Skip to main content
Log in

Demand-Driven and Supply-Sided Input–Output Models

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the demand-driven open input–output model, output is determined by final demand, given the production technology in every industry. On the contrary, in the supply-sided version, value added determines the level of output and producers must induce sales in order to achieve a desired level of income. This latter version of the model has been criticised and even rejected on its implausibility, its difficult interpretation and its bizarre implications, among other aspects. This paper argues that the supply-side model is not logically, mathematically or otherwise at odds with Leontief’s arguments. Rejection of the model is a matter of theoretical reading.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Forward linkages measure the relative capacity of each sector to induce the use of its output as input by other producers; backward linkages measure the relative ability of each sector to use other sectors’ output as inputs (Bulmer-Thomas, 1982).

  2. Using Ghosh’s original notation.

  3. Matrices A and E are similar if matrix X exists, such that XA = XE, which means that E = X−1AX; for example, X = <x>, the diagonal matrix of sectoral output (Hadley 1969).

  4. L and H are said dominant diagonal matrices and among some other properties, they are non-singular (Takayama 1985).

  5. “… the equivalence of the supply-driven input–output model and the Leontief price model can also be shown in another, surprisingly simple manner. Given the assumption of fixed quantities, the Leontief price model calculates the new price ratios for a given new value-added vector (v1′) as π′= v1xo (I − A)−l. The element πi expresses the new price in terms of the old price for good i; πi is thus a price index. The new output values (xi′) are obtained by revaluing the old outputs in their new prices. In other words, xi′ = π\(\hat{x}\)0. Post multiplying both sides … with \(\hat{x}\)0 and using B0 = \(\hat{x}\) −10 A0\(\hat{x}\)0 yields x1′ = v1′ (I − B0)−1, which is exactly the supply-driven input-model…” (Dietzenbacher 1997, p. 634). In his notation, B = E the distribution coefficients matrix.

  6. To the best of our knowledge, Leontief did not adhere explicitly to any theory of value and avoided such discussion when reconsidering both Walras’ and Marx’s theories (Leontief 1937, 1938).

  7. Given any matrices A and B, B B—1 = I, the identity matrix; therefore, BAB—1 = A (Harary 1969).

References

  • Augustinovics, M. 1970. Methods of international and intertemporal comparison of structure. In Contributions to input–output analysis, ed. A.P. Carter and A. Brody, 249–269. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bon, R. 1986. Comparative stability analysis of demand-side and supply-side input–output models. International Journal of Forecasting 2: 231–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bon, R. 1988. Supply-side multiregional input–output models. Journal of Regional Science 28: 41–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulmer-Thomas, V. 1982. Input–output analysis in developing countries: Sources and methods. Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassel, G. 1927. Theoretische Sozialökonomie, Leipzig: A. Deichertsche Verlagsbuchhandlung Dr. Werner Scholl, 1927 (English version: Theory of Social Economy, various editions).

  • Chen, C.Y., A. Rose. 1986. The joint stability of input-output production and allocation coefficients. Regional Research Institute, West Virginia University. Research Paper No. 8617. http://www.rri.wvu.edu/pdffiles/wp8617.pdf. Accessed 30 Aug 2012.

  • Chenery, H., and T. Watanabe. 1958. International comparisons of the structure of production. Econometrica 26: 487–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Mesnard, L. 2009. Is the Ghosh model interesting?. Journal of Regional Science 49 (2): 361–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. 1973. Teoría del valor. Barcelona: Antoni Bosch Editor (English version: Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium (Cowles Foundation Monographs Series), various editions).

  • Dietzenbacher, E. 1997. In vindication of the Ghosh model: A reinterpretation as a price model. Journal of Regional Science 23 (4): 629–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerra, I., and F. Sancho. 2011. Revisiting the original Ghosh model: Can it be made more plausible. Economic Systems Research 5 (3): 319–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerra, I., and F. Sancho. 2012. A non-possibility theorem for joint- stability in interindustry models. Applied Mathematics and Computation 219: 4045–4048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1951. Some properties of a generalized Leontief model. In Activity analysis of production and allocation, ed. T. Koopmans. New York/London: Wiley/Chapman and Hall, Cowles Commission for Research in Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarratani, F. 1976. Application of an interindustry supply model to energy issues. Environment and Planning 8: 447–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, A. 1958. Input–output approach in an allocation system. Economica New Series 25 (97): 58–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruver, G. 1989. On the plausibility of the supply-driven input–output model: A theoretical basis for input-coefficient change. Journal of Regional Science 29: 441–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadley, G. 1969. Linear algebra. Algebra lineal. Bogotá: Fondo Educativo Interamericano.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harary, F. 1969. Graph theory. Reading: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hazari, R.B. 1970. Empirical identification of key sectors in the Indian economy. The Review of Economics and Statistics 52 (3): 301–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L. 1976. The measurement of Hirschman linkages. Quarterly Journal of Economics XC (2): 323–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laumas, P. 1976. The weighting problem in testing the linkage hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics XC (2): 308–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W. 1928. Die Wistschaft als Kreislauf. Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Politik 60: 577–623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1936. Quantitative input and output relations in the economic system and the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics XVIII (3): 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1937. Interrelation of prices, output, savings and investment. A study in empirical application of the economic theory of general interdependence. The Review of Economics and Statistics XIX (3): 109–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1938. The significance of Marxian economics for present-day economic theory. American Economic Review 28 (1): 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1944. Output, employment, consumption and investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 58 (2): 290–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. 1885. El Capital, Crítica de la Economía Política, Tomo II, Vol. 5, El Proceso de Circulación del Capital. México: Siglo XXI Editores, 1979 (English versión: Capital: Volume 2: A Critique of Political Economy, Various editions).

  • Manresa, A., and F. Sancho. 2013. Supply and demand biases in linear interindustry models. Economic Modelling 33 (2): 94–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGilvray, J. 1981. Linkages, key sectors and development strategy. In Structure, system and economic policy, ed. W. Leontief. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, R., and P. Blair. 2009. Input–output analysis: Foundations and extensions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nikaido, H. 1970. Introduction to sets and mappings in modern economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oosterhaven, J. 1988. On the plausibility of the supply-driven input–output model. Journal of Regional Science 28 (2): 203–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterhaven, J. 1989. The supply-driven input–output model: A new interpretation but still implausible. Journal of Regional Science 29: 459–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterhaven, J. 1996. Leontief versus Ghoshian price and quantity models. Southern Economic Journal 62 (3): 750–759.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterhaven, J. 2012. Adding supply-driven consumption makes the Ghosh model even more implausible. Economic Systems Research 24 (1): 101–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A., and T. Allison. 1999. On the plausibility of the supply-driven input–output model: Empirical evidence on joint stability. Journal of Regional Science 29: 451–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, Paul. 1951. Abstract of a theorem concerning substitability in open Leontief models. In Activity analysis of production and allocation, ed. T. Koopmans. New York/London: Wiley/Chapman and Hall, Cowles Commission for Research in Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumann, J. 1990. On some basic issues of input–output economics: Technical structure, prices, imputations, structural decomposition, applied general equilibrium. Economic Systems Research 2 (3): 229–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schinkte, J., and R. Stäglin. 1988. Important input coefficients in market transactions’ tables and production flow tables. In Input–output analysis: Current developments, ed. M. Ciaschini. London: Chapman and Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. 1960. Producción de mercancías por medio de mercancías: Preludio a una crítica de la teoría económica, Barcelona: Oikos-Tau, 1982 (English Version: Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

  • Takayama, A. 1985. Mathematical economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. 1937. „Über ein öikonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwersschen Fixpunksatzes“ Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums, 73–83. Translated into Spanish as “Un modelo de equilibrio económico general.” in Segura J. y Rodríguez C., eds. La economía en sus textos, Madrid: Taurus, 1998 (English Version: “A Model of General Economic Equilibrium” The Review of Economic Studies, 13, 1–9 (1945)).

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are indebted to Prof. Dr. Joerg Beutel for useful comments and observations to an earlier version of this paper. Two anonymous referees have made valuable suggestions to improve this paper. We assume responsibility for all the remaining mistakes.

Funding

Financial support to conduct our research work by PAPIIT (UNAM) Project IN301018 is gratefully acknowledged, Dr. Marquez is also grateful to Programa de Becas Posdoctorales en la UNAM, Becario del Instituto de Investigaciones Económicas.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marco Antonio Marquez Mendoza.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aroche Reyes, F., Marquez Mendoza, M.A. Demand-Driven and Supply-Sided Input–Output Models. J. Quant. Econ. 19, 251–267 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-020-00229-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-020-00229-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation