Skip to main content
Log in

FSA in an ETF world

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper models the value of conducting financial statement analysis (FSA) in the presence of an electronically traded fund (ETF) that gives exposure to the firm’s systematic value. FSA is characterized as a costly process that yields a private signal about the idiosyncratic portion of a firm’s future payoffs. The value of this signal depends on how efficiently price transmits information to uninformed traders. A popular argument is that ETFs are attracting noise traders away from the underlying firm, making prices more informative and private information less valuable. While I find that prices are more informative after the introduction of an ETF, I show that this isn’t because of a change in the amount or location of noise trading. Holding noise trading constant, ETFs allow informed investors to hedge out exposure to the portion of firm value that they are uninformed about, which causes them to place larger bets on their private information. This is what causes firm prices to be more informative. The introduction of an ETF into an economy thus presents two competing forces on the value of conducting FSA. On the one hand, prices are more informative after the arrival of an ETF, making private information less valuable, but on the other, informed traders can use the ETF to hedge, making private information more valuable. I characterize how these forces trade off as a function of the exogenous noise in the economy. These results are unavailable in previous theoretical papers about ETFs, because they modeled investors as being risk neutral, thus eliminating their desire to hedge out uncertainty.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Israeli et al. (2017) results may appear at odds with Glosten et al. (2016). However, Israeli et al. (2017) show that the Glosten et al. results apply to the concurrent pricing of information about the common component of the news, while their results apply to the pricing of future information and is largely driven by the idiosyncratic component of the news.

  2. Another branch of the ETF literature considers how the ETF aids trading in assets that are otherwise illiquid. Bhattacharya and O’Hara (2017) consider the case where there is no market for the underlying asset, and so informed traders must use the ETF as an indirect means of trading on their information.

  3. To see this, note, in Subrahmanyam (1991), that the derived demands for the firm asset and the ETF asset are always in the same direction (compare equation 5 on page 22 and equation 8 on page 24).

  4. Because the individual firm asset markets are segmented, without loss of generality, every parameter in the model could be firm-specific (that is, indexed by ‘j’). I supress this detail to avoid unnecessary notation.

  5. There are two common options for describing the signal error’s covariance across investors—either the errors are independent across all agents, or they are perfectly correlated, as in my model. Neither assumption is ideal. In my model, every analyst who conducts FSA reaches exactly the same conclusion. However, assuming independent errors is also unrealistic, implying that the analysts collectively know the value of the payoff perfectly. As shown later, there are some practical modeling advantages to assuming all informed agents see exactly the same signal.

  6. There is little tension in a model where investors have a signal about the common factor and then an ETF is added to the market. The ETF allows the factor-informed trader the perfect mechanism to use her information, and so the value of the factor information increases.

  7. By the commutative law of addition, a positive supply shock on the RHS of the market clearing condition is equivalent to a negative demand shock on the LHS.

  8. The general expressions for the conditional mean and variance of normal random variables are as follows. Let F be an n-dimensional vector of payoffs with prior mean vector μ and let Y be an m- dimensional vector of signals about those payoffs, with no particular covariance structure and mean vector u. The covariance matrix of FY is n+m dimensional and symmetric. Partition this matrix into an nxn matrix of the top left corner, labeled ∑11, an mxm matrix in the bottom right corner labeled ∑22, an nxm matrix of the top right corner labeled ∑12, and an mxn matrix in the bottom left corner, labeled \( {\sum}_{12}^{\prime } \) The nx1 posterior mean vector is then given by \( E=\mu +{\sum}_{12}{\sum}_{22}^{-1}\left(Y-\upsilon \right) \), and the nxn posterior covariance matrix is given by \( V={\sum}_{11}-{\sum}_{12}{\sum}_{22}^{-1}{\sum}_{12}^{\prime } \) (Welch 2014).

  9. There is no additional information to be gained by conditioning beliefs on the prices of other firm assets j ≠ j because \( {\hat{P}}_{0j},={Y}_{j,}^s-{K}_0\ast {X}_j, \) is uncorrelated with the payoff \( {F}_j={F}^c+{F}_j^s \) and with firm j’s price signal \( {\hat{P}}_{0j}={Y}_j^s-{K}_0\ast {X}_j \)

  10. Recall that the mean of the liquidity demand is the per capita supply of the risky asset.

  11. Admati (1985) provides a solution to the multi-asset noisy rational expectations equilibrium with a reasonably general information structure, but her model does not accommodate the case where information is only about one component of the asset’s final payoff.

  12. With negative exponential utility functions and normal random variables, demand functions do not depend on the level or distribution of the known supply of assets; consequently, assumptions about these values only impact the constant in the price function and have no impact on the informational properties of the model. For instance, we could assume that a fraction μ of each firm asset’s known supply is traded as a basket of securities (as created by the ETF sponsor), while 1-μ of the supply is traded in individual asset markets, without changing the coefficients on the random variables in the pricing function. Importantly, with or without the ETF, the realized economy-wide payoff is the sum of the individual firm payoffs and the variance of the random liquidity noise is the same in both economies.

  13. Arbitraging between the ETF and the basket of constituent securities whenever the ETF price deviates from the value of the basket is a primary function of the Authorized Participant (AP). The AP can accomplish this either by trading in the secondary market for the ETF and the constituent securities or by trading in the primary market with the ETF sponsor. There is a rich literature regarding the microstructure of ETFs—how they are created, how they are priced, and why they offer extremely low transaction costs. Lettau and Madhavan (2018) detail the inner workings of ETFs and related research into it. My model relies only on the facts that an ETF is a basket of securities that collectively provide exposure to some commonly held attribute of the constituent firms, that they can be longed or shorted at very low cost, and that there is no arbitrage between the individual asset prices and the ETF asset price.

  14. Israeli et al. (2017) discuss how liquidity noise trading is leaving individual firm markets and moving to ETF markets. Note, however, that, because \( {P}_{ETF}=\frac{1}{N}{\sum}_{j=1}^N{P}_j={\overline{P}}_j \), the liquidity noise in the firm assets necessarily affects the noise on ETF asset in the same direction; a shift up in one market and down in another market is not possible without a second source of noise. For our purposes, an additional exogenous source of noise in the ETF market would have no impact on the informational properties of the ETF economy. To see this, change the model to allow another noise term in the ETF market, so that \( {P}_{ETF}={b}_0+{b}_1\overline{\mathrm{Y}}\hbox{-} {\mathrm{b}}_2\overline{\mathrm{X}}\hbox{-} {\mathrm{b}}_3{X}_{ETF} \) If this was the case, then \( {\overline{P}}_1 \) would also have to have a b3XETF term (because of the no arbitrage condition), and to do this each of the N individual P1j’s would therefore have a b3XETF/N term. The investor could then use the PETF and P1j to back out the new XETF term, making it irrelevant to the information environment.

  15. There is no additional information to be gleaned from observing other firm asset prices j ≠ j, because \( {\hat{P}}_{1j},={Y}_j^s-{K}_1{X}_j, \) is uncorrelated with the firm payoff \( {F}_j={F}^c+{F}_j^s \) and is a noisy of the ETF price signal \( {\hat{P}}_{ETF}={\overline{\mathrm{Y}}}^s-{K}_1\overline{\mathrm{X}} \) for inferences about the ETF payoff \( {F}_{ETF}={F}^c+{\overline{F}}^s \). Plugging \( {\hat{P}}_{1j} \), into the covariance matrix with the firm price signal and the ETF price signal has no impact on the posterior means or variances.

  16. The fact that the ETF asset can be used as an indirect means of investing based on the private signal comports with a relatively new phenomenon in the financial press. Yahoo!Finance sends targeted messages to users suggesting which ETFs have significant exposure to the individual firms in the user’s portfolio, suggesting that a way to invest in the firm is through the ETF.

  17. In the next section, we fully develop the equilibrium with an infinite number of firms in the ETF; here our purpose is only to cleanly illustrate how hedge plays out in the demand functions.

  18. Perhaps the easiest way to see the diminishing impact of price noise is to note that, at some point, price becomes completely uninformative and additional liquidity noise has no impact on beliefs.

  19. One might be tempted to generalize further and predict that market-wide ETFs are the most valuable of all. However, this would only be true if there were a common component that was being isolated by diversification in the ETF holdings; the more stocks in the ETF, the harder it is to assume that each firm’s payoff has exactly the same common component. In addition, Theorem 3 relies on very high liquidity noise or on a behavioral assumption that traders do not infer information from price; absent this, we are back to Theorem 2.

  20. Assuming N goes to infinity is probably overly restrictive for Theorem 4; technically all that is

    needed is that Φ1(λ) is decreasing in λ.

References

  • Admati, A. 1985. A noisy rational expectations equilibrium for multi-asset securities markets. Econometrica 53 (May): 629–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Admati, A., and P. Pfleiderer. 1987. Viable allocations of information in financial markets. Journal of Economic Theory 43: 76–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alles, M., and R. Lundholm. 1993. On the optimality of public signals in the presence of private information. The Accounting Review 66 (1): 93–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, I., F. Franzoni, and R. Moussawi. 2018. Do ETFs increase volatility? Journal of Finance 73 (6): 2471–2535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, A., and O’Hara, M.. 2017. Can ETFs increase market fragility? Effect of information linkages in ETF markets. City University of New York working paper.

  • Bhojraj, S., Mohanram, P., and Zhang, S. 2018. ETFs and Information Transfer Across Firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics. forthcoming.

  • Black, F. 1986. Noise. Journal of Finance 41: 529–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BlackRock Global ETP 2018 Landscape monthly snapshot. September 2018.

  • Cong, L., and Xu, D.. 2016. Rise of factor investing: asset prices, informational efficiency, and security design. In 29th Australasian Finance and Banking Conference.

  • Eyster, E., M. Rabin, and D. Vayanos. 2019. Financial markets where traders neglect the informational content of prices. Journal of Finance 74 (1): 371–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glosten, L., Nallareddy, S., and Zou, Y. (2016). ETF trading and informational efficiency of underlying securities. Unpublished working Paper.

  • Gorton, G., and G. Pennacchi. 1993. Security baskets and index-linked securities. The Journal of Business 66 (1): 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S., and J. Stiglitz. 1980. On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review 70: 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamm, S. 2014. The effect of ETFs on stock liquidity. Ohio State University working paper.

  • Hirshleifer, D., and S. Teoh. 2003. Limited attention, information disclosure, and financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 36 (1–3): 337–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., and J. Stein. 1999. A unified theory of Underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets. Journal of Finance 54 (6): 2143–2184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., and J. Stein. 2007. Disagreement and the stock market. The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 21 (2): 109–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, S., O’Hara, M., and Zhong, Z. 2018. Innovation and informed trading: Evidence from industry ETFs. November 2018 working paper.

  • Israeli, D., C. Lee, and S. Sridharan. 2017. Is there a dark side to exchange traded funds (ETFs)? An information perspective. Review of Accounting Studies 22 (3): 1048–1083.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, A. 1985. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53 (November): 1315–1335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau, M., and A. Madhavan. 2018. Exchange-traded funds 101 for economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives 32 (1): 135–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, F.W., and Zhu, Q.. 2016. Synthetic shorting with ETFs. University of Texas at Austin working paper.

  • Subrahmanyam, A. 1991. A theory of trading in stock index futures. Review of Financial Studies 4 (1): 17–51.

  • Welch, W. 2014. Properties of the Normal and multivariate Normal distributions. Class note. https://www.stat.ubc.ca/~will/cx/private/normal_properties.pdf

  • Wigglesworth, R. 2018. ETF growth is ‘in danger of devouring capitalism.’ Financial Times. February 4.

  • Zou, Y. 2018. Lost in the rising tide: ETF flows and valuation. Columbia Business School working paper.

Download references

Acknowledgements

Thanks to Paul Fischer, Henry Friedman, Alexander Nezlobin, Thomas Hemmer, and participants at the Brazil Accounting Conference, the Utah Winter Accounting Conference, the McGill Accounting Conference, the University of Miami Workshop, and the Darden Accounting Conference, for their helpful comments. Thanks also to the owners and patrons of CooCoo Coffee for their support over the life of this project.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Russell J. Lundholm.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Lemma 1

Derive the price and value of information in the no-ETF economy as follows. Substitute in the mean and variance values from (2) and (4) into the demand functions in (5) and then substitute these demands into the market clearing condition in (6), and then solve for P0j to get

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{P}_{0j}=\Big\{\lambda \left[\eta +\frac{h{Y}_j^s}{h+s}\right]\left[g+\frac{h{Q}_0}{h+{Q}_0}\right]+\left(1-\lambda \right)\left[\eta +\frac{h\left({Y}_j^s-{K}_0{X}_j\right)}{h+{Q}_0}\right]\left[g+\frac{hs}{h+s}\right]\\ {}\kern2em -\frac{\left(g+\frac{hs}{h+s}\right)\left(g+\frac{h{Q}_0}{h+{Q}_0}\right){X}_j}{\rho}\Big\}\\ {}\kern2em \div \left\{\lambda \left(g+\frac{hs}{h+s}\right)+\left(1-\lambda \right)\left(g+\frac{h{Q}_0}{h+{Q}_0}\right)\right\}.\end{array}} $$
(40)

Note that (40) is linear in \( {Y}_j^s \) and Xj. The equilibrium price is determined by equating the coefficients in (40) with the coefficients in our conjectured price, \( {P}_{0j}={a}_0+{a}_1{Y}_j^s-{a}_2{X}_j \). More precisely, recalling that K0 = a2/a1, we need to equate the ratio of coefficients on Xj \( {Y}_j^s \) in (40) to K0. Defining G = gh + gs + hs, this gives

$$ {K}_0=\frac{\left(1-\lambda \right){hK}_0G+G\left( gh+{gQ}_0+{hQ}_0\right)/\rho }{\lambda h\left( gh+{gQ}_0+{hQ}_0\right)+\left(1-\lambda \right) hG}. $$
(41)

Substitute in \( {Q}_0=s+{K}_0^2w \) from (4) and simplify to get

$$ {K}_0^3-{K}_0^2\left[\frac{G}{\lambda ph}\right]+{K}_0\left[\frac{G}{\left(g+h\right)w}\right]-\frac{G^2}{\lambda ph\left(g+h\right)w}=0. $$
(42)

The solution to this cubic defines the equilibrium K0, and thus the equilibrium coefficients in the price equation. Factoring the cubic yields the unique solution

$$ {K}_0=\left(\frac{a_2}{a_1}\right)=\frac{G}{\lambda \rho h}. $$
(43)

1.2 Lemma 3

The key to taking the limits on the demand functions given in (19)–(22) as N goes to infinity is to note three things. First,

$$ \underset{N\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}} Det\left({V}_{1I}\right)=\frac{ghs}{h+s} and\underset{N\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}} Det\left({V}_{1U}\right)=\frac{ghQ_1}{h+{Q}_1}. $$
(44)

Second, (29) establishes that lim \( \underset{N\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}{K}_1=\frac{s}{\lambda \rho} \) And third, (1 − J) ∈ (0,1).

With this, for the informed traders

$$ \underset{N\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}{D}_{1I}\left( firm\kern0.17em asset\right)=\frac{\rho \left(h+s\right)}{ghs}\left[g\left(\eta +\frac{hY_j^s}{h+s}-{P}_{1j}\right)-g\left(\eta -{P}_{ETF}\right)\right], and $$
(45)
$$ \underset{N\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}{D}_{1I}\left( ETF asset\right)=\frac{\rho \left(h+s\right)}{ghs}\left[-g\left(\eta +\frac{hY_j^s}{h+s}-{P}_{1j}\right)+\left(g+\frac{hs}{h+s}\right)\left(\eta -{P}_{ETF}\right)\right] $$
(46)
$$ =-\underset{N\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}{D}_{1I}\left( firm\ asset\right)+\frac{\rho }{g}\left(\eta -{P}_{ETF}\right). $$
(47)

The same steps yield the same result for the uninformed trader demands.

1.3 Lemma 4

All we need from the equilibrium price vector is the value of K1 written in terms of the exogenous parameters and to verify the initial assumption that the ratio of coefficients b4/b3 in the conjectured pricing equation equals K1. To derive K1 in ETF economy, begin with the demand functions given in Eqs. (19)–(22). To find K1 express the demands generally as linear expressions of the information variables (\( {\mathrm{Y}}_j^s and{\hat{P}}_{ETF}={\overline{Y}}^s-{K}_1\overline{X} \) for the informed and \( {\hat{P}}_{1j}={Y}_j^s-{K}_1{X}_j\ and\ {\hat{P}}_{ETF} \) for the uninformed) and prices to get

$$ {D}_{1I}\left( firm\ asset\right)={\beta}_0+{\beta}_y{Y}_j^s+{\beta}_{\overline{Y}}{\overline{Y}}^s+{\beta}_{\overline{X}}\overline{X}+{\beta}_j{P}_{1j}+{\beta}_{ETF}{P}_{ETF} $$
(48)
$$ {D}_{1U}\left( firm\kern0.17em asset\right)={\gamma}_0+{\gamma}_y{Y}_j^s+{\gamma}_x{X}_j+{\gamma}_{\overline{Y}}{\overline{Y}}^s+{\gamma}_{\overline{X}}\overline{X}+{\gamma}_j{P}_{1j}+{\gamma}_{ETF}{P}_{ETF} $$
(49)

Market clearing for the N firm assets, j=1 to N requires

$$ \lambda {D}_{1I}\left( firm\ asset\right)+\left(1-\lambda \right){D}_{1U}\left( firm\ asset\right)={X}_j. $$
(50)

Substituting the demands into the market clearing equation and solving for P1j gives

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{P}_{1j}=\left[{X}_j-\lambda \left({\beta}_0+{\beta}_y{Y}_j^s+{\beta}_x{X}_j+{\beta}_{\overline{Y}}{\overline{Y}}^s+{\beta}_X\overline{X}+{\beta}_{ETF}{P}_{ETF}\right)-\left(1-\lambda \right)\right)\Big({\gamma}_0+{\gamma}_y{Y}_j^s+\\ {}\kern2.75em {\gamma}_x{X}_j+{\gamma}_{\overline{Y}}{\overline{Y}}^s+{\gamma}_{\overline{X}}\overline{X}+{\gamma}_{ETF}{P}_{ETF}\left)\right]\div \left[\lambda {\beta}_j+\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_j\right].\end{array}} $$
(51)

Note that (51) is linear in (\( {Y}_j^s \), Xj, \( {\overline{Y}}^s \), \( \overline{X} \)) and PETF, and, because PETF is the average of the individual P1j’s, it is linear in (\( {\overline{Y}}^s \), \( \overline{X} \)); consequently, the conjectured linear form of P1j in (9) is validated. From (51) we can pick out the coefficients on (\( {Y}_j^s \), Xj, \( {\overline{Y}}^s \), \( \overline{X} \))

$$ coefficient on{Y}_j^s:\frac{-{\lambda \beta}_y-\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_y}{{\lambda \beta}_j+\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_j}, $$
(52)
$$ coefficient on{X}_j:\frac{1-{\lambda \beta}_x-\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_x}{{\lambda \beta}_j+\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_j}, $$
(53)
$$ coefficient on{\overline{Y}}^s:\frac{-{\lambda \beta}_{\overline{Y}}-\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_{\overline{Y}}}{{\lambda \beta}_j+\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_j}, and $$
(54)

and

$$ coefficient on\overline{X}:\frac{-{\lambda \beta}_{\overline{X}}-\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_{\overline{X}}}{{\lambda \beta}_j+\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_j}. $$
(55)

In the equilibrium conjecture, the ratio of the negative of the coefficient on Xj to the coefficient on \( {Y}_j^s \) equals K1= b2/b1; that is,

$$ {K}_1=\frac{1-{\lambda \beta}_x-\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_x}{{\lambda \beta}_y+\left(1-\lambda \right){\gamma}_y}. $$
(56)

From the demand functions in (19)–(22), we can find the (βx, βy, γx, γy) written in terms of K1. These are

$$ {\beta}_x=0, $$
(57)
$$ {\beta}_y=\frac{\rho }{Det\left({V}_{1I}\right)}\left\{\left[g+\frac{hs+{h}^2\left(1-J\right)}{N\left(h+s\right)}\right]\left[\frac{h}{\left(h+s\right)}\right]-\left[g+\frac{hs}{N\left(h+s\right)}\right]\left[\frac{hK_1^2w}{\left(h+s\right)I}\right]\right\}, $$
(58)
$$ {\gamma}_x=-{\gamma}_y{K}_1. $$
(59)
$$ {\gamma}_y=\frac{\rho }{Det\left({V}_{1U}\right)}\left\{\left[g+\frac{hQ_1}{N\left(h+{Q}_1\right)}\right]\left[\frac{h}{\left(h+{Q}_1\right)}\right]\right\}, and $$
(60)

Plugging (βx, γy, γx) into the ratio for K1 gives the intermediate expression K1λβy = 1. Substituting in βy and simplifying gives the cubic in K1, as shown in (28) in the text.

Also from (19)–(22), we can find (\( {\beta}_{\overline{Y}} \), \( {\beta}_{\overline{X}} \), \( {\gamma}_{\overline{Y}} \), \( {\gamma}_{\overline{X}} \)) to compute the ratio of the coefficients on \( \overline{X} \) and \( {\overline{Y}}^s \) given in (54) and (55):

$$ {\beta}_{\overline{Y}}=-\frac{\rho }{Det\left({V}_{1I}\right)}\left\{\left[g+\frac{hs}{N\left(h+s\right)}\right]\left[\frac{h\left(N-1\right)}{I}\right]\right\}, $$
(61)
$$ {\beta}_{\overline{X}}=-{\beta}_{\overline{Y}}{K}_1, $$
(62)
$$ {\gamma}_{\overline{Y}}=-\frac{\rho }{Det\left({V}_{1U}\right)}\left\{\left[g+\frac{hQ_1}{\left(h+{Q}_1\right)}\right]\left[\frac{h}{\left(h+{Q}_1\right)}\right]\right\}, and $$
(63)
$$ {\gamma}_{\overline{X}}=-{\gamma}_{\overline{Y}}{K}_1. $$
(64)

It is easy to see that the ratio of the negative of the coefficient on \( \overline{X} \) to \( {\overline{Y}}^s \) also equals K1, as originally conjectured in (10).

1.4 Proof of Theorem 2

The sign of the difference between Φ1 and Φ0 is determined by the difference in the ratio of the determinants: \( {\Phi}_1>{\Phi}_0\ when\ \frac{Det\left({V}_{U1}\right)}{Det\left({V}_{I1}\right)}>\frac{Det\left({V}_{U0}\right)}{Det\left({V}_{I0}\right)} \) and visa versa. Label \( \Delta =\frac{Det\left({V}_{U1}\right)}{Det\left({V}_{I1}\right)}-\frac{Det\left({V}_{U0}\right)}{Det\left({V}_{I0}\right)} \). The limiting values of these determinants as N goes to infinity are given in (32) and (44). Plugging them in gives

$$ \Delta =\left[\frac{G}{h+s}\right]\left[\frac{ghQ_1}{h+{Q}_1}\right]-\left[g+\frac{hQ_0}{h+{Q}_0}\right]\left[\frac{ghs}{h+s}\right] $$
(65)
$$ =\frac{gh}{h+s}\left\{\frac{GQ_1\left(h+{Q}_0\right)-\left(h+{Q}_1\right)\left[ hs\left(h+{Q}_0+{hsQ}_0\right)\right]}{\left(h+{Q}_1\right)\left(h+{Q}_0\right)}\right\}. $$
(66)

The sign of Δ is determined by the sign of the numerator in the braces term.

Substitute in \( {Q}_0=s+{K}_0^2w\ and\ {Q}_1=s+{K}_1^2w \) into the numerator of the braces term and collect terms around w to get the following quadratic in w:

$$ {K}_0^2{K}_1^2{ghw}^2-\left({h}^2{sK}_0^2-{GhK}_1^2\right)w=0. $$
(67)

A trivial root is at w=0; when there is no exogenous noise, there is no price noise, and so all private information is conveyed to the market through price and the uninformed effectively have the same information as the informed. The quadratic is then negative for small values of w (meaning that Φ0 > Φ1). After substituting in for K1 and K0, the second root can be found at

$$ {w}^{\ast }=\frac{h\left(h+s\right){\left({\lambda}_j\rho \right)}^2}{Gs} $$
(68)

and the quadratic is increasing in w beyond this point (meaning that Φ1 > Φ0).

1.5 Theorem 3

Consider the case where N is finite, but w goes to infinity. Referring to (8) for the value of information in the no-ETF economy and taking the limit with respect to w gives

$$ \underset{w\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}{\Phi}_0\frac{\rho }{2}\ast \mathit{\ln}\left(\frac{G+{h}^2}{G}\right). $$
(69)

For the ETF economy, refer to (16) for Det(V1I) and note that the only place w appears is as part of J, so that we can compute \( \underset{w\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}\left(1-J\right)=\frac{N-1}{N} \)

With this

$$ \underset{w\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}} Det\left({V}_{1I}\right)=\frac{\left[G+\left(n-1\right) gs\right]h\left(N-1\right)}{N^2\left(h+s\right)}. $$
(70)

Refer to (18) for Det(V1U) and note that w only appears as part of Q1. Substituting in \( s+{K}_1^2w \) for Q1 and taking the limit gives

$$ \underset{w\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}} Det\left({V}_{1U}\right)=\frac{\left( gN+h\right)h\left(N-1\right)}{N^2}. $$
(71)

Putting these together gives the value of information in the ETF market with infinite liquidity noise:

$$ \underset{w\to \infty }{\mathit{\lim}}{\Phi}_1=\frac{\rho }{2}\ast \mathit{\ln}\left(\frac{\left( gN+h\right)\left(h+s\right)}{G+\left(N-1\right) gs}\right). $$
(72)

The difference between the arguments inside the log functions determine the difference between Φ1 and .Φ0. This difference is increasing in N and is zero when N=1. Thus Φ1 > Φ0 for N > 1.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lundholm, R.J. FSA in an ETF world. Rev Account Stud 26, 1428–1455 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-020-09571-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-020-09571-8

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation