnote 35

2 Governance of Banks and Financial Institutions in Supervisory Law and Practice

2.1 The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision: The Guidelines, Corporate Governance Principles for Banks, 2015

The Basel Committee has issued the authoritative Guidelines on Corporate governance principles for banks, released in a revised version in July 2015.Footnote 36 The Guidelines, while underlining the jurisdictional differences and the necessity of proportionality and differences in governance approaches, set out 13 major principles in respect of banks’ corporate governance. They concern (1) The overall responsibilities of boards, (2) Board qualification and composition, (3) The structure and practices of boards, (4) Senior management, (5) Governance and group structures, (6) Risk management functions, (7) Risk identification, monitoring and control, (8) Risk communication, (9) Compliance, (10) Internal audits, (11) Compensation, (12) Disclosure and transparency and (13) The role of supervisors. This list sounds familiar to someone who is accustomed to dealing with corporate law and corporate governance, though already at first glance Principle 4 on senior management and Principle 13 on the role of supervisors are special for bank governance. As in corporate governance of non-banking entities, the board is at the center of the attention. But the demands on its composition, qualification, responsibilities and practices are much higher than for non-bank corporations. The risks a bank runs are of course very special. Accordingly the requirements concerning the bank board’s governing and controlling functions are spelt out in considerable detail and are much more demanding. So are the disclosure and transparency requirements. It is interesting to see that a special principle is devoted to the governance of group structures, groups of companies being subject to special legal treatment in only some countries (like Germany), while in others they are not recognized as a special area in corporate law and governance.Footnote 37 The Guidelines do not have the character of legally binding norms, but they spell out in detail what rules banks should observe.Footnote 38

2.2 Principles and Guidelines of Other Supervisory Institutions (European Banking Authority 2016/17, the Financial Stability Board 2017 and Similar National Supervisory Agencies In and Outside of the European Union)

The crisis resulted in many other international institutions adopting recommendations, supervisory measures and regulations in the area of corporate governance as regards the banking industry. Though scarcely addressed by academic authors, many of these instruments and schemes are now in their second or even third generation, e.g. the Guidelines on internal governance of the European Banking Authority (EBA) of 2017,Footnote 39 the Joint ESMA and EBA Guidelines from 2017,Footnote 40 the report of the Financial Stability Board (April 2017),Footnote 41 the Guidelines of the European Central Bank of 2018Footnote 42—and those of similar national supervisory agencies, for example the Swiss FINMA (September 2016)Footnote 43 or the German Federal Financial Supervisory Agency (BaFin 2016/2017)Footnote 44—and for the insurance companies the International Association of Insurance Supervisors (November 2015).Footnote 45

2.3 CRD IV, National Bank Supervisory Laws, Legal and Policy Analyses

The concepts and recommendations of the Basel Committee made their way not only into the principles and guidelines of other international and national supervisory institutions, but also into the bank supervisory law of the Member States of the European Union via the Capital Requirements Directive (CRD IV).Footnote 46 Further, via the Solvency II Directive,Footnote 47 they entered similarly into the Member States’ supervisory law of insurance companies.

Accordingly, as to the academic literature, much of it is just a doctrinal legal presentation and a commentary-like treatment of the actual supervisory law in the various Member States. A significant amount of the literature deals with the European law in the CRD IVFootnote 48—as well as in Solvency II and regarding its implementation for insurance supervision—looking particularly at supervisory boards/boards of directors/CEOs, most of it purely de lege lata,Footnote 49 but at times based more on functional legal policy considerations. It is true that there are some authors who question the whole approach of the Basel III regulation, but this is due to fundamentally different views towards regulation.Footnote 50 In any case, there is criticism of over-regulation as voiced by the industry, and a large number of academic authors rightly join in the latter’s complaints.Footnote 51 The provisions drafted by legislators, supervisory agencies and international bodiesFootnote 52 are indeed increasingly detailed; while these provisions are, legally speaking, only persuasive in nature, they are de facto more or less binding. Yet despite often being adopted in the wake of corporate scandalsFootnote 53 and while frequently tending to overshoot the target, regulation remains both unavoidable and indispensable.

The interplay between stock corporation law, bank supervisory law and insurance supervisory law in corporate governance is considered more rarely.Footnote 54 Yet there is a basic agreement on the necessity of taking note of the similarity of supervisory problems in the separate fields as well as of trying to harmonize rules whenever the problems are functionally similar, while maintaining different rules and regulations when the risks and features are different. Cross-sectoral regulation is needed.Footnote 55 Some have rightly observed that a European bank corporation law is gradually developing in its own right, and these authors ask what effect the European banking union will have on the governance of credit institutions.Footnote 56 Corporate governance of banks may even pave the way to a self-contained law covering financial intermediaries and their corporate governance.

3 Shareholder, Stakeholder or Creditor Governance: The Controversies Regarding the Purpose of Corporations and Banks

3.1 Shareholder or Stakeholder Governance: The German Experience and the American and European Discussion on the Purpose of Corporations

The purpose of corporations is an old and controversial topic. The classic approach is the one that prevails in the United States: the purpose of a corporation is to make profit for the shareholders. On the other side of the spectrum stands Germany. There, the board is responsible to promote the interests of all stakeholders, i.e. the shareholders, labor and the public good. While the shareholder-oriented approach had gained some attention also in Germany before the financial crisis, the traditional stakeholder concept is still generally agreed upon. The labor interest is even further consolidated by the mandatory labor co-determination at parity in the supervisory board. Other European states, such as the United Kingdom, follow a middle way with the so-called enlightened shareholder approach, a shareholder orientation that also looks at the interests of other stakeholders in view of preserving a long-term profitability of the firm (Europe).Footnote 57 But in the United Kingdom this concept is increasingly criticized as too vague and hardly effective. It is of note that most recently even in the United States there has been a tendency towards having more regard for the full spectrum of stakeholders’ interest, as promulgated by the business roundtable statement in 2019.Footnote 58 Yet whether this non-binding declaration of many American business leaders will really amount to a change in practice remains to be seen. In any case, in times and terms of financial rescue and insolvency proceedings, it has been recognized that risk together with governance (‘ownership’) is transferred from the owners to the creditors.Footnote 59

3.2 Towards Creditor or Debtholder Governance for Banks

As regards bank corporations and financial institutions, the case is clearly different. Empirical findings, the experience of the financial crisis, and economic and legal conclusions have produced a change in perspective that amounts to a theory of creditor (i.e. debtholders and depositors) governance.Footnote 60 The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision’s benchmark guidelines, the Corporate Governance Principles for Banks from July 2015, state at the very beginning: ‘The primary objective of corporate governance should be safeguarding stakeholders’ interest in conformity with public interest on a sustainable basis. Among stakeholders, particularly with respect to retail banks, shareholders’ interest would be secondary to depositors’ interest.’Footnote 61 This corresponds to the standing supervisory practice of other national and international banking agencies too.

This position is a clear rejection of the shareholder primacy view, but it differs also from the only slightly tempered view held in Europe, since banks are expected to consider creditor interest not only when this is in the long-term interest of the corporation.Footnote 62 Creditor governance is not just a question of the purpose of bank corporations, instead having consequences in many other areas regarding the corporate governance of banks. In particular this view reduces also the relative importance of controlling shareholders, institutional investors and shareholder control in general, as is presently the center of attention in the corporate governance of (non-bank) corporations.Footnote 63

3.3 Implications for Research and Reform: Self- or Co-Regulation, Mandatory Transparency, State Regulation

Along with the theoretical assessment of corporate governance of banks and financial institutions as creditor governance, there comes the task of examining the various problems associated with corporate governance—which, as regards (non-financial) corporations, have been comprehensively considered in international practice and academic literatureFootnote 64—and to determine what this implies for the corporate governance of banks and financial institutions. This is a comprehensive task, for which here only a few benchmarks can be given and for which some examples can be given in Sect. 4, below. This should be reflected in a research agendaFootnote 65 that is jointly devised and pursued by economists and jurists and perhaps representatives from other disciplines.Footnote 66 Before examining what the new look means for a number of regulatory core issues of banking, its relevance for two more general regulatory approaches should briefly be mentioned: self-regulation and regulation by transparency.

As to self-regulation of banks,Footnote 67 experience in the financial sector is rather mixed.Footnote 68 In Germany voluntary codes for insider trading did not work; in the end European legislators had to step in. The same was true when the German Takeover Commission adopted a voluntary takeover code. A considerable number of German enterprises did not comply with it, and their free-riding forced the German legislature to intervene with the German Takeover Act. The German Central Bank went through a similar experience when the European transborder bank group regulation was not yet in sight and the Bank tried to regulate with mere ‘moral suasion’. But there is no rule without exception. In the Netherlands, in addition to European and Dutch banking regulations, the corporate governance of banks is further enhanced by a voluntary bankers’ code of conduct which has been set up by the banking community itself (Dutch Banking Code).Footnote 69 Even a bankers’ oath similar to the Hippocratic Oath is foreseen, an oath that is reported to have been taken by around 90,000 bank employees. Some voices had been supporting a similar experiment in Germany,Footnote 70 but the German banking association shied away for two reasons. First, they argued that banking legislation is already tough enough, maybe too tough, and, second, they feared that the legislature might turn parts of the code into binding law. Yet it seems obvious that mere voluntary self-regulation is not enough. Honesty in the banking industry—as a product of the existing business culture—is alarmingly low, as an empirical study by Fehr and others, published in Nature, has established.Footnote 71 There is a case at least for co-regulation between the banking industry and state supervision.Footnote 72

Transparency and disclosure are traditional instruments serving shareholder and creditor protection. The two aims are usually linked, particularly since investors can be both shareholders and creditors. Transparency plays an especially significant role for banks and financial institutions. The Basel Committee holds in its Principle 12 on Disclosure and Transparency: ‘The governance of the bank should be adequately transparent to its shareholders, depositors, other relevant stakeholders and market participants.’Footnote 73 Yet here transparency has—unlike with companies—an additional function, namely keeping supervisory bodies informed, as it minimizes their need to intervene or facilitates a more targeted intervention.Footnote 74 Particularly with banking groups, complex and opaque structures give rise to risk; in the wake of the banking crises such structures have recurrently led to requirements of greater transparency.Footnote 75 More disclosure can of course conflict with the need for secrecy, and public transparency may not produce exclusively positive consequences.Footnote 76 Nevertheless, where not excessive and where account is had of the differences between the addressees (inter alia, regarding their size, complexity, structure, economic significance and risk structure), transparency and disclosure are in fact more market-friendly instruments than mandatory legislation and state supervision.Footnote 77

4 Regulatory Core Issues for the Corporate Governance of Banks and Financial Institutions

4.1 Composition and Qualification of the (One-tier or Two-Tier) Board: Enhancing Independent Control

Enhancing independent control by targeting the composition of bank boardsFootnote 78 in the interest of creditors would be the most structured intervention. This could be done either directly by having creditors sitting on the board or indirectly by having somebody else entrusted with taking care of their interests.Footnote 79

Since creditors are less risk-prone than shareholders, it might indeed make sense to have them sitting in bank boards.Footnote 80 Actually, this is what several economists have proposed following the financial crisis, among them Martin Hellwig, the well-known bank economist from the Bonn Max Planck Institute. The proposal recalls earlier considerations for seating a public interest representative on the board,Footnote 81 an idea that was never adopted because the public interest is hard to grasp and such a representative may easily be captured by politics. It is true that creditor interest is more specific and that bondholders might indeed have an interest in moderating the risk-taking by a bank. Yet in view of the German co-determined boards, giving creditors one or more seats in the board could only further split up the board at the expense of the shareholder side and endanger the difficult balance between capital and labor within the board, possibly with limits under the German Constitution.

Another idea would be to entrust the labor side or one of the labor representatives with specifically taking care also of the creditors’ interests. Yet experiences with co-determination in companies suggest that workers do not view themselves as representing the interests of other creditors, neither internally within the company nor externally as unions; rather, the workforce recognizes and heeds its own specific interests.

Then why not give the bank supervisors a regular seat in the bank boards?Footnote 82 This idea has indeed been brought forward in the discussion. At first glance it looks good. After all, it is the supervisors’ official responsibility to protect the interest of debtholders, and they could make sure that the risks assumed by the bank are raised and considered in the board. But three arguments stand against this. First, the bank supervisors already now have the right to take part in the sessions and deliberations of the board if they consider it necessary for their supervisory work. Second, regular board membership for the supervisors would create a serious conflict of interest since they would have to oversee as supervisors what they co-decided as board members. Third, the reform would have consequences for the liability of supervisors, which up to now the legislature has strictly avoided.

Another route for influencing the composition of bank boards would be making more specific use of independent directors. The conventional wisdom is that independent directors are indispensable for overseeing the executive directors in the interest of the shareholders—a belief that, as we have seen, had its origins in the USA and Great Britain, namely countries with typically dispersed shareholding—though the cure-all quality ascribed to independent directors has significantly abated in recent years.Footnote 83 Yet for banks empirical research has suggested that the independence of management or supervisory bank board members is—setting aside conflicts of interests—of far less importance than expert knowledge and experience.Footnote 84 An apparent exception relates to audit and risk committees, for which independence plays a major role.Footnote 85 The data show that for most large international banks board independence does not constrain bank risk-taking.Footnote 86 Qualifications and expertise stand clearly in the foreground of the official recommendations and the supervisory practice too.Footnote 87 Accordingly, even for independent directors, bank supervisors attach more importance to independent judgment rather than to the possession of an independent background.Footnote 88

The composition of bank boards is special when it comes to banks that are totally or partially owned by the state or other public authorities (SOEs).Footnote 89 In Germany there is a particular experience with the state banks (Landesbanken) dating back to the financial crisis. While the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision has offered only cursory comments in this regard,Footnote 90 the empirical findings are unequivocal. Specifically, significant influence exercised by public authorities is accompanied with a negative impact on the quality of corporate governance in banks and financial institutions as well as on their performance.Footnote 91 This holds especially true when organ members are appointed less for their expertise than for political affiliation or for similar other reasons. Thus an empirical study looking at the profile of twenty-nine of the largest banks during the financial crisis showed that public banks, primarily Landesbanken, experienced three times greater losses than banks having private shareholders between the first quarter of 2007 and the third quarter of 2008. The supplementary study focusing on the biographies of 593 supervisory board members from these public banks revealed that their experience in management and finance was systematically less than the level seen in private banks. The correlation between losses, on the one hand, and reduced qualifications and experience, on the other, was highly significant statistically and suggested causation.Footnote 92 More generally the relationship between the state and firms, specifically banks, can lead to harmful dependencies and interactions. In particular there is the danger of regulatory capture.Footnote 93 While this danger may be less acute for bank supervisors who after the financial crises are under close observation of the financial press, the general public and legislators, it may still become a problem. As the state is expected to regulate and supervise banks more closely, an inquiry into the economic effects of this symbiotic relationship between the state and the banks becomes even more essential.Footnote 94

4.2 Duties and Liabilities and the Pay of Bank Directors, Senior Managers and Key Function Holders; Bank Groups

As compared to corporations in general,Footnote 95 the duties imposed on the organs of banks are stricter, much more detailed and of a mandatory nature.Footnote 96 This is true particularly since the financial crisis. European and Member State supervisory practice as to the bank boards is far-reaching and demanding. Of primary concern are, rightly, risk management and compliance.Footnote 97 But regulation and supervision also cover organizational and operational issues (as addressed by various committees—particularly a risk committeeFootnote 98). More recently, the compensation of bank directors has become a hot issue. Quite apart from societal concerns, the regulatory aim here is to avoid misplaced incentives.Footnote 99 There is, as well, an appreciation of the unique dangers of banking groups,Footnote 100 such as interconnectedness, loss of confidence and bank runs. For this reason the current mass of bank group regulation is considerably more exacting than that which is applicable to corporate groups generally.Footnote 101

In view of all this, proposals such as stricter personal director liabilityFootnote 102 are not really convincing; other better-aimed, organizational and systemic measures may be more effective. But another, more promising proposal has just been made for directors, not specifically bank directors.Footnote 103 Under the proposed scheme directors would be liable for compliance failures, but limited in quantum to a proportionate clawback of stock-based pay. This system could be introduced by bank legislators or by shareholder proposals or judicial innovation. The authors call this a ‘compliance clawback’. Under German law this is not a novelty, and it can be found already in practice. The recent German act on strengthening shareholder rights in accord with the European Shareholder Rights Directive IIFootnote 104 provides for mandatory disclosure on whether and how the corporation has actually made use of the possibility to claw back variable components of the remuneration of directors.Footnote 105

For corporations, the focus of corporate governance and stock corporation law is clearly on the board, be it the one-tier board or the management and the supervisory boards. Second or third-tier management levels are left exclusively to labor and labor law. This compartmentalization of legislation and research may work for corporations in general, but certainly not for banks and other financial institutions. The financial crisis has shown that many of the abuses at the forefront of the bank business have been perpetrated by dealers and advisors acting below the board level. Solely requiring the board to organize and monitor bank personnel is not enough to prevent excessive risk-taking. Bank managers who are actually undertaking risky business must be addressed directly. In particular, risk-enhancing incentives such as certain bonus structures must be avoided. This is why under bank governance and banking regulation, senior management and key function holdersFootnote 106 as such are covered by recommendations and governance requirements. It is true that this may be in conflict with labor law that, at least in Europe, to a large degree shields employees from personal liability. But either bank governance rules should prevail or a legal solution for this conflict must be found.

4.3 Enforcement: Civil, Penal and Administrative Sanctions, Private Enforcement

In the general discussion on corporate governance, the questions of enforcement and control are assigned a central importance.Footnote 107 This corresponds to an increased orientation in literature and research not merely on substantive company and banking law questions, but also to problems related to procedural law and insolvency law insofar as corporations are concerned. In the area of banking law, one even speaks of a shift from banking contract law to bank supervisory law and bank regulation. Yet based on the above-mentioned empirical findings, this simply does not correspond to more enforcement by shareholdersFootnote 108 (specifically by large shareholders, institutional investors and hedge funds—all of which are currently at the center of the corporate governance discussion—and notwithstanding the current attempt to subject institutional investors to mandatory rules of conduct or non-binding codes of conduct).Footnote 109 But also a conclusion to impose legal obligations on the creditors—in the place of investors—would be inadequate since that would mean merely shifting the problem from one group of stakeholders onto another. Small creditors like small investors have a rational disinterest, particularly when they are protected by deposit guarantees. Bond creditors as well have only a limited potential and interest in influencing and monitoring the corporate governance of issuers.Footnote 110 The internationally customary covenants found in the terms and conditions of a loan are not much help in this regard either.Footnote 111 Large investors such as banks hold a variety of security agreements and thus, outside of the situation of insolvency, generally have little incentive to intervene. The previously existing network of financial relationships (Deutschland-AG) and the principal banking system (Hausbankensystem) have largely been dismantled.Footnote 112 What remains is control by state supervision: specifically bank and insurance supervisory control, that—functioning much like a trustee for debtholders and depositors—(i) must ensure the effectiveness and enforceability of corporate governance rules, (ii) must possess the necessary competence and be capable of imposing sanctions,Footnote 113 and (iii) must have specialized certified bank auditors at its disposal.Footnote 114 To this we can add the energetic application of the fit-and-proper standard and disqualification.Footnote 115 But by the same token, it is vital that supervisory regulations do not smother the board; rather, under the mantra of co-regulation, a certain discretion should be afforded the board so as to allow for independent, internal enforcement.Footnote 116

In addition to this, there might also be a role for banks’ own codes of conduct—whether internal or applicable for the entire sector—as is shown, for instance, by the Dutch Banking CodeFootnote 117 and as is highly recommended by institutions such as the Basel Committee, the EBA and the FSB.Footnote 118 Here, a clear deficit can be identified in Germany.Footnote 119 Internationally, there are successful experiences with the implementation of soft law by the National Contact Points (NCP) under the OECD proposals on corporate social responsibility that could offer orientation to the banking sector too. In the end, however, it inevitably boils down to the ethical standards prevailing among companies and business leaders, who must set the tone from the top. This applies generally to the corporate governance of companies, and it is especially true in respect of banks and financial institutions.Footnote 120

5 Conclusions

  1. 1.

    Banks are special, and so is the corporate governance of banks and other financial institutions as compared with the general corporate governance of non-banks. Empirical evidence, mostly gathered after the financial crisis, confirms this. Banks practicing good corporate governance in the traditional, shareholder-oriented style fared less well than banks having less shareholder-prone boards and less shareholder influence.

  2. 2.

    The special governance of banks and other financial institutions is firmly embedded in bank supervisory law and regulation. Starting with the recommendations of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, many other supervisory institutions have followed the lead with their own principles and guidelines for good governance of banks. In the European Union, this has led to legislation on bank governance under the so-called CRD IV (Capital Requirements Directive), which has been transformed into the law of the Member States. The legal literature dealing with this is mostly doctrinal and concerned with the national bank supervisory law. But there are also more functional legal as well as economic contributions, these addressing primarily, but not exclusively, systemically important financial institutions. The latter are under a special regime that needs separate treatment.

  3. 3.

    Most recently there has been intense discussion on the purpose of (non-bank) corporations. Shareholder governance and stakeholder governance have been and still are the two different prevailing regimes in the United States and in Europe, particularly in Germany. Yet for banks this difference has given way to stakeholder and, more particularly, creditor or debtholder governance, certainly in bank supervision and regulation.

  4. 4.

    Yet the implications of this for research and reform are still uncertain and controversial. For banks, self-regulation, if at all, must give way to co-regulation or cooperative regulation between the banks and the state. Mandatory transparency is indispensable. For banks this transparency has the additional function of informing the regulators and supervisors in order to facilitate their task of creditor and debtholder protection and more generally the protection of the economy. Particular qualification and independence problems arise for state-owned banks.

  5. 5.

    The regulatory core issues for the corporate governance of banks are manifold. A key problem is the composition and qualification of the (one tier or two tier) board. The legislative task is to enhance independent as well as qualified control. Yet the proposal of giving creditors a special seat in the board disregards the reality of labor codetermination. Giving bank supervisors a permanent seat in the board would create serious conflicts of interest since they would have to supervise themselves.

  6. 6.

    There are many other important special issues of bank governance, for example the duties and liabilities of bank directors in particular as far as risk and compliance are concerned, but also the remuneration paid to bank directors and senior managers or key function holders. Claw-back provisions, either imposed by law or introduced by banks themselves, exist already in certain countries and are beneficial.

  7. 7.

    Much depends on enforcement, an understudied topic. A mix of civil, penal and administrative sanctions, possibly coupled with private enforcement, may have advantages.

  8. 8.

    The corporate governance of banks is an ongoing task for supervisors, regulators and legislators, but also one for the banks themselves. In banking, ethics is indispensable, and the tone from the top matters.

  9. 9.

    For all of these issues, more economic, legal and interdisciplinary research on corporate governance in banks and financial institutions is needed, and it could also help pave the way forward.Footnote 121