Skip to main content
Log in

Understanding the New Normal: The Role of Demographics

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We calibrate an overlapping-generations model with a rich demographic structure to observed and projected changes in U.S. population, family composition, life expectancy, and labor market activity. The model indicates that demographic factors associated with the post-war baby boom pushed up real interest rates and real gross domestic product (GDP) growth from 1960 to the 1980s. Since the 1980s, the model accounts for a little more than a 1-percentage-point decline in both real GDP growth and real interest rates—much of the permanent declines in those variables according to some estimates. Our model predicts GDP growth and interest rates will remain low by historical standards, consistent with a “new normal” for the U.S. economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The expression “secular stagnation” was popularized during the Great Depression by Hansen (1939), who wrote: “[this] is the essence of secular stagnation—sick recoveries which die in their infancy and depressions which feed on themselves and leave a hard and seemingly immovable core of unemployment.” One potential contributor to secular stagnation in the twenty-first century is a step down in technology growth, with authors such as Fernald (2015) and Gordon (2016) arguing that the high productivity gains enjoyed before the early 1970s and during the information technology boom of the mid-1990s to early 2000s are unlikely to be repeated.

  2. For an early use of the expression “new normal,” see El-Erian (2010).

  3. The baby-boom generation consists of the cohorts born after World War II through the mid-1960s; see Hogan et al. (2008) for a statistical definition.

  4. Colby and Ortma (2015) describe the salient features of the U.S. demographic transition. Aaronson et al. (2014) discuss the effects of the demographic transition on recent and future movements in the aggregate labor supply.

  5. See Bloom et al. (2009) for evidence that a fall in fertility rates causes a rise in female labor force participation.

  6. For recent empirical evidence of the historically low correlation between real economic growth and real interest rates, see Bosworth (2014) and Hamilton et al. (2016). See also Lunsford and West (2019) for the evidence of the superior explanatory power of demographic variables compared to real economic growth over long horizons.

  7. Consistent with this prediction, Browning and Ejrnæs (2009) provide evidence that two-adult households without children—for which household consumption roughly equals adult consumption—have fairly flat consumption profiles over their midlife.

  8. One limitation of our approach is that extensions of the model that are not amenable to transforming the household equilibrium conditions into a set of linear equations conditional on aggregate variables would call for the use of nonlinear solution methods. One such extension is the inclusion of intentional bequest motives. Several authors have solved such problems by limiting the set of demographic (see, for example, De Nardi et al. (2016)).

  9. We use annual estimates of live births from NCHS. The NCHS also makes available monthly data on live births; however these data contain apparent seasonal patterns.

  10. To extract the trends in quarterly EPR series, we use the Hodrick–Prescott filter with a Lagrange multiplier of 25,000. This value is much higher than the typical value of 1,600 used in the business cycle literature. However, we found that the typical multiplier is much too low to filter out the cyclical effects of the Great Recession. See our technical appendix for further discussion.

  11. These patterns are consistent with several and at times offsetting factors, including increased access to public and private savings and pension funds, improved health and access to health insurance, and longer life expectancy. For a recent overview of the literature on the labor supply of older workers, see Coile (2015).

  12. The main productivity series published by Fernald (2014) excludes the contribution of aggregate labor quality growth, which we re-introduce for consistency with our model and the estimates of Shackleton (2013) and Gordon (2015). In Sect. 6, we show the robustness of our key findings to adding aggregate labor quality to our baseline calibration.

  13. We again use the Hodrick–Prescott filter with a Lagrange multiplier of 25,000 on quarterly data.

  14. Moreover, the 1900 Census counts by age are imprecise, displaying jumps in the number of persons reporting that their age in years ends with either a 0 or a 5. The quality of Census data appears to have improved quickly thereafter, making us confident that our key findings are insensitive to reasonable deviations from the initialization of demographic data. In any case, we smooth the 1900 Census counts when we initialize the age distribution.

  15. For comparison with our model predictions, we report time-series estimates that are “two-sided,” that is, for each period, we report estimates that use all past and future information to infer the equilibrium real interest rate. The time-series studies sometimes emphasize one-sided and/or real-time estimates, which speak to when changes in equilibrium real rates became apparent in the data.

  16. That is, we assume that a person aged a in any period after 1960:Q1 faces the same mortality rate, fertility rate, and employment rate (or combinations of these three variables, depending on the simulation) as someone aged a did in 1960:Q1 under our baseline calibration. The net migration flows by age and period are kept the same as under our baseline calibration.

  17. That said, we view the typical value of the Hodrick–Prescott filter Lagrange multiplier for quarterly data, at 1,600, as much too low to eliminate all cyclical fluctuations, especially in light of the unusually prolonged recovery from the global financial crisis.

  18. Cognizant of these limitations, Carvalho et al. (2016) write that “[the tractability of their age-independence assumptions] comes at the cost of not endowing the model with any flexibility to match the empirical age distribution. This additional feature would require an overlapping generation (OLG) model that is more computationally intensive and less analytically tractable. Hence, in our quantitative exercise, we can only target a few demographic statistics. We leave for future research an extensive comparison of the results obtained in this framework with those from a large-scale OLG model, disciplined by a richer set of moments from demographics data.” We see a contribution of our study as providing this important comparison point.

  19. In addition to using a different modeling framework, these authors assume that the simulated economy begins from a steady state in 2005, whereas we compute a dynamic equilibrium over a much longer period.

  20. Another related contribution based on the OG framework is Cooley and Henriksen (2018), who focus on steady-state analysis and thus miss the transitional dynamics that we find to be important; see Gagnon et al. (2018) for further discussion.

  21. See our appendix and replication materials for details on the construction of our series. Consistent with our earlier approach, we assume that these developments are anticipated and calibrate the household’s discount factor, \(\beta\), such that the average real rate in the 1980s corresponds to the average point estimate of Johannsen and Mertens (forthcoming). Absent this adjustment to the calibration, the introduction of positive technology growth in the model would raise the entire path of the equilibrium real rate compared with our baseline specification with no technology growth.

  22. At business cycle frequencies, one might expect that calibrating the model to match data on the aggregate labor supply would mostly capture movements in aggregate output given that the capital stock is relatively fixed in the near term. However, at low frequencies, the endogenous dynamics of capital accumulation is also potentially important for explaining movements in the trend of real GDP growth.

  23. The average the labor quality growth in the first and last 10 years of the sample in Fernald (2014) is similar to the sample-wide average, with some variation being observed over the in-between decades. Accordingly, we use the sample-wide average to impute labor quality growth in the simulation periods not covered by this author’s sample.

  24. The evidence reviewed in Chirinko (2008) is consistent with a long-run elasticity somewhere between 0.4 and 0.6, with the preferred value of the more recent study by Chirinko and Mallick (2017) being at the bottom of that range. Under a standard CES production function, one cannot lower the elasticity parameter down to that range while simultaneously imposing that the share of capital in aggregate income is aligned with that in the data. In particular, for a capital share of aggregate income \(s_{K}\) and a balanced-growth real return on capital (net of depreciation) of r, Equation (4) requires setting \(\alpha\) equal to \(r^{\rho }/(s_{K})^{\rho -1}.\) If we were to set r such that it conforms with the estimates of Johannsen and Mertens (forthcoming) in the 1980s, then the value of \(\alpha\) consistent with \(s_{K}\)=0.35 would exceed 1 whenever the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor is assumed to be below 0.72.

  25. We calibrate the discount rate such that the model with dependents matches the observed average level of interest rates in the 1980s. Without this normalization, the equilibrium real interest rate would be \(1\frac{1}{2}\) percentage points higher since the 1960s than otherwise. In that sense, the inclusion of dependent children in our model is consequential for our calibration and for the mix of factors that explain the overall level of interest rates.

  26. See Section D of our appendix for a discussion of historical demographic projections for the United States.

  27. On the correlation in real interest rates across countries, see, among many contributors, Desroches and Francis (2006) and King and Low (2014).

References

  • Aaronson, Stephanie, Tomaz Cajner, Bruce Fallick, Felix Galbis-Reig, Christopher Smith, and William Wascher. 2014. Labor Force Participation: Recent Developments and Future Prospects. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 49 (2): 197–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abel, Andrew B. 2003. The Effects of a Baby Boom on Stock Prices and Capital Accumulation in the Presence of Social Security. Econometrica 71 (2): 551–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aksoy, Yunus, Henrique S. Basso, Ron P. Smith, and Tobias Grasl. 2019. Demographic Structure and Macroeconomic Trends. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11 (1): 193–222.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, Ryan, Jonathan Kearns, and Marco J. Lombardi. 2015. (Why) Is Investment Weak? BIS Quarterly Review 2015 (March): 99–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, Felicitie C., and Michael L. Miller. 2005. Life Tables for the United States Social Security, 1900–2100. Office of the Chief Actuary, Actuarial Study no. 120. Social Security Administration.

  • Bernanke, Ben. 2005. The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Speech delivered at the Sandridge Lecture of the Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, VA.

  • Bloom, David, David Canning, Günther Fink, and Jocelyn Finlay. 2009. Fertility, Female Labor Force Participation, and the Demographic Dividend. Journal of Economic Growth 14 (2): 79–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosworth, Barry P. 2014. Interest Rates and Economic Growth: Are They Related? Center for Retirement Research Working Paper 2014-8. Boston College.

  • Brooks, Robin. 2000. What Will Happen to Financial Markets When the Baby Boomers Retire? IMF Working Paper No. 00/18. International Monetary Fund.

  • Browning, Martin, and Mette Ejrnæs. 2009. Consumption and Children. The Review of Economics and Statistics 91 (1): 93–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho, Carlos, Andrea Ferrero, and Fernanda Nechio. 2016. Demographics and Real Interest Rates: Inspecting the Mechanism. European Economic Review 88 (C): 208–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chirinko, Robert S. 2008. \(\sigma\): The Long and Short of It. Journal of Macroeconomics 30 (2): 671–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chirinko, Robert S., and Debdulal Mallick. 2017. The Substitution Elasticity, Factor Shares, and the Low-Frequency Panel Model. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 9 (4): 225–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coile, Courtney C. 2015. Economic Determinants of Workers’ Retirement Decisions. Journal of Economic Surveys 29 (4): 830–853.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colby, Sandra L., and Jennifer M. Ortma. 2015. Projections of the Size and Composition of the U.S. Population: 2014 to 2060. Current Population Reports P25-1143. U.S. Census Bureau.

  • Cooley, Thomas, and Espen Henriksen. 2018. The Demographic Deficit. Journal of Monetary Economics 93: 45–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curtis, Chadwick C., Steven Lugauer, and Nelson C. Mark. 2015. Demographic Patterns and Household Saving in China. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (2): 58–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Nardi, Mariacristina, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones. 2016. Medicaid Insurance in Old Age. American Economic Review 106 (11): 3480–3520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro, Marco, Domenico Giannone, Marc P. Giannoni, and Andrea Tambalotti. 2017. Safety, Liquidity, and the Natural Rate of Interest. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2017 (1): 235–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desroches, Brigitte, and Michael Francis. 2006. Global Savings, Investment, and World Real Interest Rates. Bank of Canada Review 2006 (Winter): 3–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, Peter A. 1965. National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model. American Economic Review 55 (5): 1126–1150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domeij, David, and Martin Floden. 2006. Population Aging and International Capital Flows. International Economic Review 47 (3): 1013–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, Gauti B., Neil R. Mehrotra, and Jacob A. Robbins. 2019. A Model of Secular Stagnation: Theory and Quantitative Evaluation. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11 (1): 1–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • El-Erian, Mohamed A. 2010. Navigating the New Normal in Industrial Countries. Washington, DC: Speech delivered at the International Monetary Fund’s Per Jacobsson Foundation Lecture.

  • Fehr, Hans, Gitte Halder, Sabine Jokisch, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. 2003. A Simulation Model for the Demographic Transition in the OECD: Data Requirements, Model Structure and Calibration. Wurzburg Economic Papers no. 45. University of Wurzburg, Chair for Monetary Policy and International Economics.

  • Fernald, John G. 2014. A Quarterly, Utilization-Adjusted Series on Total Factor Productivity. FRBSF Working Paper Series no. 2012-19. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

  • Fernald, John G. 2015. Productivity and Potential Output Before, During, and After the Great Recession. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 29 (1): 1–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernald, John G. 2016. Reassessing Longer-Run US Growth: How Low? FRBSF Working Paper Series no. 2016-18. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

  • Feroli, Michael. 2003. Capital Flows Among the G-7 Nations: A Demographic Perspective. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2003-54. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).

  • Gagnon, Etienne, Benjamin K. Johannsen, and David López-Salido. 2018. Comment on the Demographic Deficit. Journal of Monetary Economics 93 (C): 63–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geanakoplos, John, Michael Magill, and Martine Quinzii. 2004. Demography and the Long-Run Predictability of the Stock Market. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 35 (1): 241–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geppert, Christian, Alexander Ludwig, and Raphael Abiry. 2016. Secular Stagnation? Growth, Asset Returns and Welfare in the Next Decades: First Results. SAFE Working Paper Series no. 145. Leibniz Institute for Financial Research SAFE.

  • Gertler, Mark. 1999. Government Debt and Social Security in a Life-Cycle Economy. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 50 (1): 61–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, Robert J. 2015. Secular Stagnation on the Supply Side: U.S. Productivity Growth in the Long Run. Digiworld Economic Journal 1 (100): 19–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The US Standard of Living since the Civil War. Princeton University Press.

  • Hamilton, Brady E., and Candace M. Cosgrove. 2010. Central Birth Rates by Live-Birth Order, Current Age, and Race of Women in Each Cohort from 1911 through 1991: United States, 1960–2005. Table 1. Hyattsville, MD: National Center for Health Statistics. Released: June 30, 2010.

  • Hamilton, James D., Ethan S. Harris, Jan Hatzius, and Kenneth D. West. 2016. The Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present, and Future. IMF Economic Review 64 (4): 660–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, Alvin H. 1939. Economic Progress and Declining Population Growth. American Economic Review 29 (1): 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogan, Howard, Debbie Perez, and William R. Bell. 2008. “Who (Really) Are the First Baby Boomers?” Joint Statistical Meetings Proceedings. Social Statistics Section. American Statistical Association, 1009–1016.

  • Holston, Kathryn, Thomas Laubach, and John C. Williams. 2017. Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants. Journal of International Economics 108: S59–S75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda, Daisuke, and Masashi Saito. 2014. The Effects of Demographic Changes on the Real Interest Rate in Japan. Japan and the World Economy 32: 37–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannsen, Benjamin K., and Elmar Mertens. Forthcoming. A time series model of interest rates with the effective lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12771.

  • Jones, Callum. 2018. Aging, Secular Stagnation and the Business Cycle. IMF Working Paper no. 18/63. International Monetary Fund.

  • Kara, Engin, and Leopold von Thadden. 2016. Interest Rate Effects of Demographic Changes in a New Keynesian Life-Cycle Framework. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20 (1): 120–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiley, Michael T. 2020. What Can the Data Tell Us About the Equilibrium Real Interest Rate? International Journal of Central Banking 16 (3): 181–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, Mervyn, and David Low. 2014. Measuring the ‘World’ Real Interest Rate. NBER Working Paper Series no. 19887. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Krueger, Dirk, and Alexander Ludwig. 2007. On the Consequences of Demographic Change for Rates of Returns to Capital, and the Distribution of Wealth and Welfare. Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (1): 49–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lubik, Thomas A., and Christian Matthes. 2015. Calculating the Natural Rate of Interest: A Comparison of Two Alternative Approaches. Richmond Fed Economic Brief 15-10. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

  • Ludwig, Alexander, Dirk Krüger, and Axel Börsch-Supan. 2009. Demographic Change, Relative Factor Prices, International Capital Flows, and Their Differential Effects on the Welfare of Generations. In Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment, ed. N.B.E.R. Chapters, 385–414. National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

  • Lunsford, Kurt G., and Kenneth D. West. 2019. Some Evidence on Secular Drivers of US Safe Real Rates. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11 (4): 113–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, Edmund. 1961. The Golden Rule of Accumulation: A Fable for Growth. American Economic Review 51 (4): 638–643.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, James M. 2001. Demographic Structure and Asset Returns. The Review of Economics and Statistics 83 (4): 565–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachel, Lukasz, and Thomas D. Smith. 2017. Are Low Real Interest Rates Here to Stay? International Journal of Central Banking 13 (3): 1–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, Kenneth. 2015. Debt Supercycle, Not Secular Stagnation. VOX: CEPR’s Policy Portal, April 22, http://www.voxeu.org/article/debt-supercycle-not-secular-stagnation.

  • Shackleton, Robert. 2013. Total Factor Productivity Growth in Historical Perspective. Working Paper Series no. 2013-01. Congressional Budget Office.

  • Summers, Laurence H. 2014. Reflections on the ‘New Secular Stagnation Hypothesis. Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures. London: VoxEU.org eBook, CEPR Press, pp. 27–40.

  • Yaari, Menahem E. 1965. Uncertain Lifetime, Life Insurance, and the Theory of the Consumer. The Review of Economic Studies 32 (2): 137–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, Fang. 2009. Consumption Over the Life Cycle: How Different is Housing? Review of Economic Dynamics 12 (3): 423–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Benjamin K. Johannsen.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Declarations of interest: none. We are grateful to Sarah Baker, Carter Bryson, and Kathryn Holston for excellent research assistance, and to seminar participants at the Bank of Canada, the Danish Central Bank, Erasmus University in Rotterdam, the Federal Reserve Board, the 7th Joint Bank of Canada and European Central Bank Conference, the Centro de Estudios Monetarios y Financieros, the Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance, the Federal Reserve Banks of Chicago, Kansas City, and Minneapolis, the International Monetary Fund, the Sveriges Riksbank, and the “Declining Natural Rate of Interest” session organized by the Washington Center for Equitable Growth at the 2018 annual meetings of the Allied Social Science Association. We further thank Linda Tesar and two anonymous referees for their input. Comments can be directed to benjamin.k.johannsen@frb.gov.

Supplementary Information

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gagnon, E., Johannsen, B.K. & López-Salido, D. Understanding the New Normal: The Role of Demographics. IMF Econ Rev 69, 357–390 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-021-00138-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-021-00138-4

JEL Classification

Navigation