Skip to main content
Log in

Relationship Networks in Banking Around a Sovereign Default and Currency Crisis

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study how banks’ exposure to a sovereign crisis gets transmitted onto the corporate sector. To do so, we use data on the universe of banks and firms in Argentina during the crisis of 2001. We build a model characterized by matching frictions in which firms establish (long-term) relationships with banks that are subject to balance sheet disruptions. Credit relationships with banks more exposed to the crisis suffer the most. However, this relationship-level effect overstates the true cost of the crisis since profitable firms (e.g., exporters after a devaluation) might find it optimal to switch lenders, reducing the negative impact on overall credit and activity. Using linked bank-firm and firm-level data, we find evidence largely consistent with our theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Central Bank of Argentina

Fig. 2

Source: International Financial Statistics of the IMF, Argentina Secretary of the Treasury, and Instituto Nacional de Estadísticas y Censos (INDEC)

Fig. 3

Source: Central Bank of Argentina

Fig. 4

Source: Central Bank of Argentina

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The poverty rate is defined as the fraction of population living below the upper middle income poverty line of $5.50, as published by the World Bank.

  2. See Sect. 2 for a review of the events prior, during and after the default of 2001.

  3. One observation is that, as in Bocola (2016) and Rojas (2018), the decision of the sovereign to default or leave the currency peg is not actually modeled. Any financial shock that has qualitatively similar implications for banks would operate in the same way, whether it was the result of a government default or not. Default events (e.g., Argentina 2001) or episodes of high default risk have provided valuable natural experiments for teasing out the effects of financial shocks in the cross section of firms. We note however that our empirical strategy prevents us from fully capturing the cost of default as they arise from general equilibrium effects.

  4. Other papers have focused on imports rather than exports as a way to document negative effects of sovereign default or devaluations (e.g., Mendoza and Yue 2012; Gopinath and Neiman 2014). We focus on exports instead for two reasons. First, we use the exporter nature of some firms in our sample as a way to identify positive credit demand shocks. Second, our dataset of the universe of firms in Argentina does not include the importer identifiers.

  5. The theoretical model is presented in detail in “Appendix 1”.

  6. Also related are Paravisini (2008), Becker and Ivashina (2014) and Greenstone et al. (2014).

  7. Their sample consists of a very small set of companies. We contribute by looking at all firms in Argentina.

  8. Following the Tequila crisis, the Central Bank of Argentina required all supervised institutions to report on a monthly basis the status of all loans outstanding in excess of 50 pesos (equivalent to US$50 at the time).

  9. Our definition of debt between bank i and firm j includes all credit available from bank i to firm j.

  10. In 2001 corporate bonds represented 8.19% of GDP and corporate loans 24.3% of GDP. It is important to note that risk-rating agencies placed most corporate bonds in selective default status (see Fernandez et al. 2007), making it almost impossible for firms to access new credit via the corporate debt market.

  11. Non-deposit liabilities correspond to total liabilities denominated in foreign currency minus deposits denominated in foreign currency. We then calculate the ratio to total assets. This is the relevant measure of exposure of the banking sector to the devaluation since, as we describe in Sect. 2, the government converted dollar denominated deposits into pesos in 2002 at the 1.4 to 1 exchange rate (pesos per dollar) and all domestic credit denominated in foreign currency at the 1 to 1 exchange rate (pesos per dollar).

  12. Unfortunately, we do not have access to additional data sources for the size of the firms, such as employees, sales or assets.

  13. The number of banks or banking relationships is measured as the number of banks for which we observe a positive loan amount for firm j in any period t. A new relationship is defined as a banking relationship that was not active prior to the default event and becomes active (i.e., has positive loans) after the default. The age of the relationship counts the number of months from the start of the relationship until the last appearance in our sample. All active firm-bank relationships receive an age equal to 1 at the beginning of our sample in June 1999 (i.e., the sample is left censored for existing relationships in 1999). For example, a relationship that is continuously active from the start of the sample until December 2001 has an age equal to 31 months. The same relationship (if it remained active) would have an age of 45 months in December 2003 and so on.

  14. Table 10 in the appendix presents summary statistics for all variables used in the empirical analysis. In particular, we also present additional bank balance sheet ratios, different measures of the size of the banking network, and additional statistics at the firm level such as its credit status (a default indicator). Tables 11 and 12, also in the appendix, present the distribution of the number of banking relationships and the distribution of the age of the banking relationships conditional on export status, respectively.

  15. As we described in Sect. 2, after the sovereign default the Argentine government “pesified” dollar denominated deposits at the 1.4 to 1 exchange rate (pesos per dollar), effectively reducing the liability exposure to the devaluation. To capture this idea, in our measure of exposure we include only non-deposit liabilities in foreign currency.

  16. This growth measure is standard in the establishment and firm dynamics literature (e.g., Haltiwanger et al. 2013). It shares some properties of log differences but also allows us to capture entry and exit into credit relationships. We use it in this section to be consistent with the measure we utilize when analyzing lending relationships at the firm-bank level and firm level. Variables for 2001 correspond to the average of year 2001. Bank type k can be public banks (i.e., government owned), domestic private banks, foreign private banks, or other.

  17. “Appendix 3” presents several robustness checks that involve including additional controls.

  18. Results do not change if we include only time fixed effects, only bank-type fixed effects, or time and bank-type fixed effects separately.

  19. The p values presented in Table 2 are based on standard errors that do not correct for heteroscedasticity. The significance level of sovereign debt exposure is unaffected when using standard errors clustered by bank type-time. Similarly, the significance level on the foreign currency exposure coefficient is significant only at the 15% in column 4 of Table 2 but remains significant at the 10 percent level in all other columns when clustering by bank type-time.

  20. This is particularly important for small and medium-sized firms that characterized the corporate sector in Argentina during the 2001/2002 crisis (and still do). These firms tend to be relatively more opaque, operate less diversified product lines, have less access to the management systems, and allocate a smaller fraction of their assets to fixed assets that can be used as collateral. Notice that the increased concentration and internationalization of Argentine banking during the 1990s further hindered credit access for these firms since private and foreign banks are known for concentrating their business on clients with lower opacity more than public and domestic banks.

  21. If firms’ demand for credit is bank specific (after controlling for observable characteristics of the bank and the relationship), the identification strategy is not valid. One concern is the case where banks that specialize in firms that export had a larger exposure to sovereign debt or foreign currency non-deposit liabilities and suffer a larger balance sheet shock than other banks.

  22. Table 1 presents summary statistics at the firm level. This table shows that the average firm has 1.47 banking relationships, implying that many firms in our sample have only one banking relationship (pre and post-default). In particular, Table 11 in the appendix shows that 34.7% (pre-default) and 41.6% (post-default) of the volume of loans in our sample correspond to firms in the sample have only one banking relationship (this amounts to 69.9% and 76.2% of the firms in the sample, pre- and post-default, respectively). In addition, only 24% of the volume of loans within firms with positive export status have one relationship.

  23. When estimating the effects at the firm level and using the full sample, we show that the estimated effects are robust to controlling for the number of banking relationships. In addition, we follow Khwaja and Mian (2008) who use the correlation between the supply and demand effects derived from the difference between the fixed effects estimates at the relationship-level [see Eq. (3)] and the OLS estimates of the same equation at the firm-level (estimated including firms with more than one banking relationship as well) to show that the estimates at the firm level, if biased, underestimate the true effects.

  24. p values presented in Table  3 correspond to robust standard errors. Results are unaffected if standard errors are computed by clustering at the firm level.

  25. In addition, we follow Khwaja and Mian (2008) to address a potential bias when working with firm level data.

  26. We do not have access to detailed balance sheet information (such as foreign currency composition of liabilities) outside the banking sector. Working with a sample that contains balance sheet information would require us to focus on a very small sample of firms (those publicly listed in Argentina) as opposed to the universe of firms as we do here. Using the set of publicly listed firms for Argentina and Mexico, Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2016) find that domestic exporters holding unhedged foreign currency debt decrease investment.

  27. p values presented in Table 4 based on standard errors clustered at the firm level. Results are unaffected if p values are derived from robust standard errors. This is also valid for all the firm level regressions that follow.

  28. To remove outliers, we filtered firms that are in the bottom 5% and top 2% of the total debt (i.e., sum of debt with all banks) distribution. Results are robust if, as opposed to removing firms, we winsorize the sample and only remove observations.

  29. We performed the statistical test to corroborate whether the coefficient on sovereign debt exposure is different for non-exporters than for exporters. Effectively we can reject the null that the coefficients are equal at the 10 percent level. We performed a similar test for Foreign currency exposure and while the coefficient on exporters is not significant, we cannot reject the null that it is equal to the coefficient for non-exporters.

  30. The negative effect of the foreign currency exposure of their banking network is still present and significantly larger than for firms that do not export when we do not control for the number of banks and the fraction of new relationships in the banking network.

  31. We performed the statistical test to corroborate whether the coefficients on sovereign debt exposure and foreign currency exposure is different for non-exporters than for exporters. We cannot reject the null that the coefficients for exporters are equal to the coefficient for non-exporters.

  32. A bias could arise if, for example, more profitable exporters were better able to adapt to the adverse macroenvironment after the default and devaluation.

  33. Olivero and Yuan (2011) also provide evidence on the magnitude of these switching costs.

  34. Table 21 in the appendix shows the full set of regression specifications related to the probability of starting new relationships.

  35. The last column of Table 7 controls for banking networks characteristics such as liquidity, leverage and net income in 2001.

  36. The credit situation of a loan can take 5 values: 1 normal situation, 2 low risk, 3 medium risk, 4 high risk/insolvent, 5 written off.

  37. The full set of results is presented in Table 23 in the appendix.

  38. When working with the relationship level sample, which given its granularity is more prone to the presence of outliers, we applied a more stringent relationship level filter. In particular, after applying filters 1 and 2, we eliminate relationships with less than 6 observations, to then apply filters 3 and 4. Results at the firm level are unaffected by the filter we use.

References

  • Adrian, Tobias, Paolo Colla, and Hyun Song Shin. 2012. Which Financial Frictions? Parsing the Evidence from 2007–2009. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, ed. Daron Acemoglu, Jonathan Parker, and Michael Woodford, vol. 27.

  • Alfaro, Laura, Manuel García-Santana, and Enrique Moral-Benito. 2019. On the Direct and Indirect Real Effects of Credit Supply Shocks. NBER Working Paper No 25458.

  • Amiti, Mary, and David Weinstein. 2018. How Much do Idiosyncratic Bank Shocks Affect Investment? Evidence from Matched Bank-Firm Loan Data. Journal of Political Economy 26(2): 525–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, Cristina, Yan Bai, and Luigi Bocola. 2017. Sovereign Default Risk and Firm Heterogeneity. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 23314.

  • Becker, Bo, and Victoria Ivashina. 2014. Cyclicality of Credit Supply: Firm Level Evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics 62: 76–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, Allen N., Leora F. Klapper, and Gregory F. Udell. 2001. The Ability of Banks to Lend to Informationally Opaque Small Businesses. Journal of Banking & Finance 25: 2127–2167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bleger, Leonardo, and Guillermo Rozenwurcel. 2000. Financiamiento a las PyMES y cambio estructural en la Argentina. Un estudio de caso sobre fallas de mercado y problemas de información. Desarrollo Económico 40(157): 45–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bocola, Luigi. 2016. The Pass-Through of Sovereign Risk. Journal of Political Economy 124(4): 879–926.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bottero, Margherita, Simone Lenzu, and Filippo Mezzanotti. 2015. Sovereign Debt Exposure and the Bank Lending Channel: Impact on Credit Supply and the Real Economy. Bank of Italy Temi di Discussione (Working Paper) No 1032.

  • Calomiris, Charles, and Andrew Powell. 2001. Can Emerging Market Bank Regulators Establish Credible Discipline? The Case of Argentina, 1992–99. In Prudential Supervision: What Works and What Doesn’t, ed. Frederic Mishkin, 147–196. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castagnino, Tomás, Laura D’Amato, and Máximo Sangiácomo. 2013. How do Firms in Argentina Get Financing to Export? ECB Working Paper No 1601.

  • Chava, Sudheer, and Amiyatosh Purnanandam. 2011. The Effect of Banking Crisis on Bank-Dependent Borrowers. Journal of Financial Economics 96: 116–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chodorow-Reich, Gabriel. 2013. The Employment Effects of Credit Market Disruptions: Firm-Level Evidence from the 2008–9 Financial Crisis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(1): 1–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duqi, Andi, Angelo Tomaselli, and Giuseppe Torluccio. 2017. Is Relationship Lending Still a Mixed Blessing? A Review of Advantages and Disadvantages for Lenders and Borrowers. Journal of Economic Surveys 32(5): 1446–1482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duygan-Bump, Burcu, Alexey Levkov, and Judit Montoriol-Garriga. 2014. Financing Constraints and Unemployment: Evidence from the Great Recession. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 92.

  • Escudé, Guillermo, Tamara Burdisso, Marcelo Catena, Laura D’Amato, George McCandless, and Tomás Murphy. 2001. Las MIPyMES y el mercado de crédito en la Argentina. Documentos de Trabajo Banco Central de la República Argentina 15.

  • Fernandez, Roque Benjamin, Celeste González, Sergio Pernice, and Jorge M. Streb. 2007. Loan and bond finance in Argentina, 1985–2005. New York City, NY: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gan, Jie. 2007. The Real Effects of Asset Market Bubbles: Loan and Firm-Level Evidence of a Lending Channel. The Review of Financial Studies 20(6): 1941–1973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli, Nicola, Alberto Martin, and Stefano Rossi. 2018. Banks, Government Bonds, and Default: What do the Data Say? Journal of Monetary Economics 98: 98–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gopinath, Gita, and Brent Neiman. 2014. Trade Adjustment and Productivity in Large Crises. American Economic Review 104(3): 793–831.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone, Michael, Alexandre Mas, and Hoai-Luu Nguyen. 2014. Do Credit Market Shocks Affect the Real Economy? Quasi-Experimental Evidence from the Great Recession and ‘Normal’ Economic Times. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Guidotti, Pablo and Juan Pablo Nicolini. 2016. The Argentine Banking Crises of 1995 and 2001: An Exploration into the Role of Macro-prudential Regulations. Technical report, Mimeo Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. May.

  • Haltiwanger, John, Ron S. Jarmin, and Javier Miranda. 2013. Who Creates Jobs? Small Versus Large Versus Young. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2): 347–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, Ricardo and Andrés Velasco. 2002. Hard Money’s Soft Underbelly: Understanding the Argentine Crisis. In Brookings Trade Forum, vol. 2002, 59–104. Brookings Institution Press.

  • Hébert, Benjamin, and Jesse Schreger. 2017. The Costs of Sovereign Default: Evidence from Argentina. American Economic Review 107(10): 3119–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard, Robert, Kenneth Kuttner, and Darius Palia. 2002. Are There Bank Effects in Borrowers’ Costs of Funds? Evidence from a Matched Sample of Borrowers and Banks. The Journal of Business 75(4): 559–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ioannidou, Vasso, and Steven Ongena. 2010. “Time for a Change”: Loan Conditions and Bank Behavior When Firms Switch Banks. Journal of Finance 65(5): 1847–1877.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiménez, Gabriel, Atif Mian, José-Luis Peydró, and Jesús Saurina. 2014. The Real Effects of the Bank Lending Channel. Working Paper Banco de España.

  • Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem, Herman Kamil, and Carolina Villegas-Sanchez. 2016. What Hinders Investment in the Aftermath of Financial Crises: Insolvent Firms or Illiquid Banks? Review of Economics and Statistics 98(4): 756–769.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khwaja, Asim Ijaz, and Atif Mian. 2008. Tracing the Impact of Bank Liquidity Shocks: Evidence from an Emerging Market. American Economic Review 98(4): 1413–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, Michael W., Joe Peek, and Eric S. Rosengren. 2002. Troubled Banks, Impaired Foreign Direct Investment: The Role of Relative Access to Credit. American Economic Review 92(3): 664–682.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porta, La, Florencio Lopez-deSilanes Rafael, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. Government Ownership of Banks. The Journal of Finance 57(1): 265–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manova, Kalina. 2012. Credit Constraints, Heterogeneous Firms, and International Trade. Review of Economic Studies 80(2): 711–744.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza, Enrique G., and Vivian Z. Yue. 2012. A General Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and Business Cycles. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(2): 889–946.

    Google Scholar 

  • Micco, Alejandro, and Ugo Panizza. 2006. Bank Ownership and Lending Behavior. Economics Letters 93(2): 248–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montoriol-Garriga, Judit, and Christina Wang. 2012. Rationing of Bank Credit to Small Businesses: Evidence from the Great Recession. Technical report, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.

  • Olivero, María Pía and Ryan Yuan. 2011. Switching Costs for Bank-Dependent Borrowers and the Bank Lending Channel of Monetary Policy. Working paper Drexel University. Retrieved December 2018, from http://www.mariapia-olivero.com.

  • Ongena, Steven, and David C. Smith. 2001. The Duration of Bank Relationships. Journal of Financial Economics 61(3): 449–475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paravisini, Daniel. 2008. Local Bank Financial Constraints and Firm Access to External Finance. The Journal of Finance 63(5): 2161–2193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paravisini, Daniel, Veronica Rappoport, Philipp Schnabl, and Daniel Wolfenzon. 2014. Dissecting the Effect of Credit Supply on Trade: Evidence from Matched Credit-Export Data. The Review of Economic Studies 82(1): 333–359.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popov, Alexander, and Neeltje Van Horen. 2014. Exporting Sovereign Stress: Evidence from Syndicated Bank Lending During the Euro Area Sovereign Debt Crisis. Review of Finance 19(5): 1825–1866.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, Raghuram G. 1992. Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice Between Informed and Arms’-Length Debt. Journal of Finance 47: 1367–1400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, Raghuram G. 1994. Why Bank Credit Policies Fluctuate: A Theory and Some Evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2): 399–441.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rojas, Eugenio. 2018. Firm Heterogeneity & the Transmission of Financial Shocks During the European Debt Crisis. Working paper University of Florida. Retrieved March 2020, from https://sites.google.com/site/erojasba1/research-working-papers.

  • Sharpe, Steven A. 1990. Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending, and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized Model of Customer Relationships. The Journal of Finance 45(4): 1069–1087.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Thadden, Ernst-Ludwig. 2004. Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending, and Implicit Contracts: The Winner’s Curse. Finance Research Letters 1: 11–23.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pablo D’Erasmo.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve System or the Central Bank of Argentina. For very helpful comments we thank the editorial committee of the IMF-CBC-IMFER Conference on Current Policy Challenges Facing Emerging Markets, two anonymous referees, Carlos Urrutia, and conference participants at the 2019 Society of Economic Dynamics Meetings, 2018 Spring Midwest Macroeconomics Meetings, the CORE 2018 meetings in Córdoba, Argentina, Swarthmore College, and the 2018 Meetings of the LACEA in Quito, Ecuador. We thank Laura D’Amato for valuable help with this project.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Theoretical Model

In this section we present a model characterized by search and matching frictions in which firms (borrowers) have established long-term relationships with their lenders. Using our model, we derive testable implications that shed light on how the state of the banking network affects credit supply and real activity and we use these implications as a guide to design the empirical specification of the next sections.

1.1 Appendix 1.1: Environment

Banks and firms are assumed to be distributed on islands. There are a total of \((I+1)\) islands: a total of I peripheral island and a central one. Islands are labeled from 0 to I, where the island labeled 0 is the central island. There are a total of B banks per island (including the central island) and F firms on islands 1 through I (note that there are no firms on the central island). The relationships between firms and banks in the peripheral islands are interpreted as existing relationships that do not require costly setup costs. The central island is meant to represent a market where new firm-bank relationships are established after incurring in a cost.

Each period, a fraction \(\alpha _i\) of all firms on the ith island receive an investment opportunity. Investment opportunities, or projects, need to be financed by banks in order to produce. Each financed project produces y units of output that is split between the firm and the bank financing the project. Per project, the firm receives \((y-r_i)\), and the bank receives \(r_i\), where \(r_i\) can be interpreted as the interest rate on the \(i_{th}\) island. Firms remain in the market for only one period.

Each bank on the ith island receives \(v_i\) units of available credit to be offered in the ith market. Once banks and firms meet, they split the surplus of the match after bargaining, with the bank’s bargaining power given by \(\phi\).

Banks and firms find each other using a constant-returns-to-scale matching function:

$$\begin{aligned} M = m \left( F \alpha _i \right) ^{\gamma } \left( B \nu _i \right) ^{1-\gamma }. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Given this matching technology, market tightness is indicated by \(\theta _i=\frac{Bv_i}{F\alpha _i}\). The probability of an investment opportunity to be financed is then given by \(q(\theta _i) = \frac{M}{F \alpha _i} = m \left( \frac{Bv_i}{F\alpha _i} \right) ^{1-\gamma }\), and the probability of a unit of available bank credit being matched to a firm is \(p(\theta _i) = \frac{M}{B v_i}\). While firms can transfer investment projects from their ith island to the central island by paying a switching cost z, unmatched credit vacancies cannot be moved.

Total output is then measured by the total number of projects successfully financed \(q(\theta _i) F \alpha _i\).

The timing is as follows: First, the vectors \(\alpha\) and v containing the information on \(\alpha _i\) and \(v_i\) for all islands are observed, and peripheral island markets open for all islands 1 through I. Then, the central market opens and firms can decide to take their unmatched projects to the central island by paying the cost z.

1.2 Appendix 1.2: Equilibrium

On the central island, matched firms and banks bargain over the match surplus without any outside option:

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{r_0} (y-r_0)^{1-\phi } r_0^{\phi } \\&\quad r_0 = \phi y \end{aligned}$$

This determines the interest rate on the central island, which is given by \(r_0 = \phi y\). The equilibrium on the central island affects the outside option for firms in the peripheral islands and the matching surplus to be split between banks and firms in the peripheral islands.

The outside option of a firm on the peripheral island is given by

$$\begin{aligned} U_i=\max (0,q(\theta _0)(1-\phi )y-z). \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Notice that \(U_i\) is independent of island i conditions, so it can be labeled as U. The matching surplus in the ith island is then:

$$\begin{aligned} S=y-U. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

This is so because banks in the peripheral islands cannot transfer their credit vacancies to the central island. This fact determines that their outside option is effectively zero. Again, the surplus of a match on the peripheral island is not affected by the island conditions; therefore we label it as S.

The banks in the peripheral islands receive \(\phi S\), which is constant across all peripheral islands. This is because, independent of the island’s conditions, they all share the same outside option for firms given by the transition to the central island U.

In particular, banks in all peripheral islands receive

$$\begin{aligned} r_i=\phi (y-\max (0,q(\theta _0)(1-\phi )y-z)). \end{aligned}$$
(8)

After the first sub-period finishes, there are a fraction \((1-q(\theta _i))\) of projects that could not find a bank on the ith island. Then, the firm must decide to pay the transition cost to the central island or scrap the project. At this point, the firm will transition to the central island market as long as \(z<q(\theta _0)(y(1-\phi ))\), where \(\theta _0\) is the market tightness on the central island and determines the probability of successfully finding financing for the project.

This condition determines a threshold \(\hat{\theta _0}=q^{-1}(z/(y(1-\phi )))=\frac{z}{\left[ m y(1-\phi )\right] }^{\frac{1}{1-\gamma }}\), above which all firms with unmatched projects at the peripheral island will transition to the central island. Intuitively, since the probability of finding a match is increasing in \(\theta\), firms will pay the fixed cost only if, given the supply of credit in the central island, the demand for credit is such that the expected return (net of cost) is non-negative. If \(\theta _0=\hat{\theta }_0\), then firms with unmatched projects are indifferent between transitioning to the central island and scrapping the project.

Let \(\underline{\theta }_0=\frac{Bv_0}{F\sum _{i=1}^I\alpha _i(1-q(\theta _i))}\) denote the market tightness that would result if all unmatched firms transition to the central island (for a given \(v_0\), \(\{\alpha _i,v_i\}_{i=1}^{I}\)). If \(\underline{\theta }_0\ge \hat{\theta _0}\), all unmatched projects will in fact transition to the central island, and the central island market tightness equals

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _0=\underline{\theta }_0. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

If \(\underline{\theta }_0<\hat{\theta }_0\), in equilibrium, not all unmatched firms will transition to the central island. Firms will transition until the equilibrium market tightness \(\theta _0=\hat{\theta }_0\). Since \(\underline{\theta }_0<\hat{\theta }_0\), it is possible to find the fraction of unmatched firms that will transition to the central island consistent with \(\theta _0=\hat{\theta }_0\) by defining \(\tau \in [0,1]\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{\tau }\underline{\theta }_0=\hat{\theta }_0 \Leftrightarrow \tau = \frac{\underline{\theta }_0}{\hat{\theta }_0}. \end{aligned}$$

When \(\theta _0=\hat{\theta _0}\) firms are indifferent between transitioning or not, so we assume that unmatched firms use a mixed strategy and transition to the central island with probability \(\tau\).

1.3 Appendix 1.3: Shocks to Banks Exposed to Government Debt/Devaluation

It is assumed that in good times the vectors v and \(\alpha\) are constant for all islands, generating a constant probability of financing for all projects across islands given by

$$\begin{aligned} q(\theta _i)+(1-q(\theta _i))\tau q(\theta _0)=q(Bv/F\alpha )+(1-q(Bv/F\alpha ))\tau q(\theta _0). \end{aligned}$$
(10)

In bad times, heterogeneous banks are subject to idiosyncratic shocks. A subset of islands receives loan vacancies that are lower than in good times. This lowers the probability of financing for all projects in all islands but in a heterogeneous way. This captures the idea that some banks are hit harder than others in some circumstances. In our case, it is banks that were exposed to government debt that cannot offer credit after the government defaults. The credit-availability shock represented by \(v_i\) is meant to represent the supply of credit from banks after their asset position is affected by movements in the price of some of its components. In particular, if a bank holds government bonds that depreciate due to a default, it will have less available credit to offer to firms as a result.

For the islands where the stock of loan vacancies fell, there is a direct effect on the probability of financing \(q(\theta _i)\) on their own island. The lower probability of financing on the peripheral island is not counteracted by the financing probability at the central island (which depends also on the probability of not finding financing on the peripheral island), because the term \((1-q(\theta _i))\) is multiplied by a number that is less than one given by \(\tau q(\theta _0)\).

The phenomenon in the affected peripheral islands triggers a secondary effect on the central island that affects all projects in all islands. This additional flow of unmatched projects from the islands shocked with lower availability of credit causes \(\theta _0\) or \(\tau\) or both to fall, lowering the financing probability for all projects on the central island and lowering output.

1.4 Appendix 1.4: Testable Implications

Given the workings of the model and the availability of data, we can look at the following testable implications:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial q(\theta _i)}{\partial v_i}\ge 0 \end{aligned}$$
(11)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tau q(\theta _0)}{\partial v_i}\le 0. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

Equation (11) implies that the probability of finding financing from the perspective of the firm is increasing in the availability of funds \(\nu _i\) for banks on the peripheral island (or initial island). In terms of empirical implementation, it would mean that after the devaluation, exporters whose long-term relationships with the banking system did not suffer as much after the sovereign default, should see their credit increase faster than their counterparts with relationships with banks where the availability of credit suffered as a result of the default.

Moreover, Eq. (12) states that new relationships on the central island and the availability of credit in the peripheral one should be negatively related to each other. That is, conditional on the availability of credit in the initial relationships, new relationships should start more often for those firms whose initial long-term bank relationships suffer the most with the default.

Appendix 2: Data Appendix

We use data from the Central Bank of Argentina’s credit registry (called Central de Deudores). Our original sample expands from June 1999 to December 2005. While we use firm and bank-level information prior to the default and the devaluation, we focus the analysis on how credit and other variables evolved from June 2002 to December 2005. This sample contains 202,438 firms and 344,105 bank relationships (or loans). To construct our firm level sample, we apply the following filters

  1. 1.

    For each firm and period, we aggregate the loans (in real terms) with all banks. Call this variable “total debt.” For each firm, we compute the maximum value (over the time series) of total debt. To remove outliers we eliminate firms in the bottom 5% (very small firms) and top 2% of the distribution of maximum total debt.

  2. 2.

    We eliminate firms that report 12 or fewer observations.

  3. 3.

    We exclude government sector firms. We also exclude firms in the financial sector.

  4. 4.

    We eliminate lending relationship observations that are in the top or bottom 5% of the distribution of (quarterly) loan growth.

  5. 5.

    We eliminate lending relationships with less than 4 observations.

We are left with 97,279 firms and 159,312 lending relationships. Of these, there 33,333 firms with more than one lending relationship.Footnote 38

Table 10 provides summary statistics at the firm level.

Table 10 Summary statistics (firm level)

Table 11 shows the distribution of banking relationships for the firms in our sample (pre- and post-default/devaluation) as the fraction of firms and as the fraction of total loans.

Table 11 Distribution of banking relationships

Table 12 shows the distribution of the age of banking relationships for the firms in our sample (years 2003–2005). Relationships in the 21–25 months (year 2001), 46–50 months (year 2003), 61–65 months (year 2004) and 71–75 months (year 2005) bins correspond to firms with relationships that started at the beginning of our sample and operated continuously. Firms in the 1–5 months and 6–10 months bins are firms with banking relationships that started during the corresponding calendar year (there are some firms with new banking relationships in the 11–15 months bin). In the year 2004, we observe a large increase in the lower end of the age distribution and a significant decline in the fraction of relationships at the top end of the distribution.

Table 12 Distribution of age of banking relationships

Table 13 shows the sectoral allocation of credit by the banking sector in Argentina.

Table 13 Allocation of bank credit by sector

Appendix 3: Bank-Level Regressions: Robustness Checks

We use the following specification to study the correlation between the change in loans to the private non-financial sector (\(\ell _{it}\)) between period t and period \(t-1\) for bank i (measured as a 3-month change) and a measure of exposure to government debt in 2001 prior to default (\(\mathrm{E}_{i2001}\)) and a measure of exposure to the devaluation via non-deposit foreign currency liabilities (\(\mathrm{FC}_{i2001}\)). We also include a set of bank-level controls (\(X_{it}\)) and month fixed effects (\(\alpha _t\)):

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \ell _{it} = \alpha _t + \beta _1 \mathrm{E}_{i2001} + \beta _2 \mathrm{FC}_{i2001} + \beta _3 X_{it-1} + u_{it}. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

The controls at the bank level are intended to account for other variables that can impact the banks’ availability of loanable funds. As such the vector \(X_{it-1}\) includes liquidity, leverage, the level of loans to the private non-financial sector, and profitability as measured by banks’ net income (Tables 14, 15).

Table 14 Bank-level effects of sovereign debt exposure
Table 15 Bank-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure

Appendix 4: Relationship-Level Regressions: Robustness Checks

This section presents results from additional relationship-level regressions that we run following the specification in Eq. (3). The model of changes in credit from bank i to firm j in period t that we estimate is

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \ell _{ijt} = \rho _{jt} + \beta _1 \mathrm{E}_{i2001} + \beta _2 \mathrm{FC}_{i2001} + \beta _3 R_{ijt-1} + \beta _4 X_{it-1} + e_{ijt}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\rho _jt\) are firm-time fixed effects, \(\mathrm{E}_{i2001}\) and \(\mathrm{FC}_{i2001}\) are defined as before and capture bank j exposure to the sovereign default and devaluation in 2001, \(R_{ijt-1}\) are controls that capture the characteristic of the relationship between bank i and firm j (e.g., age of the relationship, concentration) and \(X_{it-1}\) are standard bank-level characteristics such as bank size (measured by assets), liquidity, leverage, and profitability (Tables 16, 17).

Table 16 Relationship-level effects of sovereign debt exposure
Table 17 Relationship-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure

Appendix 5: Firm-Level Regressions: Robustness Checks

This section presents results from additional firm-level regressions where we add firm characteristics as additional controls (Table 18) or we condition by the exporter status of the borrower (Tables 1920212223).

Table 18 Firm-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure
Table 19 Firm-Level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure (by export status)
Table 20 Firm-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure (by export status), on impact in 2003
Table 21 Firm-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure on probability of new relationships
Table 22 Firm-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure on extensive margin of exports
Table 23 Firm-level effects of sovereign debt and foreign currency exposure on borrowers default

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

D’Erasmo, P., Moscoso Boedo, H., Olivero, M.P. et al. Relationship Networks in Banking Around a Sovereign Default and Currency Crisis. IMF Econ Rev 68, 584–642 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-020-00114-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-020-00114-4

JEL Classifications

Navigation