Skip to main content
Log in

The effect of California’s top-two primary system on voter turnout in US House Elections

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper evaluates one potential impact of California’s Proposition 14, which created a top-two primary system for all non-Presidential election races within the state. Our analysis is twofold, with the concern of each analysis placed on voter roll off when the result of the top-two primary placed a non-traditional pairing of candidates on the ballot.We focus on U.S. House races using data at the congressional district level to evaluate the impact of a non-traditional general election that omits one of the major parties from the ballot. Using major party registration of the political party omitted from the general election ballot, we find suggestive evidence that voter roll-off increases with these non-traditional contests. These elections do not effect voter turnout as a whole, but can increase voter roll-off by upwards of 7%.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Here, we define voter roll-off as abstention in a down ballot race. For our purposes, the only down ballot races we investigate are for both chambers of Congress, namely, House seats.

  2. There is potential for the effect of same-party candidates and a major party v. minor party ballot to be explored within the paper. However, the small number of observations where a major party candidate is against a minor party of potentially slightly different views makes disentangling this effect difficult. Thus, that case is not presented itself.

  3. This is by no means to say that this effect is ubiquitously accepted in the literature. For a critical analysis of this literature and arguments refuting it, see Alvarez et al. (2006).

  4. This is not to say that California is the only state with this system for federal elections, excluding the Presidency. In 2004, Washington passed a similar measure (initiative 872) which it began using in 2008.

  5. For an overview of dominant theories of primary turnout, see Gerber and Morton (1998).

  6. This is different from strategic voting in general. For example, voters may be willing to vote for a candidate within their party that is not their first choice if they believe that their preferred candidate has a worse chance of winning a general election than their second choice (Cain 1978).

  7. For aggregate effects of voter turnout and roll-off across California and Washington, see Patterson (2020).

  8. With this being for the election of US House of Representatives, our data is only bi-annual and for even numbered years. To our knowledge, redistricting of congressional districts has not occurred since 2012, and thus our data should consistently represent the same district throughout our sample.

  9. District 21 in 2014 and District 1 in 2018 have a turnout for the House race that exceeds that of the Gubernatorial race. Districts 1 and 10 in 2016 have House turnout that exceeds the Presidential turnout in each respective district for 2016.

  10. This presents the possibility of under-predicting voter roll-off if voters chose not to participate in contests higher up on the ballot. In particular, we are only studying specific voter roll-off, that is we are not suggesting that voters are abstaining from any other measures on the ballot. For example, if a voter abstained from the Presidential and House races, they would not be counted in our measure of voter roll-off, even if they voted in another election on the ballot.

  11. For a description of PVI, see Moskowitz et al. (2019).

  12. These elections can be solid, likely, lean, or toss-up Democrat or Republican.

  13. For reference of the number of races, see Table 1.

  14. Presidential turnout is used for 2012 and 2016, while Gubernatorial turnout is used for 2014 and 2018.

  15. Republican v. Other party was omitted from the analysis as there was only one occurrence of that combination.

  16. Important to mention is that the only variation of the analysis is the one where the four observations with a greater House turnout than the turnout for President or Governor are included in their raw form. The results are consistent across the other specifications, however.

References

  • Ahler DJ, Citrin J, Lenz GS (2016) Do open primaries improve representation? An experimental test of California’s 2012 top-two primary. Legis Stud Q 41(2):237–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez RM, Nagler J (1997) Analysis of crossover and strategic voting. Social Science Working Paper 1019, California Institute of Technology, pp. 1-44

  • Alvarez RM, Sinclair B (2012) Electoral institutions and legislative behavior: the effects of primary processes. Polit Res Q 65(3):544–557

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez RM, Sinclair B, Hasen RL (2006) How much is enough? The “ballot order effect” and the use of social science research in election law disputes. Elect Law J 5(1):40–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Augenblick N, Nicholson S (2015) Ballot position, choice fatigue, and voter behaviour. Rev Econ Stud 83(2):460–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battaglini M, Morton RB, Palfrey TR (2010) The swing voter’s curse in the laboratory. Rev Econ Stud 77(1):61–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bendor J, Diermeier D, Ting M (2003) A behavioral model of turnout. Am Polit Sci Rev 97(2):261–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Case A (2003) Political institutions and policy choices: evidence from the United States. J Econ Liter 41(1):7–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais A (2006) What affects voter turnout? Annu Rev Polit Sci 9:111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blom-Hansen J, Elklit J, Serritzlew S, Villadsen LR (2016) Ballot position and election results: evidence from a natural experiment. Elect Stud 44:172–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonneau CW, Cann DM (2015) Party identification and vote choice in partisan and nonpartisan elections. Polit Behav 37(1):43–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brockington D (2003) A low information theory of ballot position effect. Polit Behav 25(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bullock W, Clinton JD (2011) More a molehill than a mountain: the effects of the blanket primary on elected officials’ behavior from California. J Polit 73(3):915–930

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cain BE (1978) Strategic voting in Britain. Am J Polit Sci 22:639–655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calcagno PT, Westley C (2008) An institutional analysis of voter turnout: the role of primary type and the expressive and instrumental voting hypotheses. Const Polit Econ 19(2):94–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Däubler T, Rudolph L (2018) Cue-taking, satisficing, or both? Quasi-experimental evidence for ballot position effects. Polit Behav 42:1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Donovan T (2008) The Limbaugh effect: a rush to judging cross-party raiding in the 2008 democratic nomination contests. In: The forum (vol 6), pp 1-8

  • Donovan T (2012) The top two primary: What can California learn from Washington? Calif J Polit Policy 4(1):1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen TJ, Pesendorfer W (1996) The swing voter’s curse. Am Econ Rev 86:408–424

    Google Scholar 

  • Fowler JH (2006) Habitual voting and behavioral turnout. J Polit 68(2):335–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber ER, Morton RB (1998) Primary election systems and representation. J Law Econ Organ 86:304–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber AS, Green DP, Shachar R (2003) Voting may be habit-forming: evidence from a randomized field experiment. Am J Polit Sci 47(3):540–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green DP, Shachar R (2000) Habit formation and political behaviour: evidence of consuetude in voter turnout. Br J Polit Sci 30(4):561–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Großer J, Schram A (2010) Public opinion polls, voter turnout, and welfare: an experimental study. Am J Polit Sci 54(3):700–717

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Highton B, Huckfeldt R, Hale I (2016) Some general consequences of California’s top-two primary system. Calif J Polit Policy 8(2):1–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson GC (2004) Partisan and ideological polarization in the California electorate. State Polit Policy Q 4:113–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jewitt CE, Treul SA (2014) Competitive primaries and party division in congressional elections. Elect Stud 35:140–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jun B-H, Min H (2017) What creates heterogeneity in ballot order effects? Evidence from Korea’s local elections of education superintendent. Elect Stud 46:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim N, Krosnick J, Casasanto D (2015) Moderators of candidate name-order effects in elections: an experiment. Polit Psychol 36(5):525–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King A, Leigh A (2009) Are ballot order effects heterogeneous? Soc Sci Q 90(1):71–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein D, Baum L (2001) Ballot information and voting decisions in judicial elections. Polit Res Q 54(4):709–728

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin D (2019) Party ambiguity and individual preferences. Elect Stud 57:19–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGhee E (2015) California’s top two primary and the business agenda. Calif J Polit Policy 7(1):1–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Meredith M, Salant Y (2013) On the causes and consequences of ballot order effects. Polit Behav 35(1):175–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moskowitz DJ, Schneer B et al (2019) Reevaluating competition and turnout in US house elections. Q J Polit Sci 14(2):191–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagler J (2015) Voter behavior in California’s top two primary. Calif J Polit Policy 7(1):1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Patterson S Jr (2020) Estimating the unintended participation penalty under top-two primaries with a discontinuity design. Elect Stud 68:102231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierson P (2000) Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics. Am Polit Sci Rev 94(2):251–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plutzer E (2002) Becoming a habitual voter: inertia, resources, and growth in young adulthood. Am Polit Sci Rev 96(1):41–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rekker R, Rosema M (2019) How (often) do voters change their consideration sets? Elect Stud 57:284–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair B, Wray M (2015) Googling the top two: information search in California’s top two primary. Calif J Polit Policy 7(1):1–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Sparks S (2018) Campaign spending and the top-two primary: how challengers earn more votes per dollar in one-party contests. Elect Stud 54:56–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sparks S (2019) Polarization and the top-two primary: moderating candidate rhetoric in one-party contests. Polit Commun 36:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward DG, Tavits M (2019) How partisan affect shapes citizens’ perception of the political world. Elect Stud 60:102045

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Joshua Hall and Laura Buffett-Jackson for their helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel D. Bonneau.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bonneau, D.D., Zaleski, J. The effect of California’s top-two primary system on voter turnout in US House Elections. Econ Gov 22, 1–21 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-021-00249-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-021-00249-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation