Skip to main content
Log in

Choregia and trierarchy as profit-oriented entrepreneurships

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

With regards to the model of the homo oeconomicus this paper argues that incentives for performing liturgies in classical Athens were based on profit-oriented calculation rather than desire to gain support for public offices. In classical Athens democratic measures diminished the power of single-person offices which led to a decrease in the desire to hold such offices by the aristocracy. Simultaneously, recourse to altruistic incentives is incompatible with the costs of liturgies and the effort some members of Athens society made in order to perform them. Careful examination of past research on liturgical spending in classical Athens and an analysis of coeval conditions show the validity of economic instruments that lead to a rational-actor perspective on public spending under the incentive of financial gain rather than non-monetary profit.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For further elaboration see: Meyer (1895), Wagner-Hasel (2011).

  2. For a detailed analysis of market economics see Mankiw and Taylor (2010).

  3. See Kirsch (2004), 170–175.

  4. For a detailed examination of the direct democracy of Athens using a political economy perspective see Tridimas (2011).

  5. For detailed information cf. Herodotus (2003) VII. 138–144.

  6. Lysias (2004) XIX. 42, XXI. 2; (Gabrielsen 1994, 216).

  7. For an economic perspective on Athenian trade policies see Woolmer (2016).

  8. Cf. FGrH 328 F33 Atthis; (Wilson 2011, 40).

References

  • Amemiya, T. (2007). Economy and economics of ancient Greece. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bleicken, J. (1995). Die athenische Demokratie. Paderborn: Schöningh.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bücher, K. (1906). Die entstehung der volkswirtschaft. Tübingen: Laupp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christ, M. R. (2006). The bad citizen in classical Athens. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Christ, M. (2008). The bad citizen in classical Athens. Cambridge: Cambridge Unviersity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Csapo, E. (2004). The context of ancient drama. Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demosthenes (2003). Speeches Victor Bers, (Trans.). Austin: University of Texas Press.

  • Eich, A. (2006). Die politische Ökonomie des antiken Griechenland (6.–3. Jahrhundert vor Christus). Cologne: Böhlau.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finley, M. I. (1973). The ancient economy. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabrielsen, V. (1994). Financing the Athenian fleet. Public taxation and social relations. London: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, J. R. (2007). Let’s hear it for the fat man. In C. Miller (Ed.), Origins of theatre in ancient Greece (pp. 96–107). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herman, G. (1998). Reciprocity, altruism and prisoners dilemma. In C. Gill (Ed.), Reciprocity in ancient Greece (pp. 199–225). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herodotus (2003). The Histories (A. de Sélincourt, Trans.) London: Penguin Books.

  • Kaiser, B. A. (2007). The Athenian trierarchy: Mechanism design for the private provision of public goods. The Journal of Economic History, 67(2), 445–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirsch, G. (2004). Neue politische ökonomie. Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lysias (2004). Reden (I. Huber, Trans.). Darmstadt: Wiss. Buchges.

  • Lyttkens, C. H. (1997). A rational-actor perspective on the origin of liturgies in ancient Greece. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 153, 462–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G., & Taylor, M. (2010). Economics. Andover: South-Western Cengage Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, E. (1895). Die wirtschaftliche Entwicklung des Altertums: Ein Vortrag, gehalten auf der dritten Versammlung Deutscher Historiker in Frankfurt a. M. am 20. April 1985. Jena. Fischer.

  • Pomeroy, S. B. (1999). Ancient Greece. A political, social and cultural history. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchard, D. M. (2013). Sport, democracy and war in classical Athens. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett, W. K. (1991). The Greek state at war 5. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raaflaub, K. A. (1998). The transformation of Athens in the 5th century. In D. Boedeker & K. A. Raaflaub (Eds.), Democracy, empire, and the arts in fifth-century Athens (pp. 17–43). Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raaflaub, K. A. (2007). The Breakthrough of Demokratia in Mid-Fifth-Century Athens. In K. A. Raaflaub, J. Ober, & R. W. Wallace (Eds.), Origins of Democracy in Ancient Greece (pp. 105–164). Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Thukydides (1991). Geschichte des Peloponnesischen Krieges (P. Landmann, Trans.). Munich: Dt. Taschenbuch.

  • Tridimas, G. (2011). A political economy perspective of direct democracy in ancient Athens. Constitutional Political Economy, 22, 58–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tridimas, G. (2013). Homo oeconomicus in ancient Athens: Silver bonanza and the choice to build a navy. Homo Oeconomicus, 30(4), 435–458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner-Hasel, B. (2011). Die Arbeit des Gelehrten. Der Nationalökonom Karl Bücher (pp. 1847–1930). Frankfurt a.M: Campus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, P. (2000). The Athenian institution of the khoregia: The chorus, the city and the stage. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, P. (2011). The glue of democracy—Tragedy, structure and finance. In D. M. Carter (Ed.), Why Athens?—Reappraisal of tragic politics (pp. 19–44). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Woolmer, M. (2016). Forging links between regions. In E. M. Harris, D. M. Lewis, & M. Woolmer (Eds.), The ancient Greek economy—Markets, households and city–states (pp. 149–165). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joshua Günther.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We wish to thank the anonymous reviewers for their comments and suggestions on earlier drafts of this paper. Special thanks hereby to Roland Oetjen, who introduced us to New Institutional Economics and supported us throughout our research. Responsibility for any errors remaining is ours alone.

Glossary

Glossary

Archon:

One of the nine highest offices in archaic Athens

Areopagus:

Aristocratic council. Oversaw laws and magistrates

Arete:

Moral virtue

Basileus:

High priest of ancient Athens

Choregia:

Theatrical liturgy that enables the carrier to train and finance a chorus for a festival

Cleisthenes’ reforms:

Reorganization of the Athenian political structure in democratic fashion in order to break up existing power-bases in the society

Club good:

Good bound by excludability, not rivalness

Common property resource:

Good bound by rivalness, not excludability

Council of Five Hundred:

Executive power in classical Athens

Delian League:

Association of Greek city states 478–404, members numbering between 150 and 330 with purpose to uphold the hegemony in the Mediterranean

Demos:

Citizens of a polis

Eisphora:

War tax that was introduced in times of need. Poll tax implemented on the richest citizens

Ekklesia:

Assembly of Athens, carrying out legislative powers

Free riding:

Act of gaining utility of a good without paying for it

Heliaia:

Supreme court of ancient Athens

Lamian War:

War that led to Athens final defeat against Macedonia in 322

Liturgy:

Appropriation of goods by the richest members of a society as alternative to poll tax

Metic:

Foreigner currently or permanently residing in Athens

Pentecontaetia:

Fifty years between Persian Wars and Peloponnesian War

Polemarch:

Commander in chief

Polis:

Greek city state

Private good:

Good bound by both, excludability and rivalness

Public good:

Good bound by neither excludability, nor rivalness

Solon’s reforms:

Reorganization of the Athenian polis in order to overcome disparity. Allocation of citizens in four classes according to emblements. Political rights varied between the classes

Thesmothetai:

Six junior archons. Mainly organizational character for trials

Trierarchy:

Liturgy that enables the carrier to finance and command a warship for a year

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Günther, J., Hahn, F. Choregia and trierarchy as profit-oriented entrepreneurships. Const Polit Econ 30, 177–193 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09276-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09276-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation