Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Criminal Politicians and Socioeconomic Development: Evidence from Rural India

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although it seems intuitively clear that candidate quality provides a critical pillar of democratic governance, the consequences of electing low-quality politicians remain unclear. Combining census data and election results, we conduct a regression discontinuity analysis to examine the socioeconomic effects of criminal politicians in India. We find that the election of state legislators with criminal charges can exacerbate household poverty in a village as household electrification and literacy rates both decrease when criminal candidates win close elections against non-criminal ones. In contrast, the presence of criminal politicians does not have a conclusive negative effect on the supply of local infrastructures, such as paved roads and power grids. These results highlight the importance of differentiating between different types of policy outcomes. Rent-seeking politicians will engage in local infrastructural projects, but they may pay little attention to these projects’ contribution to poverty reduction.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Following Besley (2005), we distinguish between honesty/integrity and competence as the two principal dimensions of candidate quality.

  2. Most existing studies focus on India, but few have analyzed criminal politicians in Italy (Mastrorocco and Di Cataldo 2016), the United Kingdom (Larcinese and Sircar 2013), and the Philippines (Magno 2010).

  3. See Section 5 to see the definitions of close elections.

  4. See Section 4 for more discussion on the definition of serious crimes.

  5. With a focus on India, Lee (2018) shows that the electoral victory of women politicians will lead to the provision of high-quality latrines.

  6. Gehring, Kauffeldt, and Vadlamannati (2016) also seek to estimate the effect of electing criminal politicians into office on their legislative effort and the use of local development funds, but they focus on criminal politicians in Lok Sabha, the national parliament, instead of state assemblies.

  7. In the Indian context, a robust democratic constitution and a series of anti-corruption laws imply that the legal system and regulations governing political activity are themselves of relatively high quality. The problem is that many politicians circumvent the rules and engage in illegal activities, and the criminal character of a politician is thus a good indicator of these inherent character traits. In contrast, in a country with biased laws on paper, willingness to break the law might not say anything about self-interest or a lack of respect for the rule of law.

  8. Researchers have also noticed that some MLAs do not spend their allotted funds in constituencies. As Keefer and Khemani (2009) highlight, an MLA’s effort of delivering pork will be lower in constituencies when these constituencies are their party’s stronghold, perhaps because politicians would like to focus their resources on swing voters. We include fixed effects in our analysis to account for this caveat.

  9. A positive scale effect does not mean that criminal politicians do not have an overall adverse effect. A positive local scale effect could come at the expense of areas governed by non-criminal politicians in a zero-sum game of resource allocation.

  10. Here, of course, we must remember that such an increase in the number of projects does imply inefficient resource use and possibly the implementation of fewer projects in other areas of the country.

  11. “Lawless Legislators Thwart Social Progress in India,” May 4, 2007, Wall Street Journal, available at http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB117823755304891604(accessed August 17, 2016).

  12. The same concern also applies to the self-reported educational qualifications. See, for example, “5 Indian Politicians Shrouded in Fake Degree Scandals,” New Indian Express, June 9, 2015.

  13. The ADR defines a serious criminal politician as a politician who has been charged with offenses that lead to five years or more in jail, offenses that are non-bailable, offenses that cause loss to exchequer, offenses related to electoral fraud, assault, murder, kidnap, or rape, and offenses included in the Representation of the People Act (Section 8) and the Prevention of Corruption Act. Serious criminal politicians also include those who have been charged with any crimes particularly against women.

  14. Vaishnav (2017) follows a similar approach. Unfortunately, we cannot use data on actual convictions as opposed to pending charges. Criminal convictions against incumbent politicians are very rare in India and the legal process very time-consuming.

  15. To clarify, here we only present five states where criminal politicians are most common, but the following analysis includes villages from the entire country.

  16. Note the change of constituency boundaries in India after the March 2008 elections in Meghalaya. Using both administrative records and GIS maps of Indian boundaries, we have assigned every village in the country separately for pre-2008 and post-2008 constituency.

  17. See Table A1 for the composition of our samples, both at the village and at the constituency level.

  18. Alternatively, we address the concern of duplicated villages, which would otherwise result in the over-representation of some villages in the sample, by providing the results with a single round of elections. The results in Section A14 are very similar to our main findings.

  19. Given our focus on the local RDD, we do not include higher-order polynomials, as they may produce biased coefficients (Gelman and Imbens 2014). We estimate, instead, models that begin with the treatment variable alone, then add election year and state fixed effects, then add a linear local polynomial, and final include pre-treatment control variables. This approach ensures robustness and avoids noisy, potentially biased estimates based on complex functional form.

  20. The 2011 Census recorded a household lacking assets if it owned none of the following items: radio, television, computer (or laptop) with Internet connection, landline telephone, mobile phone, bicycle, scooter, or car.

  21. See http://www.myneta.info/ for more details.

  22. In Section A6 (Supporting Information), we find the Imbens and Kalyanaraman (2012) optimal bandwidths and show that they are generally very close to 5%, thus validating our a priori decisions. We also apply different methods to see if our results vary by different optimal bandwidths (Hyytinen et al. 2018; Calonico et al. 2019); the results are very similar.

  23. All table, figure, and section labels beginning with “A” are in Supporting Information.

  24. Figure A6 shows that the effect on power supply of the serious criminal candidates is positive and sometimes statistically significant when we focus on the sample with the margin of victory smaller than 1%. This finding is still consistent with our proposed theory—that is, criminal politicians may have the incentive to provide local public infrastructure in pursuit of rents.

  25. In Table A71, in the sample with the margin of victory smaller than 5%, we find that the interaction of “S criminal” with “alignment” is positive and statistically significant. This finding suggests that serious criminals are more likely to secure a village’s power supply when they are aligned with their respective chief ministers. However, in the same sample, which includes 18,981 observations with a serious criminal politician winning a close election, only 5,726 were aligned with their respective chief ministers.

  26. The inspection includes items such as quality control arrangements, earthworks, side drains, road markings, surfacing, and pavement conditions.

  27. See Section A10.

  28. Table A18 (Supporting Information) shows the results based on serious criminal politicians.

  29. Section A11 shows suggestive evidence for criminal candidates’ election contributing to more road agreements and higher rates of non-completion, but the estimates are mostly statistically insignificant.

  30. The IHDS Project selected nationally representative samples in both rounds. See ihds.info.

References

  • Aidt T, Golden MA, Tiwari D. Criminal Candidate Selection for the Indian National Legislature. Working Paper: UCLA; 2015.

  • Alt J, de Mesquita EB, Rose S. Disentangling accountability and competence in elections: evidence from US term limits. J Polit. 2011;73(1):171–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asher S, Novosad P. Politics and local economic growth: evidence from India. Am Econ J Appl Econ. 2017;9(1):229–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltrunaite A, Bello P, Casarico A, Profeta P. Gender quotas and the quality of politicians. J Public Econ. 2014;118:62–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Green DP, McManus J, Pande R. Are poor voters indifferent to whether elected leaders are criminal or corrupt? A vignette experiment in rural India. Polit Commun. 2014;31(3):391–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan P. Corruption and development: a review of issues. J Econ Lit. 1997;35(3):1320–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan P, Mookherjee D. Decentralisation and accountability in Infrastructure delivery in developing countries. Econ J. 2006a;116(508):101–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan P, Mookherjee D. Pro-poor targeting and accountability of local governments in West Bengal. J Dev Econ. 2006b;79(2):303–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ. The control of politicians: an economic model. Public Choice. 1973;14(1):19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T. Political selection. J Econ Perspect. 2005;19(3):43–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Burgess R. The political economy of government responsiveness: theory and evidence from India. Q J Econ. 2002;117(4):1415–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Montalvo JG, Reynal-Querol M. Do educated leaders matter? Econ J. 2011;121(554):F205–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohlken AT. Development or rent-seeking? How political influence shapes infrastructure provision in India. Br J Polit Sci 2019;online first.

  • Bose S. Transforming India: challenges to the world’s largest democracy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brollo F, Nannicini T, Perotti R, Tabellini G. The political resource curse. Am Econ Rev. 2013;103(5):1759–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calonico S, Cattaneo MD, Farrell MH, Titiunik R. Regression discontinuity designs using covariates. Rev Econ Stat. 2019;101(3):442–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carnes N, Lupu N. What good is a college degree? Education and leader quality reconsidered. J Polit. 2016;78(1):35–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli F, Morelli M. Bad politicians. J Public Econ. 2004;88(3–4):759–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caughey D, Sekhon JS. Elections and the regression discontinuity design: lessons from close US house races, 1942-2008. Polit Anal. 2011;19(4):385–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chemin M. Welfare effects of criminal politicians: a discontinuity-based approach. Journal of Law Economics, and Organization. 2012;55(3):667–690.

  • Dŕeze J, Sen AK. India: development and participation. 2nd ed. New York: Oxford University Press; 2002.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn JA. Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice. 1986;50(1):5–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman R, Schulz F, Vig V. The private returns to public office. J Polit Econ. 2014;122(4):806–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehring K, Kauffeldt T, Vadlamannati KC. Crime, incentives and political effort: a model and empirical application for India. Working Paper; 2016.

  • Gelman A, Imbens G. Why high-order polynomials should not be used in regression discontinuity designs. NBER Working Paper 20405; 2014.

  • Hyytinen A, Merilainen J, Saarimaa T, Toivanen O, Tukiainen J. When does regression discontinuity design work? Evidence from random election outcomes. Econometrica. 2018;9(2):1019–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens G, Kalyanaraman K. Optimal bandwidth choice for the regression discontinuity estimator. Rev Econ Stud. 2012;79(3):933–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbens GW, Lemieux T. Regression discontinuity designs: a guide to practice. J Econ. 2008;142(2):615–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensenius FR. Development from representation? A study of quotas for scheduled castes in India. Am Econ J Appl Econ. 2015;7(3):196–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keefer P, Khemani S. When do legislators pass on ‘pork?’ The determinants of legislator utilization of a constituency development Fund in India. In: Policy research working paper 4929. World: Bank; 2009.

  • Keefer P, Knack S. Boondoggles, rent-seeking, and political checks and balances: public investment under unaccountable governments. Rev Econ Stat. 2007;89(3):566–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenny C. Construction, corruption, and developing countries. World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 4271; 2007.

  • Kramon E, Posner DN. Who benefits from distributive politics? How the outcome one studies affects the answer one gets. Perspectives on Politics. 2013;11(2):461–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larcinese V, Sircar I. Crime and punishment the British way: accountability channels following the MPs’ expenses scandal. EPSA 2013 Annual General Conference Paper 924; 2013.

  • Lee DS. Randomized experiments from non-random selection in US house elections. J Econ. 2008;142(2):675–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee YJJ. Gender, electoral competition, and sanitation in India. Comparative Politics. 2018;50(4):587–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehne J, Shapiro JN, Vanden Eynde O. Building connections: political corruption and road construction in India. Working Paper: Princeton University; 2016.

  • Lewis-Faupel S, Neggers Y, Olken BA, Pande R. Can electronic procurement improve infrastructure provision? Evidence from public works in India and Indonesia NBER Working Paper 20344; 2014.

  • Magno CN. Crime as political Capital in the Philippines. Doctoral Dissertation: Indiana University; 2010.

  • Malhotra P, Jain P. MLA-LADS: a look into the loopholes and corrections. Centre for Civil Society Working Paper 2225; 2009.

  • Maskin E, Tirole J. The politician and the judge: accountability in government. Am Econ Rev. 2004;94(4):1034–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mastrorocco N, Di Cataldo M. Organised crime within politics: evidence from Italy. Working Paper: London School of Economics; 2016.

  • Mauro P. Corruption and the composition of government expenditure. J Public Econ. 1998;69(2):263–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCrary J. Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: a density test. J Econ. 2008;142(2):698–714.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olken BA. Monitoring corruption: evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. J Polit Econ. 2007;115(2):200–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Roland G, Tabellini G. Separation of powers and political accountability. Q J Econ. 1997;112(4):1163–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piliavsky A, editor. Patronage as politics in South Asia. New Delhi: Cambridge University Press; 2014.

  • Prakash N, Rockmore M, Uppal Y. Do criminal representatives hinder or improve constituency outcomes? Evidence from India. IZA Discussion Paper 8452; 2014.

  • Przeworski A, Stokes SC, Manin B. Democracy, accountability, and representation. New York: Cambridge University Press; 1999.

  • Sastry T. Towards decriminalisation of elections and politics. Econ Polit Wkly. 2014;49(1): 34–41.

  • Sharma V. Are BIMARU states still Bimaru? Econ Polit Wkly. 2015;50(18):58–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder J, James M, Folke O, Hirano S. Partisan imbalance in regression discontinuity studies based on electoral thresholds. Polit Sci Res Methods. 2015;3(2):169–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thube A, Thube D. Analysis of quality inspection reports of National Quality Monitors for PMGSY roads in India. International Journal of Structural and Civil Engineering Research. 2013;2(2):23–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaishnav M. When crime pays: money and muscle in Indian politics. New Haven: Yale University Press; 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiner M. Party building in a new nation: the Indian National Congress. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witsoe J. Everyday corruption and the political mediation of the Indian state. Econ Polit Wkly. 2012;47(6):47–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodall B. Japan under construction: corruption, politics, and public works. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1996.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chao-Yo Cheng.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic Supplementary Material

ESM 1

(PDF 761 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cheng, CY., Urpelainen, J. Criminal Politicians and Socioeconomic Development: Evidence from Rural India. St Comp Int Dev 54, 501–527 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-019-09290-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-019-09290-5

Keywords

Navigation