Skip to main content
Log in

Parliamentary and semi-presidential advantages in the sovereign credit market: democratic institutional design and sovereign credibility

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We propose that institutional differences in executive-legislative relations generate heterogeneity in the creditworthiness of democracies in the sovereign credit market. In particular, there is a credibility advantage for parliamentarism relative to presidentialism, because the former, with stronger parties, elongates policy-makers’ time horizons and lowers their discount rate, thereby enhancing their ability to signal the credibility of their commitment to debt repayment. Our Heckman selection analysis of democracies from 1990 to 2012 confirms the existence of parliamentary advantage in sovereign credibility, and it also reveals a semi-presidential advantage relative to presidentialism. Our study contributes to the recent stream of research that problematizes the democracy/autocracy dichotomy in the study of sovereign credibility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Reneging can take the form of not just outright default but also policy actions intended to undermine the value of the sovereign’s debt security like loan conversion plans and inflationary monetary and fiscal policies (DiGiuseppe and Shea 2015: 561).

  2. Note that sovereigns do not have to be in power to be able to extract payoffs. They can still extract payoffs in their post-tenure if their allies or affiliated parties are in power (Wright 2008).

  3. This idea is first hinted in North and Weingast’s seminal work (1989: 807) where they note that more short-sighted sovereigns can be expected to discount the reputation cost of defaults more heavily. Surprisingly, subsequent studies did not expand on this idea.

  4. This is the case even for bills without a confidence motion explicitly attached (Huber 1996: 270).

  5. One can argue that the ever-existing possibility of government dissolution and early election under parliamentarism can also limit policy makers’ time horizons by generating continuous electoral pressures. For the sake of simplicity, we would like to acknowledge this point here but not include it in our main theoretical argument. However, our empirical analysis will later help to reveal whether this opposition is strong enough to offset the elongating effect of parliamentary democracy on policy makers’ time preferences.

  6. Shugart and Carey (1992) deviate from this common practice in that they distinguish two “non-pure” regime types: premier-presidential and president-parliamentary. For now, we follow the common practice and only include one hybrid type. However, we will later conduct an additional analysis with Shugart and Carey’s sub-types.

  7. Aside from making our analysis more rigorous, these variables also help in identifying our causal mechanism. We assume that the democracy types influence sovereign credibility by signaling the sovereign’s time preference. However, institutions can influence the dependent variable with their general economic impacts as well (Gerring et al. 2009). Therefore, these controls help to increase our confidence that the impact captured by the regime type variables in our model’s estimation is due to our causal mechanism.

  8. This variable is one-year lagged, because scholars find that counties with higher access to sovereign credit might be more willing to engage in aggressive behaviors due to their greater financing abilities (Shea 2014).

  9. Furthermore, all of our empirical models include regional dummies as there might be some level of commonality within the specific regions of the world in terms of democratic experience and exposure to and relations with sovereign credit markets.

  10. In their application of the Heckman model, Beaulieu et al. (2012) use decades-fixed effects and exports to the U.S. as instrument variables. We ended up not using decades-fixed effects and exports to the U.S., because decades do not seem be significantly correlated with the dependent variable of the selection model (the presence or absence in the credit market), and exports to the U.S. are significantly correlated with the dependent variables of both the first-stage and second-stage models.

  11. It is a common practice in related literature to include the lagged value of the interest rate spread (Breen and McMenamin 2013; Beaulieu et al. 2012). The premise is that creditors remember a country’s creditworthiness in the past, implying that a country’s credit risk in the past matters to creditors’ assessments of the country’s credit risk today. Following a reviewer’s recommendation, though, when we exclude the lagged values, the results, available upon request, are even stronger.

References

  • Archer, C. C., Biglaiser, G., & DeRouen, K. (2007). Sovereign bonds and the “democratic advantage”: Does regime type affect credit rating agency ratings in the developing world? International Organization, 61(2), 341–365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R., & Keohane, R. O. (1985). Achieving cooperation under anarchy: Strategies and institutions. World Politics, 38(1), 226–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (1998). Comparative dynamics of parliamentary government. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 593–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu, E., Cox, G. W., & Saiegh, S. (2012). Sovereign debt and regime type: Reconsidering the “democratic advantage”. International Organization, 66(4), 709–738.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. (1996). Nuisance vs. substance: Specifying and estimating time-series-cross-section models. Political Analysis, 6(1), 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biglaiser, G., & Staats, J. L. (2012). Finding the “democratic advantage” in sovereign bond ratings: The importance of strong courts, property rights protection, and the rule of law. International Organization, 66(3), 515–535.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bizzarro, F., Gerring, J., Hicken, A., Knutsen, C. H., Bernhard, M., Skaaning, S. E., et al. (2015). Party strength and economic growth. The Varieties of Democracy Institute University of Gothenburg, Working paper series 2015:10.

  • Block, S. A., & Vaaler, P. M. (2004). The price of democracy: Sovereign risk ratings, bond spreads and political business cycles in developing countries. Journal of Money Finance, 23(6), 917–946.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., & Svolik, M. V. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics, 75(2), 300–316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, J. R., & Fleisher, R. (1990). The president in the legislative arena. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breen, M., & McMenamin, I. (2013). Political institutions, credible commitment, and sovereign debt in advanced economies. International Studies Quarterly, 57(4), 842–854.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A. (2007). Presidentialism, parliamentarism, and democracy. Cambridge, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2002). Democratic institutions and regime survival: Parliamentary and presidential democracies reconsidered. Annual Review of Political Science, 5, 151–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G., & McCubbins, M. D. (1993). Legislative Leviathan. Berkley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diermeier, D., & Feddersen, T. J. (1998). Cohesion in legislatures and the vote of confidence procedure. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 611–622.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiGiuseppe, M., & Shea, P. E. (2015). Sovereign credit and the fate of leaders: Reassessing the “democratic advantage”. International Studies Quarterly, 59(3), 557–570.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D. (1994). Domestic political audiences and the escalation of international disputes. American Political Science Review, 88(3), 577–592.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2007). Authoritarian institutions and the survival of autocrats. Comparative Political Studies, 40(11), 1279–1301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gartzke, E., & Gleditsch, K. S. (2004). Why democracies may actually be less reliable allies. American Journal of Political Science, 48(4), 775–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geddes, B. (1999). What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 115–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerring, J., Thacker, S. C., & Moreno, C. (2009). Are parliamentary systems better? Comparative Political Studies, 42(3), 327–359.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (1997). Econometric analysis. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hankla, C. R. (2006). Party strength and international trade: A cross-national analysis. Comparative Political Studies, 39(9), 1133–1156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. D. (1996). The vote of confidence in parliamentary democracies. American Political Science Review, 90(2), 269–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. (2007). Governance and economic growth in China and India. In L. Alan Winters & S. Yusuf (Eds.), Dancing with giants (pp. 211–242). Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P., & Khemani, S. (2009). When do legislators pass on pork? The role of political parties in determining legislator effort. American Political Science Review, 103(1), 99–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohlscheen, E. (2010). Sovereign risk: Constitutions rule. Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 62–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeds, B. A. (1999). Domestic political institutions, credible commitments, and international cooperation. American Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 979–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linz, J. J. (1990). The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy, 1(1), 51–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linz, J. J., & Valenzuela, A. (Eds.). (1994). The failure of presidential democracy: The case of Latin America. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magaloni, B. (2006). Voting for autocracy: Hegemonic party survival and its demise in Mexico. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, S., & Shugart, M. S. (Eds.). (1997). Presidentialism in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M., Gurr, T. R., & Jaggers, K. (2017). Polity IV project: Dataset users’ manual. Center for Systemic Peace www.systemicpeace.org.

  • Mezey, M. L. (1979). Comparative Legislatures. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosley, L. (2003). Global capital and national governments. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owens, J. E. (2003). Explaining party cohesion and discipline in democratic legislatures: Purposiveness and contexts. Journal of Legislative Studies, 9(4), 12–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmer, G., D’Orazio, V., Kenwick, M., & Lane, M. (2015). The MID4 data set: Procedures, coding rules, and description. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 32(2), 222–242.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Comparative politics and public finance. Journal of Political Economy, 108(6), 1121–1161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinto, A. R. (2006). Control and responsibility of credit rating agencies in the United States. The American Journal of Comparative Law, 54, 341–356.

    Google Scholar 

  • Primo, D. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2010). Party strength, the personal vote, and government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 54(2), 354–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saiegh, S. M. (2009). Coalition governments and sovereign debt crises. Economics and Politics, 21(2), 232–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuels, D. J. (2002). Presidentialized parties. The separation of powers and party organization and behavior. Comparative Political Studies, 35(4), 461–483.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, K., & Weingast, B. (2003). The “democratic advantage”: Institutional foundations of financial power in international competition. International Organization, 57(4), 3–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shea, P. (2014). Financing victory: Credit, democracy, and war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 58(5), 771–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. S. (1998). The inverse relationship between party strength and executive strength: A theory of politicians’ constitutional choices. British Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. S., & Carey, J. M. (1992). Presidents and assemblies: Constitutional design and electoral dynamics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaaler, P. M., Schrage, B. N., & Block, S. A. (2005). Counting the investor vote: Political business cycle effects on sovereign bond spreads in developing countries. Journal of International Business Studies, 36(1), 62–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Rijckeghem, C., & Weder, B. (2009). Political institutions and debt crises. Public Choice, 138, 387–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, J. (2008). To invest or insure? How authoritarian time horizons impact foreign aid effectiveness. Comparative Political Studies, 41(7), 971–1000.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Isa Camyar.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 4.

Table 4 Sample

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Camyar, I. Parliamentary and semi-presidential advantages in the sovereign credit market: democratic institutional design and sovereign credibility. Const Polit Econ 30, 383–406 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09288-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09288-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation