Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter November 20, 2020

Financing Universal Basic Income: Eliminating Poverty and Bolstering the Middle Class While Addressing Inequality, Economic Rents, and Climate Change

  • Drew Riedl EMAIL logo
From the journal Basic Income Studies

Abstract

Universal Basic Income (UBI) can serve as a beneficial public policy to reduce poverty and inequality, yet a great challenge is how to fund it. This article offers a roadmap for fully funding UBI in a manner that: eliminates poverty; bolsters the middle-class; eliminates the stigma and government bureaucracy of social welfare programs; reduces ever-expanding inequality; initiates a path to meeting climate change goals; reduces speculation; and increases fairness and opportunity in the tax code. As stand-alone policies, these revenue proposals are valuable correctives in their own right. If the entire package of UBI and funding sources were in effect, society (and American capitalism) would be on a more stable, equitable, and environmentally sustainable footing.


Corresponding author: Drew Riedl, SC Johnson College of Business, Cornell University, Ithaca, USA, E-mail:

Appendix

Additional UBI opposition points

Why has UBI not been implemented? While the main opposition to a UBI program is the supposed ‘infeasibility’ due to cost, there are several other oppositions points that have been raised (Milanovic, 2019; Stiglitz, 2019):

  1. Limited experience with UBI. Trials have been too small, too short, or not truly universal or unconditional. As examples, Finland’s trial only included unemployed, and the State of Alaska’s dividend is a “windfall grant” and therefore varies too much to be considered guaranteed income.

While limited data exists for a full scale implementation, experience and comfort can be gained by incrementally increasing UBI payments as funding sources are put into place (a “piecemeal” approach). Social welfare programs would stay in place until UBI payments are sufficient to elevate individuals above the poverty level.

  1. UBI payments represent “money for nothing” thereby diminishing labor output and harming individuals by reducing their work ethic and dignity through work.[25]

UBI does not require less work but rather offers a choice especially to those in duress (e.g. to better negotiate or refuse low-paying “bad jobs”, return to school, etc.). Allowing individuals a solid income base can facilitate new work paradigms, such as shared work programs where two workers share a full-time job. This allows more individuals to maintain active work experience and is more practical with a UBI-like program.

Notably, since UBI is received unconditionally, the substitution effect between work and leisure is largely unimpacted, particularly at low levels of income and taxation (Milanovic, 2019, p. 204). Moreover, removing social welfare rules that reduce benefits when income increases may increase labor supply at low income levels.

Early evidence and theoretical frameworks indicated modest effects on labor supplied (Marinescu, 2018, Jones & Marinescu, 2018). In a recent trial, Finland showed a modest increase in days employed of UBI recipients (Kela, 2020). Individuals who reduced labor hours often did so to provide care for aging parents and/or young children, or acquire skills through education and/or job training (Hoynes & Rothstein, 2019). Education and training in particular can have beneficial long run effects on labor and productivity.

A jobs guarantee program has been presented as an alternative yet it would require a large bureaucracy creating jobs, placing and overseeing workers, and mandating work for those who would rather care for family, start a business, or attend school.

Despite the historically low unemployment rates experienced over the last decade, we have experienced ever expanding inequality and increasing “deaths of despair” (Case & Deaton, 2020). Why would forcing work through the threat of poverty inspire dignity? It is plausible that employers would treat workers with more dignity as workers gain leverage. Conversely, it seems paternalistic to claim that individuals gain benefits, that they are somehow unaware of, or would willingly refuse, from work, yet economists are aware of these benefits. UBI would allow greater ability for individuals to work in other ways including volunteering (a “dignified” endeavor). Interestingly the “dignity of work” concern is rarely addressed for those who inherit massive wealth. However, a significant tax increase in inheritances as a proposed funding source reduces the potential for an idle wealthy class.

  1. Philosophical rethinking of welfare state. UBI would alter the public safety net from social insurance (in which individuals receive payment only after certain adverse conditions unfold), to one in which the safety net is provided continually.

This is a core feature of UBI as it is meant to avoid or soften the impacts of economic uncertainty and adversity. The current social welfare structure is burdened with stigma, bureaucracy, and administrative costs which have resulted in low participation and chronic underfunding (as poverty rates are in the mid-teens and welfare payments average roughly half the poverty level) (Hoynes & Rothstein, 2019; Semega et al., 2019). Milanovic (2019, p. 204) allows that a philosophical change is not a dispositive argument against UBI, and that the philosophy of the current system “perhaps should be changed.”

  1. Strong political opposition of powerful interests to a significant redistributive policy that will likely alter the power dynamic between employers and employees.

Recently (2011 and 2013) it has been challenging to even increase the U.S. debt ceiling. In this environment, major policy enactments are unlikely. However, crises often allow legislative breakthroughs that were unimaginable a decade prior (e.g. Social Security and Affordable Care Act). UBI had been gaining traction in public dialog (e.g. Yang campaign). Moreover, piecemeal implementation as each funding source is secured will allow the program to expand as the politics allow. It will be important when the opportunity arises to have a vision of how UBI can realize its aspirations.

  1. A UBI program would “crowd-out” other public programs.

Notably, other important needs can still be financed. Firstly, there are still sufficient funding sources available to enact additional social programs. For example, the UBI program in this paper is overfunded by roughly $50 billion per year (even with a Financial Transactions Tax that is much more modest than alternative plans). As a recent example, a Brookings paper (Whitehurst, 2017) estimated $42 billion would be needed for subsidized childcare. While the surplus of $50 billion under this UBI proposal could be used, a significant source of funding proposed in the Brookings paper is still untapped (reducing the charitable deduction, which costs $55 billion per year).

Secondly, government investments (e.g. infrastructure, education, research and development, etc.) that expand productive capacity and grow GDP (and tax revenues) faster than borrowing costs should be undertaken with debt. To do so, at least to the point that expected GDP returns are at or above borrowing costs, would ensure they are funded adequately (Krugman, 2020). This is not dissimilar from how private capital financing decisions are made. Likewise, to maintain intergenerational equity and neutrality, each generation should pay the costs of initiatives to the extent that they disproportionately benefit. When benefits accrue largely to future generations, it makes sense for government expenditures to be expensed by paying for them largely in the future (i.e. borrowing). Of course, the expected benefits should outweigh the costs. For example, climate change infrastructure investments greatly benefit future generations in mitigating climate change damage. Government borrowing for these investments reduces present day opposition and better matches the benefits with costs intertemporally (Bovenberg and Heijdra, 1998). To do otherwise, risks underfunding these programs, as current generations will probably be less willing to be taxed to fully pay for future generation’s benefits. In contrast, UBI, and perhaps even a meaningful amount of healthcare spending, fall more in the category of benefits accruing to current taxpayers and therefore should be paid for largely out of current funds.

Finally, while healthcare is a critical social issue, the American healthcare system is a far too complex and beyond the scope of this paper to adequately address here. In brief, there are significant financial resources spent on healthcare by government (actual spending plus tax deductions provided at state and federal levels) and privately spent by individuals and corporations (e.g. premiums). In total, the United States’ per capita healthcare spending is over 40% higher than the next closest country, Switzerland (OECD, 2020b). Yet, the USA has the lowest life expectancy at birth of any G7 country (OECD, 2020b). Perhaps, a better allocation of these resources could deliver results in line with comparable nations. Nonetheless, UBI trials have been shown to increase recipients’ mental and physical well-being (Kela, 2020; Marinescu, 2018). If poverty alleviation must wait until healthcare is fully resolved it could lead to indefinite delay and is perhaps a false choice.

Table A:

UBI payments and contributions for representative “median” and “top decile” families.

$60,000 income “typical” US household (two adults, two children)Notes:$300,000 income. “average” top decile (two adults, two children)Notes:
Poverty level income (two adults, two children)+$33,820$12,490 × 2+$4,420 × 2+$33,820$12,490 × 2+$4,420 × 2
VAT “top-up”+$4,400Roughly 13% of poverty level income+$4,400Roughly 13% of poverty level income
Carbon “top-up”+$750$250 × 3 ( 1 share per adult, 1/2 share for child)+$750$250 × 3 ( 1 share per adult, 1/2 share for child)
Total UBI payment$38,970$38,970
Gross cost contributions
VAT tax (applies to 65% of consumption goods)−$5,850Assume 0% savings and net paycheck of 75% of gross pay.−$24,863Assume 15% savings and net paycheck of 75% of gross pay.
Carbon tax−$800See link to calculator (CCL, 2019)−$1,140See link to calculator (CCL, 2019)
Capital Gains tax−$70(Tax Policy Center, 2018b, Table 1)−$1,280(Tax Policy Center, 2018b, Table 1)
Inheritance taxNAUnlikely to impactSee noteLikely impact upon death and/or inheritance. 90%-ile have average estates of roughly $3 million so a married couple may provide an inheritance of over $1M/heir.
Corporate tax-$270Incidence estimated (Furman, 2008, Table 6) as corporate tax change compared to baseline (after tax assumed to be 75% of gross income)-$2,250Incidence estimated (Furman, 2008, Table 6) as corporate tax change compared to baseline (after tax assumed to be 75% of gross income)
Financial Transactions Tax−$240Incidence from (Weiss & Kawano, 2020, Table 5). Estimate increased 50%, to match the larger revenue estimate.−$1,935Incidence from (Weiss & Kawano, 2020, Table 5). Estimate increased 50%, to match the larger revenue estimate.
UBI taxable−$2,928Adding UBI to income and replacing UBI amount for standard deduction likely to increase tax incidence by negating 2019 standard deduction ($24,400) amount. Taxed at 2019 MFJ marginal tax rate of 12%−$9,353Assume deductions are itemized and larger than UBI. So impact is to increase taxable income by total UBI payment ($38,970). Taxed at 2019 MFJ marginal tax rate of 24%.
Land Value Tax 2.5%−$1,700Assume median home value of roughly $228 k and 30% of value from land.−$15,000Assume home value of $1.2 M and 50% of value from land.
Social Welfare cutsNAAssume to be unaffected.NAUnlikely to be affected.
Wealth taxNANAUnlikely to have net worth above $50 million.
60% Millionaire’s TaxNANA
Subtotal gross cost contributions$11,118$55,821
Total net impact+$27,112$16,851

References

Banerjee, A., Paul, N., & Suri, T. (2019). Universal basic income in the developing world. Annual Review of Economics. https://doi.org/10.3386/w25598.Search in Google Scholar

Barnes, P. (2014). With liberty and dividends for all: How to save our middle class when jobs don’t pay enough. San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Publishers.Search in Google Scholar

Batchelder, L. L. (2020). Leveling the playing field between inherited income and income from work through an inheritance tax. Tackling the Tax Code: Efficient and Equitable Ways to Raise Revenue, 48–88.Search in Google Scholar

BEA, Bureau of Economic Analysts. (2019). GDP, fourth quarter and annual 2018 (initial estimate).Search in Google Scholar

Bivens, J., Gould, E., Mishel, L., & Shierholz, H. (2014). Raising America’s pay: Why it’s our central economic policy challenge. Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy Institute.Search in Google Scholar

Blinder, A. S., Loh, A. W., & Solow, R. M. (Eds) (2013). Rethinking the financial crisis. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Search in Google Scholar

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2019). Financial Accounts of the United States – Z.1.10.17016/2380-7172.2447Search in Google Scholar

Bovenberg, A. L., & Heijdra, B. J. (1998). Environmental tax policy and intergenerational distribution. Journal of Public Economics, 67(1), 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0047-2727(97)00064-9.Search in Google Scholar

BLS Calculator, CPI Inflation. (2019). CPI inflation calculator.Search in Google Scholar

Calsamiglia, C., & Flamand, S. (2019). A review on basic income: A radical proposal for a free society and a sane economy by Philippe Van Parijs and Yannick Vanderborght. Journal of Economic Literature, 57(3), 644–58. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20181476.Search in Google Scholar

Case, A., & Deaton, A. (2020). Deaths of despair and the future of capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9780691217062Search in Google Scholar

CBO. (2018). Options for reducing the Deficit: 2019–2028. (pp. 289–300).Search in Google Scholar

CCL. (2019). Citizens’ climate lobby Energy innovation Act carbon dividend calculator. Retrieved from https://energyinnovationact.org/carbon-dividend-calculator/.Search in Google Scholar

Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. (2020). Policy basics: Where do our federal tax dollars go?Search in Google Scholar

Chandler, C. (1996). The Dole Tax Plan, Questions Of Credibility. The Washington Post.Search in Google Scholar

Chatzky, A. (2019). Inequality and tax rates: A global comparison. Council on Foreign Relations.Search in Google Scholar

Congress, H. R. (2019). 763, Energy innovation and carbon dividend Act of 2019.Search in Google Scholar

Dalio, R. My thoughts on universal basic income. https://www.linkedin.com/pulse/my-thoughts-universal-basic-income-ray-dalio/ [Accessed 17 Jul 2018].Search in Google Scholar

Das, A. (2019). Populism of the right and left: Oaktree’s Howard Marks has a message for politicians wooing the poor. ETMarkets.com, India Times.Search in Google Scholar

Diamond, P., & Saez, E. (2011). The case for a progressive tax: From basic research to policy recommendations. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(4), 165–90. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.25.4.165.Search in Google Scholar

D’Mello, J. F. (2019). Universal basic income and entrepreneurial pursuit in an autonomous society. Journal of Management Inquiry, 28(3), 306–310.10.1177/1056492619827381Search in Google Scholar

Federation of Tax Administrators. (2020). State individual income tax rates.Search in Google Scholar

Feloni, R. (2018). Iconic hedge fund billionaire Seth Klarman explains why traditional business models are broken and outlines how companies can fix them. Business Insider.Search in Google Scholar

Finn, D., & Goodship, J. (2014). Take-up of benefits and poverty: An evidence and policy review. JRF/CESI Report.Search in Google Scholar

Furman, J. (2020). How to increase growth while raising revenue: Reforming the corporate tax code. Tackling the Tax Code: Efficient and Equitable Ways to Raise Revenue, 285–315.Search in Google Scholar

Furman, J., & Orszag, P. R. (2018). Slower productivity and higher inequality: Are they related? Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper (2018-4).10.2139/ssrn.3191984Search in Google Scholar

Gale, W. (2020). Raising revenue with a progressive value-added tax. Tackling the Tax Code: Efficient and Equitable Ways to Raise Revenue, 191–236.Search in Google Scholar

Gale, W. G., & Harris, B. H. (2011). Reforming taxes and raising revenue: Part of the fiscal solution. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 27(4), 563–588. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grr026.Search in Google Scholar

George, H. (1912). Progress and Poverty: An Inquiry into the Cause of Industrial Depressions and of Increase of Want with Increase of Wealth, The Remedy. Garden City, NY: Doubleday, Page, and Co.Search in Google Scholar

Hoynes, H., & Rothstein, J. (2019). Universal basic income in the United States and advanced countries. Annual Review of Economics, 11, 929–958. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080218-030237.Search in Google Scholar

Hughes, C. (2018). Fair shot: Rethinking inequality and how we earn. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Search in Google Scholar

IRS. SOI tax stats- historical table 23.Search in Google Scholar

IRS. (2016). Individual income tax returns 2016, Section 2.Search in Google Scholar

Jones, D., & Marinescu, I. (2018). The labor market impacts of universal and permanent cash transfers: Evidence from the Alaska Permanent Fund. No. w24312 Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w24312Search in Google Scholar

Kela. (2020). Results of Finland’s basic income experiment: Small employment effects, better perceived economic security and mental wellbeing. Retrieved from https://www.kela.fi/web/en/news-archive/-/asset_publisher/lN08GY2nIrZo/content/results-of-the-basic-income-experiment-small-employment-effects-better-perceived-economic-security-and-mental-wellbeing.Search in Google Scholar

Kirkland, R. I. (1986). Should you leave it all to the children. Fortune, 114(7), 18–26.Search in Google Scholar

Krugman, P. (2020). The case for permanent stimulus (Wonkish). New York Times.Search in Google Scholar

Leiserson, Greg. (2020). Taxing wealth. Tackling the Tax Code: Efficient and Equitable Ways to Raise Revenue, 89–148.Search in Google Scholar

Lewis, M. (2016). Flash boys. Sous-Sol.Search in Google Scholar

Lowrey, A. (2018). Give people money: How a universal basic income would end poverty, revolutionize work, and remake the world. New York: Broadway Books.Search in Google Scholar

Mankiw, N. G. (2009). Principles of macroeconomics (2009 ed.). Boston, Mass.: Cengage Learning.Search in Google Scholar

Marinescu, I. (2018). No strings attached: The behavioral effects of US unconditional cash transfer programs. No. w24337 National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w24337.Search in Google Scholar

Milanovic, B. (2019). Capitalism, alone: The future of the system that rules the world. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674242852Search in Google Scholar

Mundial, B. (2018). GDP (current US $). World Bank National Accounts Data, and OECD National Accounts Data Files.Search in Google Scholar

Nikiforos, M., Marshall, S., & Zezza, G. (2017). Modeling the macroeconomic effects of a universal basic income. New York: Roosevelt Institute.Search in Google Scholar

OECD. (2020a). Tax on corporate profits (indicator). https://doi.org/10.1787/d30cc412-en [Accessed 05 Mar 2020].Search in Google Scholar

OECD. (2020b). Health spending (indicator). https://doi.org/10.1787/8643de7e-en [Accessed 11 Aug 2020].Search in Google Scholar

Office of Management and Budget. Historical tables. http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/historical-tables/ [Accessed 12 Feb 2020].Search in Google Scholar

Pereira, R. (Ed) (2017). Financing basic income: Addressing the cost objection. Cham, Switzerland: Springer.10.1007/978-3-319-54268-3Search in Google Scholar

Philippon, T. (2012). Finance vs. Walmart: Why are financial services so expensive? In Lo, A., & Solow, R. (Eds), Rethinking Finance,” A. Blinder. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Search in Google Scholar

Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674369542Search in Google Scholar

Piketty, T., Saez, E., & Gabriel, Z. (2018). Distributional national accounts: Methods and estimates for the United States. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(2), 553–609. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjx043.Search in Google Scholar

Pollin, R., Heintz, J., & Herndon, T. (2018). The revenue potential of a financial transaction tax for US financial markets. International Review of Applied Economics, 32(6), 772–806.10.1080/02692171.2018.1485634Search in Google Scholar

Posner, E. A., & Glen Weyl, E. (2018). Radical markets: Uprooting capitalism and democracy for a just society. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Romer, P. (2019). A tax that could fix big tech. The New York Times.Search in Google Scholar

Saez, E., & Zucman, G. (2019). How would a progressive wealth tax work? Evidence from the economics literature. Unpublished paper 2019. https://doi.org/10.3386/w20625.Search in Google Scholar

SEED. A guaranteed income demonstration, purchase Categories. https://seed.sworps.tennessee.edu/spending.html#purchases [Accessed 2 Sep 2016].Search in Google Scholar

Semega, J. L., Kollar, M. A., Creamer, J., & Mohanty, A. (2019). Income and poverty in the United States: 2018. Current Population Reports, P60–266.Search in Google Scholar

Sommeiller, E., & Price, M. (2018). The new gilded age: Income inequality in the US by state, metropolitan area, and county. Economic Policy Institute, 19.Search in Google Scholar

SSA (2018). Social security admin. Expenses.Search in Google Scholar

Stern, A. (2016). Raising the floor: How a universal basic income can renew our economy and rebuild the American dream. Public Affairs.Search in Google Scholar

Stiglitz, J. (2019). People, power, and profits: Progressive capitalism for an age of discontent. New York: WW Norton and Company.Search in Google Scholar

Tax Policy Center, Briefing Book. (2018a). How could we improve the federal tax system. What would the rate be under a VAT?Search in Google Scholar

Tax Policy Center, Briefing Book. (2018b). How could we improve the federal tax system. What is the effect of a lower tax rate for capital gains?Search in Google Scholar

The Economist. (2015). Why Henry George had a point.Search in Google Scholar

Toder, E., & Rosenberg, J. (2010). Effects of imposing a value-added tax to replace payroll taxes or corporate taxes. Tax Policy Center Publication.Search in Google Scholar

Ummel, K., Komanoff, R. C., Curtin, S., Diem, A., Wilson, E., Johnson, T., & Crandall, J. (2016). Impact of CCL’s proposed carbon fee and dividend policy: A high-resolution analysis of the financial effect on US households. International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA). https://11bup83sxdss1xze1i3lpol4-wpengine.netdna-ssl.com/wp-content/uploads/2016/02/Household-Impact-Study-Ummel.pdf [Accessed 1 May 2016].Search in Google Scholar

U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (2020). Corporate profits after tax (without IVA and CCAdj) [CP]. Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/CP 5 March.Search in Google Scholar

U. S. Census Bureau (2018). Quick facts.Search in Google Scholar

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (2019). Poverty guidelines (2019).Search in Google Scholar

Van Parijs, P., & Vanderborght, Y. (2017). Basic Income: A Radical Proposal for a Free Society and a Sane Economy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674978072Search in Google Scholar

Vella, M. (2017). Universal basic income: A Utopian idea whose time may finally have arrived. TIME. https://time.com/4737956/universal-basic-income/ [Accessed 24 Apr 2017].Search in Google Scholar

Wamhoff, S. (2018). Congress should reduce, not expand, tax breaks for capital gains. Washington, D.C.: Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy.Search in Google Scholar

Webb, M. S. (2013). How a levy based on location values could be the perfect tax. Financial Times, 27. https://doi.org/10.11120/plan.2013.27010029.Search in Google Scholar

Weiss, A., & Kawano, L. (2020). A proposal to tax financial transactions. Tackling the Tax Code: Efficient and Equitable Ways to Raise Revenue, 149–190.Search in Google Scholar

Whitehurst, G. J. (2017). Why the federal government should subsidize childcare and how to pay for it. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.Search in Google Scholar

Widerquist, K. (2017). The cost of basic income: Back-of-the-envelope calculations. Basic Income Studies, 12, 2. https://doi.org/10.1515/bis-2017-0016.Search in Google Scholar

Wiederspan, J., Rhodes, E., & Luke Shaefer, H. (2015). Expanding the discourse on antipoverty policy: Reconsidering a negative income tax. Journal of Poverty, 19(2), 218–238. https://doi.org/10.1080/10875549.2014.991889.Search in Google Scholar

Yang, A. (2018). The war on normal people: The truth about America’s disappearing jobs and why universal basic income is our future. New York: Hachette Books.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2020-04-15
Accepted: 2020-11-08
Published Online: 2020-11-20

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 24.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bis-2020-0013/html
Scroll to top button