Skip to main content
Log in

Development for whom? Beyond the developed/underdeveloped dichotomy

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Relations and Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The developed/underdeveloped dichotomy is the starting point of mainstream theories of development. Based on a theoretical framework inherited from modernisation theories, they represent development as the process through which productive structures in the Global South are transformed following the footsteps of the Global North. Dependency theories productively challenged this linear conception of development, but failed to provide a consistent alternative because of their incapacity to move beyond the developed/underdeveloped dichotomy. In this article, I claim that Trotsky’s concept of uneven and combined development finally indicates a way to think of development beyond the developed/underdeveloped dichotomy. Through analogies with the work of the Dutch artist M. C. Escher, I contrast the concept of uneven and combined development with competing views of development to show both that it makes better sense of particular development trajectories and that it offers a better theoretical base for political action. By stressing the necessarily perspectived character of development, the concept of uneven and combined development makes it possible to ask a crucial question often overlooked: development for whom?

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By defining it as ‘theoretical-political’ problem, I take Kees Van der Pijl’s point that ‘the quest for a new society’ shall be recovered as ‘a criterion for relevance in social science’ (Van Der Pijl 2001, p. 380). De Sousa Santos (2007, p. xviii) also makes a similar claim.

  2. For Boaventura de Sousa Santos (1988, p. 63), ‘the post-modern science is declaredly analogical, knowing the things it knows worst through the things it knows best’. According to that perspective, analogies are much more than mere illustrations. They have the power to illuminate our understanding of things that defy our capacity of representation. The power of analogies will become clear in the fifth section of this text, particularly regarding the concept of ‘pluriverse’.

  3. I thank an anonymous reviewer at JIRD for calling my attention to the use of the term ‘take off’ in that context.

  4. Under the label of dependency theories many different ideas are loosely reunited, therefore I prefer referring to them in the plural. For a comprehensive bibliography on dependency theories put together by one of its most important names, see dos Santos (1998).

  5. The UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean was established in 1948, under the leadership of the Argentine economist Raul Prebisch, soon becoming the home of Latin American Developmentalism. Key texts of different generations of ECLAC economists were republished in a two-volume collection organised by Bielschowsky (2000). For an overview of ECLAC and dependency theories, including the tense but fruitful relations between the two schools, see Kay (2010).

  6. Marini’s argument relies on Marx’s distinction between relative and absolute surplus value. While the former is based on a reduction of the relative value of labour, by pushing down the value of the working class’ consumption goods (i.e. its reproduction cost), the latter is based on an increase in the absolute exploitation of labour, via increasing working hours, or intensification of work in regular working hours. In both cases, capitalists extract surplus value from the production process, but in the first case, the side effect is the creation of a dynamic mass consumption market for the working class, while the latter leads to a continued depression of internal markets in peripheral countries due to low salaries, sometimes below the cost of reproduction of labour itself (super-exploitation). Furthermore, these two forms of surplus extraction complement one another, as the extraction of relative surplus value in central economies requires the continued reduction of the value of consumption goods produced elsewhere.

  7. ‘[T]oday, the new ideologists of the Brazilian bourgeoisie [Serra and Cardoso] find themselves obliged to retake this tradition [developmentalism] and try to give credibility to a Brazilian capitalist development in an American or European fashion. In a nutshell, we are facing a neodevelopmentalism, still ashamed of itself, but that will soon lose its inhibitions’ (Marini 1978, p. 102–103). This is the first academic use of the term ‘neodevelopmentalism’, which would become popular three decades later in reference to post-neoliberal governments in Latin America (Antunes de Oliveira 2018).

  8. Cardoso’s final retreat to an unquestionably developmentalist theoretical position is clear in texts published in the 1990s, in which he dismisses the thesis that peripheral countries would necessarily develop in ‘distorted’ ways: ‘Today we know that it is not true. Countries which were able to manage their economies sensibly to the transformation of modes of production within capitalism, as well as to social issues, have had more favourable trajectories than others. The case of the Asian Tigers is well-known. What remained of “determinism” in the dependency theory, maybe a Marxist trait—and I always criticized determinism—certainly must be fundamentally reformulated’ (Cardoso 1995, p. 151). His practice as President actually reveals an even more drastic stepping back, including alliances with traditional oligarchies and the full-scale embrace of neoliberal policies. As summarised by Perry Anderson, ‘[i]n pursuit of office Cardoso had sacrificed not only his early convictions, which were Marxist and socialist, but over time his intellectual standards’ (Anderson 2016).

  9. The lack of a consistent concept of development in Marx can be seen as a consequence of the lack of theorisation of ‘the international’ in classical sociology (Rosenberg 2006; Makki 2015). No consistent concept of development is possible without a proper theorisation of international relations, as the relational character of development is missed.

  10. The concept of uneven and combined development—now under the acronym UCD—was revisited and reappropriated by Justin Rosenberg as the cornerstone of an alternative perspective to the neorealist paradigm in international relations. Neorealism, as it is widely accepted, confines geopolitical and sociological phenomena into two different and incommensurable realms, thereby divorcing international relations from other social sciences (Waltz 1979). Drawing on UCD, Rosenberg found a simple yet ingenious way around this theoretical problem. Avoiding the standard Marxist procedure of reducing inter-societal relations to simple expressions of the class struggle—which would represent not a real bridging between geopolitical and sociological phenomena but the subordination of the first to the second—the author finds in the principle of unevenness, understood as ‘the most general law of the historical process’, the sociological origin of political multiplicity. Hence, international relations can be understood sociologically as the uneven and combined development of multiple societies in permanent interaction. In Rosenberg’s words: ‘the international, quite simply, […] is nothing other than the highest expression of uneven and combined development. This is its sociological definition’ (Rosenberg 2006, p. 328). After Rosenberg’s pioneering work, a number of writers have been exploring the potentialities of UCD. Outstanding examples include Matin (2013a), Morton (2013), Anievas (2011), Anievas and Matin (2016).

References

  • Acemoglu, Daron. 2009. Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, Perry (2016) ‘Crisis in Brazil’, London Review of Books, 21 April.

  • Anievas, Alexander. 2011. Capital, States, and Conflict : International Political Economy and Crisis, 1914‒1945, PhD dissertation, University of Cambridge. http://ethos.bl.uk/OrderDetails.do?did=1&uin=uk.bl.ethos.609603. Accessed 26 Feb 2019.

  • Anievas, Alexander, and Kamran Matin. 2016. Historical Sociology and World History. London: Rli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anievas, Alexander, and Kerem Nişancıoğlu. 2015. How the West came to rule: the geopolitical origins of capitalism. London: Pluto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antunes de Oliveira, Felipe (2018) The Dilemmas of the Brazilian Left. Monthly Review Online, July.

  • Arrighi, Giovanni. 2009. The Long Twentieth Century: Money. Power and the Origins of Our Time, London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi, Giovanni, and Beverly Silver. 1999. Chaos and Governance in The Modern World System. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashman, Sam. 2009. Capitalism, Uneven and Combined Development and the Transhistoric. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 22 (1): 29–46. https://doi.org/10.1080/09557570802683896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bambirra, Vania. 2012. O Capitalismo Dependente Latino-Americano [Dependent Latin American Capitalism]. Florianópolis: Insular.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bambirra, Vania. 1978. Teoría de La Dependencia – Una Anticrítica [Dependency Theory – An Anti-Critique]. Mexico DF: ERA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bambirra, Vania. 1974. La Revolución Cubana: una interpretación [The Cuban Revolution: An Interpretation]. Mexico, DF: Nuestro Tiempo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, Robert J. 1991. Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2): 407–443. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937943.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-I-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bielschowsky, Ricardo (ed.). 2000. Cinqüenta Anos de Pensamento na CEPAL [Fifty Years of ECLAC Thought]. Rio de Janeiro: Record.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaney, David L., and Arlene B. Tickner. 2017. International Relations in the Prison of Colonial Modernity. International Relations 31 (1): 71–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaney, David L., and Arlene B. Tickner. 2017. Worlding, Ontological Politics and the Possibility of a Decolonial IR. Millennium 45 (3): 293–311. https://doi.org/10.1177/0305829817702446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulos, Guilherme. 2018. Interviewed by Isto É Magazine., 19 June, 2018. https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=qzA5Tz6vHLs. Accessed 26 Feb 2019.

  • Cardoso, Fernando H. 1995. Desenvolvimento: O Mais Políticos Dos Temas Econômicos. Revista de Economia Política 15 (4): 148–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Ha-Joon. 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder?: Economic Development in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem World Economics, Anthem.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, Neil. 2009. Putting the Nation Back into ‘the International”. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 22 (1): 9–28. https://doi.org/10.1080/09557570802683920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Sousa Santos, Boaventura. 1988. Um Discurso Sobre as Ciências Na Transição Para Uma Ciência Pós-Moderna [A Speach About Sciences in the Transition to a Pós-Modern Science]. Estudos Avançados 2 (2): 46–71. https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-40141988000200007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Sousa Santos, Boaventura (ed.). 2007. Democratizing Democracy: Beyond the Liberal Democratic Canon. London and New York: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Sousa Santos, Boaventura. 2014. Epistemologies of the South: Justice Against Epistemicide. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vries, Pieter. 2007. Don’t Compromise Your Desire for Development! A Lacanian/Deleuzian Rethinking of the Anti-Politics Machine. Third World Quarterly 28 (1): 25–43. https://doi.org/10.1080/01436590601081765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dos Santos, Theotonio. 1998. Por Uma Bibliografia Sobre a Teoria Da Dependência [For a Bibliography of Dependency Theory]. Estudos Avançados 12 (33): 137–146. https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-40141998000200010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dos Santos, Theotonio. 1970. The Structure of Dependence. American Economic Review 60 (2): 231–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dos Santos, Theotonio. 1969. Socialismo o fascismo: dilema latinoamericano [Socialism or Fascism: the Latin American Dilema]. Santiago: Ediciones Prensa Latinoamericana.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escher, M.C. 1982. Escher: With a Complete Catalogue of the Graphic Works. London: Thames and Hudson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escobar, Arturo. 1995. Encountering Development: The Making and Unmaking of the Third World, Princeton Studies in Culture/Power/History. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escobar, Arturo. 1992. Imagining a post-development era? Critical thought, development and social movements. Social Text 31/32 (January): 20–56. https://doi.org/10.2307/466217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteva, Gustavo. 1992. Development. In The Development Dictionary, ed. Wolfgang Sachs, 1–23. London: Zed.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fanon, Frantz. 2004. The Wretched of the Earth, edited by Richard Philcox, New York: Grove Press.

  • Frank, Andre Gunder. 1970. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Even Heretics Remain Bound by Traditional Thought. Economic and Political Weekly 5 (29/31): 1177–1184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, André Gunder. 1969. Latin America: Underdevelopment or Revolution: Essays on the Development of Underdevelopment and the Immediate Enemy. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobsbawm, Eric. 1995. Age of Extremes: The Short Twentieth Century 1914‒1991. London: Abacus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kabeer, Naila. 1994. Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kay, Cristóbal. 2010. Latin American Theories of Development and Underdevelopment, Routledge Library Editions, Development, London: Routledge.

  • Kiely, Ray. 2012. Spatial Hierarchy And/Or Contemporary Geopolitics: What Can and Can’t Uneven and Combined Development Explain? Cambridge Review of International Affairs 25 (2): 231–248. https://doi.org/10.1080/09557571.2012.678299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli, Atul. 2004. State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, David S. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are so Rich and Some so Poor. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Löwy, Michael. 2010. The Politics of Combined and Uneven Development: The Theory of Permanent Revolution. Chicago: Haymarket Book.

    Google Scholar 

  • Makki, Fouad. 2015. Reframing Development Theory: The Significance of the Idea of Uneven and Combined Development. Theory and Society 44 (5): 471–497. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-015-9252-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marini, Ruy Mauro. 1973/2009. ‘Dialética de la Dependencia’, in Carlos Eduardo Martins, ed., América latina, dependencia y globalización, second revised edition: 107–151. Pensamiento crítico latinoamericano, Bogotá: Siglo del Hombre Ed.

  • Marini, Ruy Mauro. 1978. Las Razones Del Neodesarrollismo (Respuesta a F. H. Cardoso Y J. Serra). Revista Mexicana de Sociología 40 (January): 57–106. https://doi.org/10.2307/3539683.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx, Karl. 1859/2010. ‘Preface’, A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, in: Karl Marx, Frederick Engels Volume 29: 261–265. London: Lawrence & Wishart Electric Book. http://www.hekmatist.com/Marx%20Engles/Marx%20&%20Engels%20Collected%20Works%20Volume%2029_%20M%20-%20Karl%20Marx.pdf.

  • Marx, Karl. 1867/2010. ‘Preface’, Kapital, in: Karl Marx, Frederick Engels Volume 35: 7–11. London: Lawrence & Wishart Electric Book. http://www.hekmatist.com/Marx%20Engles/Marx%20&%20Engels%20Collected%20Works%20Volume%2035_%20K%20-%20Karl%20Marx.pdf.

  • Matin, Kamran. 2013a. Recasting Iranian Modernity: International Relations and Social Change. London: Iranian Studies, Routledge/Taylor & Francis Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matin, Kamran. 2013. Redeeming the Universal: Postcolonialism and the Inner Life of Eurocentrism. European Journal of International Relations 19 (2): 353–377. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354066111425263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton, Adam David. 2013. Revolution and State in Modern Mexico: The Political Economy of Uneven Development. London: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nisbet, Robert A. 1969. Social Change and History: Aspects of the Western Theory of Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pradella, Lucia. 2015. Globalization and the Critique of Political Economy: New Insights from Marx’s Writings, Routledge Frontiers of Political Economy 192. Abingdon and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rahnema, Majid, and Victoria Bawtree (eds.). 1997. The Post-Development Reader. London: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raworth, Kate. 2017. Doughnut economics: seven ways to think like a 21st-century economist. London: Chelsea Green Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rioux, Sébastien. 2014. Mind the (Theoretical) Gap: On the Poverty of International Relations Theorising of Uneven and Combined Development. Global Society. https://doi.org/10.1080/13600826.2014.983047.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rist, Gilbert. 2002. The History of Development: From Western Origins to Global Faith. London: Zed.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, Justin. 2017. The Elusive International. International Relations 31 (1): 90–103. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047117817691353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, Justin. 2013. Kenneth Waltz and Leon Trotsky: Anarchy in the Mirror of Uneven and Combined Development. International Politics 50 (2): 183–230. https://doi.org/10.1057/ip.2013.6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, Justin. 2013. The “philosophical Premises” of Uneven and Combined Development. Review of International Studies 39 (3): 569–597. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0260210512000381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, Justin. 2006. Why Is There No International Historical Sociology? European Journal of International Relations 12 (3): 307–340. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354066106067345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rostow, W.W. 1959. The Stages of Economic Growth. Economic History Review, New Series 12 (1): 1–16. https://doi.org/10.2307/2591077.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, Jeffrey. 2006. The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time. New York and London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, Wolfgang. 1992. The Development Dictionary: A Guide to Knowledge as Power. London: Zed.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sala-I-Martin, Xavier X. 1997. I Just Ran Two Million Regressions. American Economic Review 87 (2): 178.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selwyn, Benjamin. 2014. The Global Development Crisis. London: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, Amartya. 2000. Development as Freedom. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Serra, José, and Fernando H. Cardoso. 1978. Las Desventuras de La Dialéctica de La Dependencia. Revista Mexicana de Sociología 40 (January): 9–55. https://doi.org/10.2307/3539682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serra, Narcís, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 2008. The Washington Consensus Reconsidered: Towards a New Global Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, Anwar. 2016. Capitalism: Competition, conflict, crises. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, John. 2012. The GDP Illusion. Monthly Review 64 (3): 86–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, Robert M. 1956. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1): 65–94. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2007. Making Globalization Work: The next Steps to Global Justice. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swan, T.W. 1956. Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation. Economic Record 32 (2): 334–361. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4932.1956.tb00434.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teschke, Benno. 2014. ‘IR Theory. Historical Materialism, and the False Promise of International Historical Sociology’, Spectrum: Journal of Global Studies 6 (1): 1–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trotsky, Leon. 1906/1986. Permanent Revolution & Results and Prospects. New York: Pathfinder Press.

  • Trotsky, Leon. 1931/2011. The Permanent Revolution, translated by Max Schachtman. Kapaau, Hawaii: Gutenberg Publishers.

  • Trotsky, Leon. 1932/2008. History of the Russian Revolution. Chicago: Haymarket Books.

  • Truman, Harry. 1949. Inaugural Address. http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=13282. Accessed 26 Feb 2019.

  • UNDP. 2005. Investing in Development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals. London and Sterling: Earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Der Pijl, Kees. 2001. Restoring the Radical Imagination in Political Economy. New Political Economy 6 (3): 380–390. https://doi.org/10.1080/13563460126897.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1984. The Development of the Concept of Development. Sociological Theory 2 (January): 102–116. https://doi.org/10.2307/223344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, John. 2004. The Strange History of the Washington Consensus. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 27 (2): 195–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, Kalpana. 2013. Race, Racism and Development: Interrogating History, Discourse and Practice. London: Zed Books Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, Ellen Meiksins. 1982. The Politics of Theory and the Concept of Class: E. P. Thompson and His Critics. Studies in Political Economy 9: 45–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziai, Aram (ed.). 2007. Exploring Post-Development: Theory and Practice, Problems and Perspectives. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank the participants of the Cornell-Sussex Development Workshop for comments on an early version of this paper. I offer my special thanks to Dr Louise Wise and Professors Justin Rosenberg, Ben Selwyn and Fouad Makki.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Felipe Antunes de Oliveira.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Antunes de Oliveira, F. Development for whom? Beyond the developed/underdeveloped dichotomy. J Int Relat Dev 23, 924–946 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41268-019-00173-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41268-019-00173-9

Keywords

Navigation