Skip to main content
Log in

Household-Based Clientelism: Brokers’ Allocation of Temporary Public Works Programs in Argentina

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper argues that political brokers pay particular attention to household size, and the age distribution of its members, when allocating scarce indivisible social benefits. Because people usually share their income with other household members, allocating a social benefit to an individual member of a household with n voters is likely to bring more political support than allocating the same benefit to an individual member of a household with n-1 voters. Based on the main Argentine household survey and on personal interviews with 120 brokers, this paper shows that brokers effectively collect information on family size and age composition and allocate scarce temporary public works programs to families with more voters, unintentionally discriminating against families with children not old enough to vote.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Clientelism is usually defined as the personal and discretionary allocation of resources to individuals in exchange for their political support (e.g., vote buying, turnout buying, abstention buying, and double persuasion). It is the discretionary and conditional way in which goods and services are allocated what makes an exchange clientelistic rather than what is distributed. See Gans-Morse et al. (2014) for a formal model explaining diverse clientelistic strategies.

  2. Seminal research on the economics of intra-household resource allocation includes Becker (1964) and on parental political socialization Jennings and Niemi (1968).

  3. Two aspects of this claim deserve some discussion. First, as with any normative assessment, it could be criticized pointing out that it is based on a particular theory of justice. However, the fact that governments around the world declare that a key objective of social policy is to target vulnerable families indicates that it is a popular normative assessment. Second, there is no unique definition of vulnerability. It is usually understood that a household is more vulnerable the lower the level of income per capita, the higher the volatility of income, and the higher the dependency ratio. Therefore, ceteris paribus, households with more children (i.e., higher dependency ratio) are more vulnerable.

  4. See Magaloni (2006), Rakove (1975), and Wang and Kurzman (2007).

  5. The Peronist Party is a working and lower class party founded by Juan D. Perón in 1947. While its origins are linked to the emergence of working classes, it shifted during the Presidency of Carlos Menem (1989–1999) from seeking the support of the lower classes through unions to courting their support with clientelistic appeals (Levitsky 2003). Since re-democratization in 1983, the PJ has won 5 out of 8 Presidential elections and has always controlled most Provincial and Municipal executives.

  6. Lindbeck and Weibull (1987), Nichter (2008), Stokes (2005), and Zarazaga (2016).

  7. Cox and McCubbins (1986), and Dixit and Londregan (1996).

  8. Finan and Schechter (2012), and Lawson and Greene (2014).

  9. Schaffer and Baker (2015) constitute an exception. They argue and provide evidence from Mexico that brokers target citizens who are opinion-leading epicenters in informal conversation networks. Therefore, the political effect of a single handout can be magnified via the conversion of multiple voters.

  10. Keefer and Vlaicu (2007), Kitschelt and Wilkinson (2007), Fisman and Golden (2017), O’Donnell (1992), Piattoni (2001), and Schaffer (2007).

  11. Garay (2007), Giraudy (2007), Lodola (2005), Ronconi (2009), Ronconi and Franceschelli (2007), Szwarcberg (2012).

  12. For example, according to the 2010 census, 48% of households have a personal computer in greater Buenos Aires, while the figures for the studied municipalities are 42% in La Matanza, 44% in Malvinas, 39% in Merlo, and 50% in San Miguel. La Matanza, with 834,000 voters has by itself a bigger electorate than 17 of the 24 Argentine provinces. Each of the other three municipalities in this study (Merlo 326,000, Malvinas Argentinas 203,000, and San Miguel 186,000 voters) has electorates equal or bigger than provinces like Formosa, Tierra del Fuego, and Santa Cruz.

  13. Ollier (2010), and Stokes et al. (2013).

  14. Auyero (2001), Brusco et al. (2004), Calvo and Murillo (2013), and Zarazaga (2014).

  15. According to the EPH, only 3.5% of the poor population changed neighborhood during the last 5 years.

  16. The figures are based on what brokers report in the interview. We did not systematically collect information on voters to test the accuracy of brokers’ reports. Schneider (2016) finds that brokers have little ability to identify the partisan preferences of non-core voters in rural India. We claim that brokers have fine-grained information about household size and age composition (two easily observable characteristics) in urban Argentina.

  17. See http://www.desarrollosocial.gob.ar/argentinatrabaja/.

  18. The program was launched in October 2009 and the majority of funds have been allocated to some municipalities located in greater Buenos Aires. Coincidentally, this is an area where the PJ usually wins elections, but suffered a defeat in the legislative elections of June 2009.

  19. The EPH is available at www.indec.gob.ar.

  20. Which are running water, sewerage, town gas, without dirt floors, and not located in a shantytown.

  21. See Kramon and Posner (2013).

  22. The EPH survey does not directly ask about access to the AUH. But, there is information that allows building a reasonable proxy. First, the head of household reports in the survey whether she/he receives subsidies or aid in money from the government or from civil and religious organizations. Second, she/he reports the amount of money received last month. Because we know the number of children under 18 years of age in the household, we can estimate whether the subsidy received refers to the AUH or not. For example, until October 2010, the AUH monthly benefit was pesos 144 per month for each child under the age of 18. Therefore, if a household with two children under the age of 18 reports receiving pesos 288 on subsidies, it can be assumed that it receives AUH. That is how we create the variable AUH, which adopts a value equal to one if the amount of money reported is between 10% below or above the expected amount given the number of children 17 years or less in the household; and 0 otherwise.

  23. The coefficients for the other variables usually have the expected sign: Poorer people, with fewer years of schooling, and who have not recently move into the neighborhood, are more likely to receive a temporary public works program.

  24. We also run the model for each of six Argentine geographic regions separately, and find that in all regions temporary public works programs are more likely to be allocated to individuals who are members of families with more voting members (that is, the variable Voters is positive and statistically significant in all regions, while Non-voters is always insignificant). Results available upon request to the authors.

  25. People who met the eligibility conditions, and registered between April and May 2002, automatically entered into the program. From this perspective, JJHD was universal. However, some people who met the eligibility conditions missed the registration deadline. They applied late, and only some of them were admitted. Iturriza et al. (2011) suggest that those who applied late and did not enter the program represent 15% of program participants. From this other perspective, JJHD was quasi-universal.

References

  • Auyero J. Poor people’s politics: peronist survival networks and the legacy of Evita. Durham: Duke University Press; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G. Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education. New York: Columbia University Press; 1964.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brusco V, Nazareno M, Stokes S. Vote buying in Argentina. Lat Am Res Rev. 2004;39:66–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo E, Murillo MV. When parties meet voters: partisan networks and distributive expectations in Argentina and Chile. Comp Pol Stud. 2013;46:851–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox G, McCubbins M. Electoral politics as a redistributive game. J Polit. 1986;48:370–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Londregan J. The determinants of success of special interests in redistributive politics. J Polit. 1996;58:1132–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finan F, Schechter L. Vote buying and reciprocity. Econometrica. 2012;80:863–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman R, Golden M. Corruption: what everyone needs to know. New York: Oxford University Press; 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gans-Morse J, Mazzuca S, Nichter S. Varieties of clientelism: machine politics during elections. Am J Polit Sci. 2014;58(2):415–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garay C. Social policy and collective action: unemployed workers, community associations, and protests in Argentina. Polit Soc. 2007;35:301–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giraudy A. The distributive politics of emergency employment programs in Argentina (1993-2002). Lat Am Res Rev. 2007;42:33–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iturriza, A, Bedi A, Sparrow R. Unemployment assistance and transition to employment in Argentina. Economic Development and Cultural Change 2011;59(4):811-37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jennings K, Niemi R. The transmission of political values from parent to child. Am Polit Sci Rev. 1968;62:169–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keefer P, Vlaicu R. Democracy, credibility, and clientelism. J Law Econ Organ. 2007;24(2):371–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitschelt H, Wilkinson S. Patrons, clients, and policies: patterns of democratic accountability and political competition. Cambridge: Cambridge Univerisity Press; 2007.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kramon E, Posner D. Who benefits from distributive politics? How the outcome one studies affects the answer one gets. Perspect Polit. 2013;11(2):461–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson C, Greene K. Making clientelism work: how norms of reciprocity increase voter compliance. Comp Polit. 2014;47(1):61–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitsky S. Transforming labor-based parties in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Weibull J. Balanced budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice. 1987;52:273–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lodola G. Protesta popular y redes clientelares en la Argentina: El reparto federal del Plan Trabajar (1996-2001). Desarrollo Económico. 2005;44:515–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magaloni B. Voting for autocracy: hegemonic party survival and its demise in Mexico. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2006.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nichter S. Vote buying or turnout buying? Machine politics and the secret ballot. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2008;102:19–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell G. 1992. “Delegative Democracy,” Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame, Hellen Kellog Institute for International Studies, Working paper 172.

  • Ollier M. Atrapada sin salida. Buenos Aires: UNSAM; 2010.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piattoni S. Clientelism in historical and comparative perspective. In: Piattoni S, editor. Clientelism, interests, and democratic representation: the European experience in historical and comparative perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2001.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rakove M. Don’t back no losers: an insider’s analysis of the Daley machine. Bloomington: Indiana University Press; 1975. Don't Make No Waves..

    Google Scholar 

  • Ronconi L. Estimates of the benefit incidence of workfare. Economia J LACEA. 2009;9:129–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ronconi L, Franceschelli I. Clientelism, public workfare, and the emergence of the Piqueteros in Argentina. In: Dinello N, Popov V, editors. Political institutions and development: failed expectations and renewed hopes. London: Edward Elgar; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaffer F. Why study vote buying? In: Schaffer F, editor. Elections for sale. London: Lynne Rienner Publishers; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaffer J, Baker A. Clientelism as persuasion-buying: evidence from Latin America. Comp Polit Stud. 2015;48(9):1093–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider M 2016. “Do brokers know their voters? A test of Guessability in India”. J Polit, Forthcoming.

  • Stokes S. Perverse accountability: a formal model of machine politics with evidence from Argentina. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2005;99:315–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokes S. Political clientelism. In: Goodin R, editor. The Oxford Handbook of Political Science. New York: Oxford University Press; 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokes S, Dunning T, Nazareno M, Brusco V. Brokers, voters and clientelism. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2013.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Szwarcberg M. Uncertainty, political clientelism, and voter turnout in Latin America: why parties conduct rallies in Argentina. Comp Polit. 2012;45:88–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang C-S, Kurzman C. The logistics: how to buy votes. In: Schaffer F, editor. Elections for Sale. London: Lynne Rienner Publishers; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zarazaga R. Brokers beyond clientelism: a new perspective on brokerage through the argentine case. Latin Am Polit Soc. 2014;56:23–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarazaga R. Instituciones, Política y Necesidad en los Programas de Transferencias Condicionadas: La Asignación Universal por Hijo y el Programa de Inclusión Social con Trabajo Argentina Trabaja. In: Acuña C, editor. Instituciones y políticas públicas en Argentina. Buenos Aires: Siglo; 2013. p. XXI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zarazaga R. Party machines and voter-customized rewards strategies. J Theor Polit. 2016;28(4):678–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lucas Ronconi.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ronconi, L., Zarazaga, R. Household-Based Clientelism: Brokers’ Allocation of Temporary Public Works Programs in Argentina. St Comp Int Dev 54, 365–380 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-019-09280-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-019-09280-7

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation