Skip to main content
Log in

Capital Controls and Electoral Cycles

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the relation between the evolution of capital controls and electoral cycles. We exploit a dataset containing detailed information on the level of restrictions on capital flows for 98 countries on an annual basis from 1995 to 2015, constructed by Fernandez et al. (IMF Econ Rev 64:548–574, 2016). First, we find that restrictions are more likely to increase during an election year. The relationship between changes in capital controls and elections is more robust than with any other economic variable. Second, these changes are driven predominantly by restrictions on capital outflows and on relatively liquid asset categories. Third, changes occur mostly after elections, though not exclusively. Finally, capital controls increase more if the new government is more leftist or less liberal than its predecessor, and greater electoral uncertainty is related to higher restrictions on capital flows. Overall, these results suggest that theories examining the cyclical properties of capital controls should also consider electoral cycles.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The few previous studies examining the political determinants of capital controls rely on a crude, binary measure of restrictions (Alesina et al. 1993; Grilli and Milesi-Ferretti 1995) preventing the investigation of such a link.

  2. “Booms and busts in aggregate activity are associated with virtually no movements in capital controls,” Fernández et al. (2015, p. 1).

  3. As explained by Chinn and Ito (2006), “it is almost impossible to distinguish between de jure and de facto controls on capital transactions.”

  4. Our sample is restricted to countries included in this dataset. A full list of countries can be found in “Appendix 1.” All but three countries, namely Bangladesh (18 observations); Iran and Myanmar (19 observations, respectively), are observed for the entire sample period.

  5. If the system of a country does not fit this classification, we focus on the general election.

  6. Results without this transformation are qualitatively similar and are available in a previous version of this paper.

  7. In addition to these tests, we also estimate Eq. (1) using the Chinn–Ito measure of capital openness. The sign of the election dummy is consistent with the results presented in this section. The relationship is, however, not significant. This might be explained by the construction of the Chinn–Ito index, as discussed in the previous section.

  8. In addition, we also run the model after dropping 11 countries from our sample which did not hold elections between 1995 and 2015: the results are very similar to the baseline results and are displayed in Table 12.

  9. Alternatively, we also run the model on a sample excluding countries that have ever experienced early elections. Results are displayed in Table 12. The magnitude and significance of the electoral dummy slightly decrease, but the conclusion is similar.

  10. This result is robust to all specifications detailed in Sect. 3.1 on the main results.

  11. Not all of the ten subcategories are available for all years, which is why the sample size varies in the ten specifications. For example, bonds are available only since 1997 (Fernández et al. 2016).

  12. However, for some countries/years, the period under consideration goes beyond December 31, admittedly introducing additional noise.

  13. A potential issue could be that after elections it typically takes time until governments are formed. For all elections in the sample, we collected the exact date of either the first parliamentary session in parliamentary systems or the president’s inauguration in presidential systems and repeated the analysis around the week of government formation. We do not find major changes compared to the analysis using the election date.

  14. Cerutti et al. (2017) constructed a cross-country dataset at the quarterly level focusing on changes in intensity of various prudential tools, including reserve requirements on foreign currency-denominated accounts. We repeated the same analysis as with Forbes et al. (2015) and Pasricha et al. (2018) but do not observe evidence of electoral cycle when using this specific measure.

  15. We drop observations from a sixth category that encompasses cases for which a proper classification is meaningless, for instance during a revolution or a civil war. Also, for some cases ideology is missing for the entire observation period (e.g., Bahrain, Myanmar, and Saudi Arabia).

  16. The same pattern appears when we take into account only planned elections.

  17. Available at https://manifesto-project.wzb.eu.

References

  • Aizenman, J., and G.K. Pasricha. 2013. Why do emerging markets liberalize capital outflow controls? fiscal versus net capital flow concerns. Journal of International Money and Finance 39: 28–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., V. Grilli, and G.M. Milesi-Ferrett. 1993. The political economy of capital controls. Technical Report. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Alfaro, L. 2004. Capital controls: A political economy approach. Review of International Economics 12: 571–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., and S. Bond. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., and O. Bover. 1995. Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benigno, G., H. Chen, C. Otrok, A. Rebucci, and E.R. Young. 2016. Optimal capital controls and real exchange rate policies: A pecuniary externality perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics 84: 147–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard, W., and D. Leblang. 1999. Democratic institutions and exchange-rate commitments. International Organization 53: 71–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, J., 2011. Overborrowing and systemic externalities in the business cycle. American Economic Review 101: 3400–3426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender, A., and A. Drazen. 2005. Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics 52: 1271–1295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F., G. Esquivel, and F. Lefort. 1996. Reopening the convergence debate: A new look at cross-country growth empirics. Journal of Economic Growth 1: 363–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerutti, E., S. Claessens, and L. Laeven. 2017. The use and effectiveness of macroprudential policies: New evidence. Journal of Financial Stability 28: 203–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, R. 2010. Elections, capital flows, and politico-economic equilibria. The American Economic Review 100: 1759–1777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chinn, M.D., and H. Ito. 2006. What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics 81: 163–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Luca, G., J.R. Magnus, et al., 2011. Bayesian model averaging and weighted-average least squares: Equivariance, stability, and numerical issues. Stata Journal 11: 518–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durnev, A. 2010. The real effects of political uncertainty: Elections and investment sensitivity to stock prices. Working paper.

  • Eichengreen, B. 2001. Capital account liberalization: What do cross-country studies tell us? The World Bank Economic Review 15: 341–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., and A. Rose. 2014. Capital controls in the 21st century. Journal of International Money and Finance 48: 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farhi, E., and I. Werning. 2014. Dilemma not trilemma? capital controls and exchange rates with volatile capital flows. IMF Economic Review 62: 569–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández, A., A. Rebucci, and M. Uribe. 2015. Are capital controls countercyclical? Journal of Monetary Economics 76: 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández, A., M.W. Klein, A. Rebucci, M. Schindler, and M. Uribe. 2016. Capital control measures: A new dataset. IMF Economic Review 64: 548–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, K., M. Fratzscher, and R. Straub. 2015. Capital-flow management measures: What are they good for? Journal of International Economics 96: S76–S97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fratzscher, M. 2012. Capital flows, push versus pull factors and the global financial crisis. Journal of International Economics 88: 341–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grilli, V., and G.M. Milesi-Ferretti. 1995. Economic effects and structural determinants of capital controls. IMF Staff Papers 42: 517–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halikiopoulou, D., K. Nanou, and S. Vasilopoulou. 2012. The paradox of nationalism: The common denominator of radical right and radical left euroscepticism. European Journal of Political Research 51: 504–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilzetzki, E., C.M. Reinhart, and K.S. Rogoff. 2017. Exchange Arrangements Entering the 21st Century: Which Anchor Will Hold?. Technical Report. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • IMF. 2012. The liberalization and management of capital flows—an institutional view. Technical Report. International Monetary Fund.

  • Ito, T. 1990. The timing of elections and political business cycles in Japan. Journal of Asian Economics 1: 135–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Julio, B., and Y. Yook. 2012. Political uncertainty and corporate investment cycles. The Journal of Finance 67: 45–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Julio, B., and Y. Yook. 2016. Policy uncertainty, irreversibility, and cross-border flows of capital. Journal of International Economics 103: 13–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korinek, A., and D. Sandri. 2016. Capital controls or macroprudential regulation? Journal of International Economics 99: S27–S42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kriesi, H., E. Grande, R. Lachat, M. Dolezal, S. Bornschier, and T. Frey. 2006. Globalization and the transformation of the national political space: Six european countries compared. European Journal of Political Research 45: 921–956.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leblang, D.A. 1997. Domestic and systemic determinants of capital controls in the developed and developing world. International Studies Quarterly 41: 435–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magnus, J.R., O. Powell, and P. Prüfer. 2010. A comparison of two model averaging techniques with an application to growth empirics. Journal of Econometrics 154: 139–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merz, N., S. Regel, and J. Lewandowski. 2016. The manifesto corpus: A new resource for research on political parties and quantitative text analysis. Research and Politics 3: 2053168016643346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, G.M. 1998. The political economy of capital controls. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moral-Benito, E. 2015. Model averaging in economics: An overview. Journal of Economic Surveys 29: 46–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oatley, T. 1999. How constraining is capital mobility? the partisan hypothesis in an open economy. American Journal of Political Science 43:1003–1027.

  • Pasricha, G. 2017. Policy rules for capital controls. Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper 2017-42.

  • Pasricha, G.K., M. Falagiarda, M. Bijsterbosch, and J. Aizenman. 2018. Domestic and multilateral effects of capital controls in emerging markets. Journal of International Economics 115: 48–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, D.P., and C. Inclan. 1997. The origins of financial openness: A study of current and capital account liberalization. American Journal of Political Science 41: 771–813.

  • Sachs, J., and C. Wyplosz. 1986. The economic consequences of president mitterrand. Economic Policy 1: 261–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schindler, M. 2009. Measuring financial integration: A new data set. IMF Staff Papers 56: 222–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi, M., and J. Svensson. 2006. Political budget cycles: Do they differ across countries and why? Journal of Public Economics 90: 1367–1389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 2004. Election timing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E., and J.A. Ocampo. 2008. Capital market liberalization and development. Oxford: University Press on Demand.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the coeditor, Emine Boz, as well as two anonymous reviewers for their useful and constructive comments. We would like to thank Konstantins Benkovskis, Monika Bütler, Tommy Krieger, Jan Mellert, Pierre-Guillaume Méon and participants at the European Public Choice Society Meeting, Rome, 2018, at the Baltic Economic Association meeting, Vilnius, 2018, at the Annual Congress of the Swiss Society for Economics and Statistics, St. Gallen, 2018, and at the workshop on Political Cycles, Rennes, 2018, for insightful comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to Kristin Forbes for sharing some data with us.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nicolas Gavoille.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Names of Countries Included in Sample

 

Algeria

Guatemala

Paraguay

Angola

Hungary

Peru

Argentina

Iceland

Philippines

Australia

India

Poland

Austria

Indonesia

Portugal

Bahrain

Iran. Islamic Rep.

Qatar

Bangladesh

Ireland

Russian Federation

Belgium

Israel

Saudi Arabia

Bolivia

Italy

Singapore

Brazil

Jamaica

Slovenia

Brunei Darussalam

Japan

South Africa

Bulgaria

Kazakhstan

Spain

Burkina Faso

Kenya

Sri Lanka

Canada

Korea. Rep.

Swaziland

Chile

Kuwait

Sweden

China

Kyrgyz Republic

Switzerland

Colombia

Latvia

Tanzania

Costa Rica

Lebanon

Thailand

Cote d’Ivoire

Malaysia

Togo

Cyprus

Malta

Tunisia

Czech Republic

Mauritius

Turkey

Denmark

Mexico

Uganda

Dominican Republic

Moldova

Ukraine

Ecuador

Morocco

United Arab Emirates

Egypt. Arab Rep.

Myanmar

UK

El Salvador

Netherlands

United States

Ethiopia

New Zealand

Uruguay

Finland

Nicaragua

Uzbekistan

France

Nigeria

Venezuela. RB

Georgia

Norway

Vietnam

Germany

Oman

Yemen. Rep.

Ghana

Pakistan

Zambia

Greece

Panama

 
  1. Countries with available measures of capital controls for the years 1995–2015 from Fernández et al. (2016)

Appendix 2: Data Sources

Variable

Source(s)

Detailed description

Capital controls

Fernandez et al. (2016)

Annual measure of capital controls in the aggregates, on outflows, inflows and ten subcategories. Measured annually at the end of the year. For 100 countries between 1995 and 2015

Political system

DPI (2015)

Allocation into presidential and parliamentary system

Dates of parl. elections

DPI (2015)

 

Dates of presidential elections

Various Internet sources

 

Early/planned elections

Various sources

Evidence whether elections took place at a date planned in advance or were held earlier

Dates of changes in capital controls

Forbes et al. (2015)

Precise dates of events changing capital controls for a subsample of 36 countries between 2009 and 2011

Names of leaders and parties

Various Internet sources

 

Government ideology

DPI; various Internet sources

 

REER (% change)

World Bank

Change in real exchange rate

Credit (% change)

World Bank

Change in domestic credit to private sector (% of GDP)

FX (% change)

World Bank

Change in total reserves minus gold (current US$) to GDP

Exchange regime

Ilzetzki et al. (2017)

Six categories: peg, crawling peg, managed float, free falling, free and dual market

Fisc. Deficit (% GDP)

World Bank

Total government expenditure minus government revenue over GDP

Curr. Account (% GDP)

World Bank

Trade balance plus net income and direct payments over GDP

GDP per capita

World Bank

 

GDP growth

World Bank

 

Democracy

Polity4

Index ranging from \(-10\) to 10. If the value is greater than or equal to zero, the country is classified as a democracy

Openness

IMF

Trade openness defined as the sum of imports and exports over GDP

Debt (% GDP)

World Bank

Total government debt to GDP

Interest differential (% change)

World Bank

Change in domestic/USA interest rate differential

Appendix 3: Complementary Regressions

See Tables 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14 and 15.

Table 7 Electoral cycle of capital controls
Table 8 Robustness: two lags
Table 9 Robustness: Jackknife and bootstrap SE
Table 10 Robustness: GMM
Table 11 Robustness: BMA
Table 12 Additional Evidence 2
Table 13 Ideological movements of governments
Table 14 Probability of ideological switches
Table 15 Manifesto
Fig. 9
figure 9

Capital controls on outflows increase more if election outcomes are uncertain—planned elections. Note Expected change in average capital controls on outflows conditional on electoral uncertainty. Electoral uncertainty is measured as the difference between the vote share of the two leading parties/candidates in the first election round. 90% confidence interval bands. Restricted to the subsample of democracies, and considering only planned elections

Fig. 10
figure 10

Election and leader’s transition. Note This figure shows the marginal effect of election, leader change and their interaction on changes in capital controls. The bar indicates the 90% confidence interval bands

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gavoille, N., Hofer, K. Capital Controls and Electoral Cycles. IMF Econ Rev 69, 275–324 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-020-00123-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-020-00123-3

JEL Classification

Navigation