Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter April 24, 2020

Projecting the spread of COVID-19 for Germany

  • Jean Roch Donsimoni , René Glawion , Bodo Plachter and Klaus Wälde ORCID logo EMAIL logo
From the journal German Economic Review

Abstract

We model the evolution of the number of individuals reported sick with COVID-19 in Germany. Our theoretical framework builds on a continuous time Markov chain with four states: healthy without infection, sick, healthy after recovery or despite infection but without symptoms, and deceased. Our quantitative solution matches the number of sick individuals up to the most recent observation and ends with a share of sick individuals following from infection rates and sickness probabilities. We employ this framework to study inter alia the expected peak of the number of sick individuals in Germany in a scenario without public regulation of social contacts. We also study the effects of public regulations. For all scenarios we report the expected end date of the CoV-2 epidemic.

JEL Classification: I18; E17; C63

1 Introduction

There is no need to stress the importance of the Coronavirus disease (COVID-19) for public health, economic consequences, and the well-being of individuals. Yet, there is a need for more knowledge about objective information and reliable predictions of how the pandemic will likely evolve in the months to come. How large is the risk of any individual to become sick on a particular day or within a week? How does this risk change over time? How large is the expected number of individuals ever infected, and how large is the number of individuals infected at any point in time (prevalence)? The latter question is the main concern of the public, politicians and health practitioners to ensure sufficient provisions of health services. Finally, what are the effects of policy interventions that are already in place and that are being discussed?

This paper starts by describing what we know quantitatively about the spread of the Corona epidemic in the Chinese province of Hubei and in South Korea. This offers insights from two episodes of epidemics that seem to be coming to an end and that help in making predictions for other countries. We then compare the time-series evidence from Hubei and South Korea with cross-sectional information in European countries.

Section 3 develops an epidemiological Markov model. We start from individuals that can be in four states: healthy (the initial state, state 1), infected and sick (state 2), infected and recovered or infected and never having displayed symptoms (state 3), and deceased (state 4). Individuals move between these states with endogenous transition rates that depend on population characteristics. This model allows us to make predictions, inter alia, about all the quantities of interest that appeared in the initial questions.

We apply this model to Germany. We choose parameter values such that the time series of the number of sick (and reported) individuals in Germany since 24 February is matched by our model. Our data source is the Robert Koch Institute (RKI, 2020). In order to predict the future evolution, we build on various evidence from epidemiology such as individual sickness probability and long-run infection rates of the whole population. We emphasize the scarce medical and statistical knowledge on these parameters. Any predictions therefore must be subject to large variations. We accordingly undertake robustness checks with respect to our central parameters.

Given our calibration for the epidemic without public intervention, we predict prevalence, i. e. the number of sick individuals at each point in time. We compute when the peak will be reached and whether medical services are in sufficient supply. We also undertake counterfactual analysis to understand when drastic policy measures (e. g. shutting down educational institutions or canceling big public events) are most effective.

We have four general findings: First, current epidemiological thinking implies that the long-run effects of the epidemic only depend on the aggregate long-run infection rate and the individual risk to become sick after an infection. Any measures by individuals and the public therefore only influence the dynamics of the spread of SARS-CoV-2 (severe acute respiratory syndrome due to corona virus 2).[1] Second, predictions about the duration and level of the epidemic must strongly distinguish between the officially reported numbers (Robert Koch Institut, RKI) and actual numbers of sick individuals. Third, given the current (scarce) medical knowledge about long-run infection rates and individual risks to fall sick for CoV-2, any prediction on the length (duration in months) and strength (e. g. maximum numbers of sick individuals on a given day) of the outbreak is subject to uncertainty. Our predictions therefore offer robustness analyses that provide ranges on how long the epidemic will last and how strong it will be. Fourth, comparing one public intervention to another public intervention shows that an intervention can lead to either more or less severe outcomes of the epidemic. If an intervention takes place too early, peak prevalence can actually be higher than with an intervention that starts later. Depending on the outcome measure, an intervention can also be worse than no intervention. Interventions should therefore be contingent on current infection rates in regions or countries.

Concerning predictions about COVID-19 in Germany, we find that the long-run number of sick individuals (that are reported to the RKI), once the epidemic is over, will lie between 500,000 and 5 million individuals. While this seems to be an absurdly large range for a precise projection, this reflects the uncertainty about the long-run infection rate in Germany. If we assume that Germany will follow the good scenario of Hubei (and our projections are even a bit more conservative given discussions about data quality), Germany will end up with 500,000 sick individuals over the entire epidemic. If by contrast we believe (as many argue) that once the epidemic is over, 70 % of the population will have been infected (and thereby immune), Germany will end up with 5 million cases.

Defining the end date of the epidemic as the first day with less than 100 incidences, i. e. newly reported sick individuals per day, we find a large variation of outcomes depending on the effectiveness of governmental pleas and regulations to reduce social contacts. An epidemic that is not influenced by public health measures would end in mid-June 2020. With public health measures lasting for few weeks, the end is delayed by around one to two months. The delay is advantageous because it reduces the peak number of individuals that are simultaneously sick. When we believe in long-run infection rates of 70 %, peak prevalence is equally high for all scenarios we went through and well above 1 million. When we can hope for the Hubei-scenario, the maximum number of sick individuals will “only” be around 200,000. Whatever value of the range of long-run infection rates we want to assume, the epidemic will last at least until June, with extensive and potentially future public health measures, it will last until July. In the longest case, it will last until end of August.[2]

There is an exploding literature on these issues, especially in medical science. The classic large-scale spatial model is described in Balcan et al. (2010). It is applied in Chinazzi et al. (2020) to study the effect of a travel ban on China and the world. Akbarpour and Jackson (2018) study a general model of infection, but cannot provide applications to the current epidemic. The widely discussed study by Ferguson et al. (2020) focuses on the US and the UK.[3] An insightful study on the usefulness of isolation strategies for COVID-19 based on a stochastic transition model similar to ours is by Hellewell et al. (2020). Wilder-Smith et al. (2020) discuss the similarities and differences between the SARS 2003 (severe acute respiratory syndrome) epidemic and COVID-19. One big issue is the large number of “quiet infections” in COVID-19 as opposed to SARS 2003, an aspect we will capture in our model below.

The analyses which come closest to ours are two notes by the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Epidemiologie (DGfE, 2020) and by an der Heiden and Buchholz (2020). DGfE (2020) offer predictions based on a model similar to ours (so called SEIR models, see e. g. Anderson et al., 1992). We present our model in detail, including the stochastic foundation, and discuss the implications of the modelling assumptions.[4] Modelling assumptions turn out to be crucial for evaluating public policy measures. We also implement in detail the effects of policy measures and discuss the trade-offs with respect to length and strength of the evolution of the epidemic. The match of the model with the data also differs. While DGfE (2020) seem to use summary statistics for their calibration, we determine the parameters of our model by fitting our model predictions to the data. This offers the advantage that we can update our predictions whenever new data is available.

The study by an der Heiden and Buchholz (2020) is, to the best of our knowledge, the most elaborate study at this point for Germany. We share their belief that mathematical models help in studying the effects of policy measures. Many parameters of their analysis are derived from knowledge on the epidemic in China and especially the city Shenzen. We calibrate many of our central parameters such that the model fits the observations in Germany. We also share with them the approach of using SEIR models. Our paper emphasises the implications of the fundamental model assumptions for the prediction. We find below that the evaluation of policy measures crucially depends on these model assumptions. We make these model assumptions explicit in our paper and discuss the effects of variations in these assumptions.

Why should economists work on an epidemic? The economic costs of COVID-19 are huge and seem to be larger than those of the financial crisis starting in 2007.[5] This paper provides a model that allows us to understand the spread of the disease. We employ a model in the tradition of search and matching models originating from Diamond (1982), Mortensen (1982) and Pissarides (1985). The basic structure of these models (continuous time Markov chains) is identical to epidemiological models (which is clear from overviews such as Hethcote, 2000).[6] Compared to standard search and matching models, we allow for four states, however. We extend the typical matching framework from a technical perspective by taking the stochastic nature of transitions and their prediction for the probability to be in various states into account. These probabilities are described by forward Kolmogorov equations. As we work with a discrete number of states, we obtain an ordinary differential equation system.[7] The conclusion discusses various next steps that should be undertaken to understand economic consequences of COVID-19 better. We believe that our framework can form the basis for an understanding of the economic costs of the pandemic.[8]

2 Data

This section describes what we know quantitatively about the spread of reported infections. We start with Hubei and its capital Wuhan in China. We afterwards look at South Korea and very briefly at Japan. We focus on the evolution of the number of individuals that were ever reported to be sick during the current epidemic. This number, by construction, can only rise. We chose Hubei and South Korea as the epidemics reportedly come to an end in these countries. Given the huge uncertainty about long-run infection rates and individual risk to display symptoms after an infection with CoV-2, we consider the long-run ratios of individuals reported sick to the overall population. This benchmark allows us to judge the credibility of our predictions for Germany. We are aware that we compare very different countries with very different cultural and political habits and medical systems. For reference, we also look at a cross section of infections for European countries. See the appendix for a description of data sources.[9]

Hubei

Since the onset of the outbreak in the Hubei province in China, the number of confirmed cases has risen dramatically, peaking at 67,801 (WHO Situation Reports, 2020).[10] Reporting began in January 2020 and we note that in mid-February, the WHO changed its classification methodology by reporting both clinically and lab confirmed cases rather than only lab confirmed cases. In terms of cumulative numbers, the total reported cases of infected individuals has risen continuously since January, since there has been continuous influx of new cases and very little communication about individuals transitioning back to being healthy.

When reporting began, the rise of new cases seemed to follow an exponential curve, with the number of new cases constantly increasing, however in early February, this trend stopped. Indeed, another trend then took over following a more S-shaped pattern, i. e. that of a sigmoidal function. The total number of reported cases over time is shown in Figure 1, which shows a clear explosive trend at the start of the outbreak before slowing down and approaching what appears to be an asymptote around 70,000.

Figure 1 Total cases in Hubei seem to converge to a constant.
Figure 1

Total cases in Hubei seem to converge to a constant.

To make this comparable to other countries, we take the population of around 59.17 million individuals in Hubei into account. This implies an infection rate of about 0.11 % or 1 person in 873 being infected in the long-run. While this is only one province, it does provide us with a reference point for what to expect in other regions of the world.

South Korea and Japan

Soon after China, South Korea, Japan, and many other countries all started seeing a rise in their number of confirmed cases. However, these countries have had very different experiences when it comes to infection outbreaks. Indeed, while South Korea has seen the number of confirmed cases rise to 9,241, Japan only has 1,307 confirmed cases (or 14 % that of South Korea). The question remains whether these countries are also experiencing a convergence to a stable number of (cumulative) confirmed cases. Figure 2 shows the cumulative number of confirmed cases in South Korea (left) and Japan (right).

Figure 2 Total cases in South Korea exhibit a similar pattern to the Hubei province.
Figure 2

Total cases in South Korea exhibit a similar pattern to the Hubei province.

The data from South Korea shows a reduction in the slope of the curve for total confirmed cases, indicating a significant drop in the number of new infections reported. Assuming the tendency continues, this would point toward South Korea progressively converging to a constant, similarly to the Hubei province in China. Japan on the other hand (as well as all other countries at this point) does not appear to slow down significantly. Relating South Korean infections to population size, we get a long-run infection rate of 1 in 5,337, with a peak number of confirmed cases of ca. 9,606.

Europe

In Europe, however, the situation continues to deteriorate, with new cases being reported by authorities on a daily basis numbering in the thousands (WHO Situation Reports, 2020). However, bearing in mind the lessons learned from the case of the Hubei province, and to a lesser extent from the case of South Korea, this current period of explosive growth should, in theory, be followed by a slow tapering leading to a plateauing of the total number of cases. We report in Table 1 the current infection rates in some European countries. The sample below represents 58 % of the total EU population, including Norway and Switzerland. This sample is by no means intended to be representative and is for illustrative purposes only by considering some of the most affected economies.

Table 1

Current infection rates and risks in a sample of European countries.

CountryPopulationConfirmed casesInfection rate (%)Risk per 1 inhabitant
(1)(2)= (2)/(1)= (1)/(2)
Sweden10,151,8662,5260.025 %4,050
Netherlands17,424,9786,4400.037 %2,684
France (metro)64,906,00025,6000.039 %2,535
Belgium11,455,5194,9370.043 %2,320
Germany83,100,0037,3230.045 %2,227
Norway5,515,7363,1000.058 %1,719
Spain46,937,06049,5150.105 %948
Italy60,359,54674,3860.123 %811
Switzerland8,570,14610,8970.128 %784
Sample total308,143,212214,7240.070 %1,435

As we can see from Table 1, the degree of infection per country varies from 1 in 4,050 to 1 in 784, a fivefold ratio. Other countries fare better, the UK for example has a risk of 1 in 6,914, however we can clearly see that these figures are not yet as low as those in Hubei, with the exception of Italy and Switzerland, which are now below the 1 in 873 rate observed in the Chinese province, and Spain, which is approaching it fast. If this case is to be repeated, then things will likely worsen before they improve. However, with measures taken by governments, and progress being made on the medical front for an effective vaccine, there is still room for governments to curb these rates despite the rapid rise in cases.

3 The model

3.1 The structure

The model builds on a continuous time Markov chain with 4 states. We look at health of an individual i that can be in four states S={1,2,3,4}. Healthy without infection (s=1), sick (s=2), dead (s=3), healthy with or after infection (s=4). State 1 is the initial state for all individuals, thus si(0)=1 for all i=1...N where N is initial population size.[11] There are individual transition rates λrs (with rS and sS) between these states as illustrated in Figure 3.

3.2 Transition rates

Starting with the transition from being healthy to sick, each individual in state 1 has a certain average number of social contacts per day. We capture this by an exogenous arrival or contact rate a. Once a contact takes place, there is a certain probability that the contact is with an individual that can infect the healthy individual. If we assumed random contacts with healthy and sick individuals, this probability would be (N2(t)+ηN4(t))/(N1(t)+N2(t)+N4(t)), where Ns(t) is the (expected) number of individuals in state s at t. This probability assumes that all N2(t) individuals that are sick can infect healthy individuals and a constant and exogenous share η of healthy individuals in state 4 can also infect healthy individuals from state 1. This parameter η captures the idea of “quiet infections” as emphasized e. g. by Wilder-Smith et al. (2020). As opposed to SARS 2003 (or the common flu), individuals infected with CoV-2 do not necessarily display symptoms but can nevertheless infect others. There is also first evidence (Xing et al., 2020) that even recovered individuals (i. e. those that came from state 2) can carry CoV-2, also supporting our use of a positive η.

Figure 3 Transitions between the state of health (initial state), sickness, death and health despite infection or after recovery.
Figure 3

Transitions between the state of health (initial state), sickness, death and health despite infection or after recovery.

In practice, individuals do not encounter sick individuals with this probability being equal to the share of sick individuals in society as sick individuals might stay at home or behave differently (not shaking hands or similar) than non-sick individuals. We do assume, however, that the probability π(t) to encounter a sick individual rises in N2(t) and ηN4(t) and falls in N1(t), i. e. π(t)=π(N2(t),ηN4(t),N1(t)) with π/N2>0, π/(ηN4)>0 and π/N1<0.[12] These contacts can lead to infections. Hence, we have an individual sickness rate of λ12(t)aπ(t). Finally, when there are N1(t) healthy individuals, the aggregate flow from state 1 to state 2 is ϕ12(t)aπ(t)N1(t).[13]

A further property an infection rate should reflect is the fact emphasized by many virologists and epidemiologists that once an epidemic is over, around two thirds of the entire population will be infected. This includes individuals that had symptoms at some point and asymptomatic cases. We capture this fact by introducing the infection rate which is simply the ratio of the number of infected individuals (sick and in state 2 or without symptoms in state 4) to individuals that are alive,

(1)ρ(t)=N2(t)+N4(t)N1(t)+N2(t)+N4(t).

The infection rate is zero initially at t<0. Illustrated for Germany in a way that is somewhat too simple but perfectly fine for our projection, ρ=0 on 23 February 2020 (and before) when the number of reported sick individuals was zero. On 24 February 2020, a number of N2(0)=16 is introduced into the system, and infections and sickness start occurring. The sickness rate λ12(t) is zero also in the long-run when this infection rate equals the long-run infection rate, which we denote by ρ¯. This captures the above mentioned fact that some individuals will never be infected during the epidemic and will always remain in state 1, limtN1(t)>0.

Summarizing our discussion, an example for the individual sickness rate that captures insights from epidemiology and virology would be

(2)λ12(t)λ12a,N1(t),N2(t),ηN4(t),ρ(t)=aN1(t)αN2(t)+ηN4(t)βρ¯ρ(t)γ,

where 0<α, β,γ<1 allows for some non-linearity in the process and a>0. The first term N1(t)α captures the idea that more healthy individuals reduce the individual sickness rate. The second term (N2(t)+ηN4(t))β increases the sickness rate when there are more infectious individuals. The third term in squared brackets makes sure that the arrival rate is zero when a share ρ of society is sick (state 2) or healthy after infection (state 4). The sickness rate satisfies “no sickness without infected individuals”, λ12(a,N1,0,0,ρ)=0 and “end of spread at sufficiently high level”, λ12(a,N1,N2,ηN4,ρ¯)=0. In between these start- and endpoints, the infection rate will first rise and then fall. This specification makes sure that in the long run a share of around 1ρ¯ will not have left state 1, i. e. will never have been infected.[14]

As is widely documented and reported (see e. g. Nishiura et al., 2020), there is also a flow of individuals that are infected but do not display any symptoms. We denote this flow by ϕ14(a,N1(t),N2(t),ηN4(t)) and the corresponding individual rate by λ14. The arguments can be rationalized in the same way as the flows into sickness.

Is it possible to obtain data for λ14? One would need a cohort of inhabitants of a region (and not just those that contact medical services to get tested) to understand the share of individuals that are infected but do not display symptoms. Good data is not available (let alone time series) and might never be available, given the currently still large costs per individual tests (between 80 Euro and 120 Euro). We therefore assume that a constant share r of infected individuals display symptoms. This is a quantity many epidemiologists also work with. Hence, the transition rate λ14 is related to λ12 in the following sense,

(3)rλ14N1+λ12N1=λ12N1.

In words, the outflow of newly infected, λ14N1+λ12N1 in squared brackets on the left-hand side, times the share r of individuals that show symptoms after infection gives the flow into sickness, λ12N1. We can therefore compute the transition rate from the state of being healthy (s=1) to the state of healthy again or no symptoms (s=4) as

(4)rλ14+λ12=λ12λ14=1rrλ12.

Finally, there is an individual mortality rate and a recovery rate. Both rates depend on many individual characteristics. At the aggregate level, they rise in the stock of sick individuals. We specify them as ϕ23(N2(t)) and ϕ24(N2(t)) with corresponding rates λ23 and λ24, respectively.[15] For our analysis below, we will assume that both rates are constants. Concerning recovery, we are aware that it strongly varies across age (e. g. Guan et al., 2020) and that recovery is not a state that is identical for each individual. As we abstract from ex-ante heterogeneity, we assume a recovery rate that is identical across individuals and that it takes on average nrec days until recovery. Given the exponential distribution of duration in each state, this means that 1/λ24=nrec or

(5)λ24=nrec1.

Death is an absorbing state. We also consider the final healthy state to be absorbing, i. e. we abstract from relapses.[16]

3.3 Probabilities and means

The evolution of probabilities, shares and expected numbers

We can express the transition across health states of an individual by a stochastic differential equation similar to the transition across states of employment (see e. g. appendix B.1 to Bayer et al., 2019 or Khieu and Wälde, 2020). We can also directly write down ordinary differential equations for an individual to be in a certain state s at t. Let us denote this probability by ps(t)=Prob(si(t)=s|si(0)=1), i. e. as the probability to be in state s at t conditional on having started in state 1 at t=0. The ODEs have the following general form (see Ross, 1993 for background),

(6)p˙1(t)=λ12p1(t)λ13p1(t)λ14p1(t)+λ21p2(t)+λ31p3(t)+λ41p4(t),p˙2(t)=λ21p2(t)λ23p2(t)λ24p2(t)+λ12p1(t)+λ32p3(t)+λ42p4(t),p˙3(t)=λ31p3(t)λ32p3(t)λ34p3(t)+λ13p1(t)+λ23p2(t)+λ43p4(t),

and are completed by the identity p4(t)=1p1(t)p2(t)p3(t). For brevity, individual transition rates are represented by λrs. We stress that these equations hold for arrival rates that can take any functional form with arguments N1, N2, N3 and N4.

As death is an absorbing state, λ3i=0 for all i. Given the assumption that infected means being immune to further infection and that the mortality rate is negligible in symptom-free states, we also set λ21=λ41=λ13=λ43=0. Our final structure for the evolution of individual probabilities therefore reads

(7a)p˙1(t)=λ12+λ14p1(t),
(7b)p˙2(t)=λ23+λ24p2(t)+λ12p1(t),
(7c)p˙3(t)=λ23p2(t).

A standard law of large numbers tells us that individual probabilities also give shares in the population. Hence, when we solve this system, we can think of the time paths of ps(t) also as the shares of society in the different states. When we compute the expected number of individuals in state s at t, denoted by Ns(t), we would also obtain an identical ODE system where the probabilities are replaced by the expected numbers.[17] As the interest of our analysis lies in the (expected) number of individuals in certain states (are there sufficiently many beds in hospital for severe cases?), we will also refer to the variable ps(t) as the (expected) number Ns(t) of individuals.

The probability to get sick per day

For our quantitative predictions it will be useful to present the probability for an individual to get sick over a period of one day or one week. So far, we only talked about rates λrs. We denote the probability to get sick over a period of one day, starting in t, by pdaygs(t). This probability is one minus the probability to stay healthy. The probability to stay healthy is, given the exponential distribution of duration in a state, a simple exponential function of the transition rate. We therefore obtain

(8)pdaygs(t)=1ett+1λ12sds,pweekgs(t)=1ett+7λ12sds.

The second probability pweekgs(t) is the probability to get sick between today in t and the next 7 days to come. We will plot them below to provide a measure of how risky social interactions are during the evolution of the epidemic.

3.4 The number of individuals who become sick, ever were sick, and die

Because recovery is a process with additional measurement problems, a more reliable data source for our calibration purposes is the number of individuals that have been reported sick since the onset of the epidemic. This is also the time series that is typically reported by countries and regions (such as those reported by the RKI in Germany or the WHO more generally). In our model, the corresponding number follows from the inflows from state 1 to 2 and is given by

(9)N˙2ever(t)=λ12tN1(t)=λ12(t)p1(t)N.

When we are interested in the number of individuals that are newly reported sick at some point in time t (incidences at t in short), we should not employ N2(t). The change of the latter, described in (7b), is determined by the newly reported (inflow) minus the outflow, i. e. those that recovered (and those who died). Hence, when data provides incidences on a given day t, we need to compare this with the inflow between yesterday t1 and t. Hence, our theoretical counterpart to incidences is

(10)N2new(t)=t1tλ12sp1sNds.

Finally, the number N3(t) of deaths from Corona by t is determined by the constant death rate λ23 applied to those that are currently sick,

(11)N3(t)=0tλ23p2sNds.

3.5 Model properties

Before we calibrate our model, we briefly discuss its theoretical predictions. This illustrates the plausibility of our assumptions and also the flexibility of the model. Our model consists of the ODE system (7) where we replace the probabilities ps(t) by the expected number Ns(t) as described in footnote 17. The sickness rate λ12 is from (2), the other arrival rates λ14 and λ24 are from (4) and (5), respectively. The death rate λ23 is a constant. We start the solution of our model with N2ever(0)=Nobservedever(0). We set N3(0)=N4(0)=0 and N1(0)=NN2ever(0).

One can easily understand the plausible structure of our ODE system (7). The number N1(t) of healthy individuals in state 1 (i. e. the probability or share p1(t)) can only fall. Individuals either become sick with rate λ12 or get infected without symptoms with rate λ14. Both transitions imply an outflow from state 1. The same is true, mutatis mutandis, for state 3 and 4: For state 3, there are only inflows from state 2 implying that N3(t) increases over time. State 4 only experiences inflows from state 1 and 2 implying that N4(t) increases over time. The number N2(t) of sick individuals can rise or fall, depending on the difference between inflows with λ12 and outflows with λ23 or λ24.

In the long-run, i. e. when the epidemic is over, individuals will be distributed across states 1, 3 and 4. Some individuals will never get infected. They therefore remain in state 1 all throughout the epidemic. This finding follows from the fact that the sickness rate λ12 from (2) falls to zero when the infection rate ρ(t) from (1) equals its long-run value ρ¯. Note that λ12=0 implies from (4) that λ14=0 as well, hence outflows from 1 to 4 end as well. The ratio ρ¯ is a widely accepted quantity in epidemiology and will be quantified below. Some individuals that become sick and are in state 2 die and move into state 3 in the long-run. Most individuals will be in state 4 in the long-run, either after having transitioned through state 2 or directly from state 1.

The model also displays a long-run property that is extremely useful to judge its quantitative property in a very simple way. With a population of N individuals and a long-run infection rate ρ¯ discussed after (1), the number of individuals that will have been infected is ρ¯N. When a share r of all infected becomes sick, the long-run number of individuals that were sick at some point, described in (9), is

(12)limtN2ever(t)=rρ¯N.

The long-run number of reported sick individuals therefore only depends on the long-run infection rate ρ¯ and the share r of individuals that become sick and are reported. We will exploit this property when we discuss the effects of policy measures below.

4 Calibration

4.1 Data

Our most important data source is the number of individuals that is reported to be sick. We obtain these outflows from state 1 to 2 from the Robert Koch Institute (RKI, 2020). These data fix the left-hand side of our time path for the number N2ever(t) from (9) of individuals that are ever reported as sick. To fix notation, t=0 stands for the 24th February 2020 and T is the day of our final observation.

It seems reasonable to assume that parameters are not constant throughout the entire epidemic. Most centrally, the contact rate a employed in the sickness rate (2) will change as a function of governmental regulations. The first major measures consisted in cancelling sports events (14 March) and closing schools (16 March). Other measures followed.[18] Given a median incubation of 5.2 days (Linton et al., 2020, Lauer et al., 2020) and a certain delay between feeling symptoms, contacting a doctor and getting reported at RKI (say, 2–3 days), we employ T=21 March 2020 as our last observation to fix the contact rate a.

Data to compute the death rate from Corona are also taken from the RKI (2020). We finally employ various sources, to be discussed in what follows, to fix the share r of infected individuals that become sick and the long-run infection rate ρ¯.

4.2 Targets and parameters

Parameters

Some model parameters are straightforward to fix. Concerning the recovery rate (5), we set nrec equal to an average of 14 days despite strong heterogeneity in the course of disease (Guan et al., 2020). The death rate follows from (11). As we want to match the number of reported deaths from COVID-19 by T, the constant death rate for the period from 0 to T can be computed from

(13)λ23(t)=N3obs(t)0Tp2sdsN,

where N3obs(t) is the number of deceased individuals at T. Employing this equation yields the value of 1/500 in Table 2.

A more open parameter for this epidemic (but for which there is a lot of information for other epidemics) is the long-run share of infected individuals, i. e. the limit ρ¯ of (1). We set this equal to 0.67 meaning that once the epidemic is over, two-thirds of the population will have been infected and one-third are still in the original healthy state 1. As there is a lot of uncertainty concerning this value, we consider this widely employed value of 2/3 initially. We will then also consider one tenth of 0.67 as a lower bound further below. This lower bound is motivated by observations from Hubei and South Korea discussed in Section 2.[19] Another parameter which is hard to pin down is the share η of healthy individuals in state 4 (i. e. they were or are infected at some point) that can infect other individuals. We set it equal to 0.4. We also undertake robustness analyses with respect to this parameter.

Table 2

Parameters for the epidemic without public health measures.

nrecλ23rηaρ¯αβγ
141/5000.10.43.024/1062/30.57510.86620.6459

The most interesting parameters are those that allow us to match data reported by RKI. To do so, we minimize the Euclidean distance between the reported data and the predicted values of the model. We target a weighted sum of the squared difference between N2ever(t) from (9) and observation and the newly-sick N2new(t) from (10) and observation. More precisely, parameters a, α, β and γ are obtained from

(14)mina,α,β,γΣt=1TN2ever(t)N2,observedever(t)2+N2new(t)N2,observednew(t)2.

We impose constraints for α, β, γ to lie between zero and one and for a to be positive. None of the constraints are binding. Table 2 presents these and all the other parameter values.

We finally need to quantify r. A generally accepted benchmark says that around 80 % of infected individuals do not display any or only weak symptoms.[20] The remaining share of 20 % falls sick. One crucial question for equation (4), but also for our long-run prediction from (12), is therefore the issue of reporting. If a large share of sick individuals show up at the general practitioner who does not test all individuals that display symptoms that might be caused by CoV-2, then the share r of individuals that are sick and reported will be much lower than these 20%. We therefore set r=0.1 and undertake robustness analyses further below.

Model for predictions

After some intermediate steps (see app. A.2), and employing the fact that we can replace probabilities in our system (7) by expected numbers of individuals as discussed in footnote 17, we obtain our final theoretical structure,

(15a)N˙1(t)=arN1(t)1αN2(t)+ηN4(t)βNβαρ¯N2(t)+N4(t)N1(t)+N2(t)+N4(t)γ,
(15b)N˙2(t)=aN1(t)1αN2(t)+ηN4(t)βNβαρ¯N2(t)+N4(t)N1(t)+N2(t)+N4(t)γλ23+nrec1N2(t),
(15c)N˙3(t)=λ23N2(t),
(15d)N4(t)=NN1(t)N2tN3(t).
This is the system we work with to compute predictions reported in what follows. Initial conditions for our solution are N2ever(0)=Nobservedever(0)=16 for 24 February 2020 (RKI, 2020), N3(0)=N4(0)=0 and N1(0)=83.100.000N2ever(0), where 83.1 million is the population size of Germany (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2020).

Figure 4 New incidences (reported) in the model (N2new(t){N_{2}^{\text{new}}}(t), curve) and in the data (dots) (left) and the number N2ever(t){N_{2}^{\text{ever}}}(t) of sick in model and data (right) for the epidemic without public health measures.
Figure 4

New incidences (reported) in the model (N2new(t), curve) and in the data (dots) (left) and the number N2ever(t) of sick in model and data (right) for the epidemic without public health measures.

4.3 The goodness of fit of the calibration

We can judge the quality of our calibration in two ways. First, we can check the fit for observed number of individuals that were ever reported as sick, N2ever(t) from (9). Second, we can check the quality of the match of the newly reported sick individuals, i. e. N2new(t) from (10).

The left part of Figure 4 shows the number of individuals that were ever reported as sick. The observations from RKI are depicted as circles. It shows that our parameter choices are sufficiently good to use this model for projections into the future.[21] This impression is also confirmed from the right part of Figure 4. Obviously, fitting daily values is more demanding due to the greater variance in the data.

Figure 4 also shows where, in the case of no public health measures, Germany would be heading to. Under the assumption that the share of sick and reported individuals out of the infected individuals is r=0.1, the final number of reported sick individuals will be (right part of Figure 4) 5.5 million. This level will be reached towards the end of June.[22] Hence, towards the end of the epidemic, at stable parameter values, around 7 in 100 inhabitants will have been sick (and reported).

Note that this long run value does not only come out of the solution of our calibrated system (15). It can also be directly read from the long-run prediction in (12), which can be written as limtN2ever(t)/N=rρ¯. When we assume that two thirds of the population will be infected after the epidemic, ρ¯=2/3, and 20 % become sick of which half are reported such that r=.1, we immediately see from (12) that the long run share is 6.7 %, i. e. around 7 in 100.

Figure 5 The number of sick individuals (s=2s=2) by day starting on 24 February 2020 in the absence of public health measures.
Figure 5

The number of sick individuals (s=2) by day starting on 24 February 2020 in the absence of public health measures.

5 Findings

5.1 The number of sick individuals and health care

The most important quantity coming out of our analysis is probably information about prevalence, i. e. the number N2(t) of currently sick individuals. This number will decide whether there will be enough hospital services for all individuals.

The number of sick individuals initially rises strongly. This is the consequence of infections. As recovery sets in only after 2 weeks, the initial period sees this strong increase. Once the number of new sick cases reduces (as the number of individuals in state 1 decreases) and recovery sets in, the number of sick individuals falls again. The peak will be reached in mid-May. We note that this is a prediction for the case where individual contacts, as captured by the parameter a in (2), remain unchanged over time. If the policy measures in place as of 14 March have an effect, we would expect a slowdown in the rise of N2(t). This picture therefore shows what would have happened if no interventions had taken place. In this case, the number of sick (and reported) individuals on a given day, taking recovery into account, will rise above 1 million by the end of April.

Figure 5 also provides the maximum number of infected individuals over the epidemic. This allows us to understand whether the number of extreme cases is always below the level that can be handled by the German health system. The peak of the number of sick individuals in mid-April is close to 220,000. According to the Deutsche Krankenhausgesellschaft (2020), there are 28,000 beds available in intensive care units (ICUs) in Germany. A fraction of these are currently available for the treatment of COVID-19 patients. Moreover, an undefined number of additional hospital facilities with ventilation systems might be available in due time through reorganization activities. By contrast, a large fraction of COVID-19 patients might be treatable in regular wards. While it is therefore difficult to pin down the precise number of beds available for COVID-19 patients, a peak of more than 1 million on a given day is definitely beyond any level that can be handled by the health care system. The prevention of such a scenario in the end has been the key issue of all measures currently taken by federal and state governments. We assess these measures in Section 6.

The one ‘advantage’ of a scenario without public health measures: the epidemic is over fast. As the infection rate is very high, the outflow from the state of being healthy is fast. Hence, a large share of individuals, 1r=90 %, are infected without showing symptoms (or weak symptoms such that they are not reported) and they become immune (in state 4) quickly. Both Figure 4 (left) and Figure 5 show that the epidemic would be over by the end of June.

5.2 Individual risks

One of the concerns of individuals is that they might become infected. How large is this risk in a world without interventions?

Figure 6 The probability per day (dotted) and per week (solid) to become sick in the absence of public health measures.
Figure 6

The probability per day (dotted) and per week (solid) to become sick in the absence of public health measures.

As Figure 6 shows, the risk to fall sick for each individual from (8) is very low throughout the entire epidemic. At the peak, the probability to fall sick on a given day (blue curve) is around 104. In words, 1 person in 10,000 inhabitants falls sick per day. The probability to fall sick within a week (red curve) is of course larger and lies at the peak at around 7 in 10,000 individuals. We emphasize again that this is the number of sick individuals that are actually reported to the RKI.

We compare the daily risk of 1 in 10,000 or the weekly risk of 7 in 10,000 with the long-run risk of 7 in 100 by the end of the epidemic to be or have been sick (as discussed after Figure 4), it seems that at the individual level, the daily or even weekly risk of the epidemic is not really a major health risk.[23] It is clear, however, that at the level of society, the epidemic is a major issue. This difference between the individual risk and aggregate outcomes is the result of a classic negative externality. Even individuals that take into account the overall risk of 7 in 100 to become sick might not be concerned. If the risk of infecting others was taken into account, individual behaviour would look differently. This is why governmental interventions have a clear justification from the perspective of market failure and public economics.

5.3 Robustness check

The long-run sickness rate r

Given uncertainty about the share r of individuals that become sick from an infection, we undertake robustness checks. Instead of our value of 0.1, we also solve our model for an r ten times lower and up to twice as large – as the left column of Table 3 shows. For each of these new values for r, we recalibrate the values for a and α to match the initial observations of sick individuals.

Table 3

Varying the long-run sickness rate r.

raαβγmax{N2(t)}tmaxt1000t100new
0.011.03×104.685.8289.6952182,00423 April15 July19 May
0.0251.282×104.6707.8397.6113440,1352 May4 Aug24 May
0.0512.3×104.7505.8513.7921775,4788 May25 Aug25 June
0.13.02×105.5751.8662.64591,56×10614 May7 Sep17 June
0.22.21×105.5481.8847.75112,9×10619 May27 Sep16 June

The model predictions are very reasonable from a qualitative perspective. The larger the individual risk r to get sick, the higher the number N2(t) of simultaneously sick individuals and the later the peak tmax of the epidemic.

We also find, as was to be expected, that a larger r implies a longer duration of the epidemic. If we define the end of the epidemic by the day t100new where only 100 new incidences are reported per day, we see that the end of the epidemic lies between 19 May and 25 June. Interestingly, the end of the epidemic is not monotonic in r. When the end of the epidemic is defined by the point in time t1000 where 1,000 sick individuals are left (N(t1000)=1000), the epidemic ends between 15 July and 27 September. Note that the t1000 definition implies much later endpoints (of one and the same epidemic) than the t100new definition.

Figure 7 The number N2(t){N_{2}}(t) of sick individuals as a function of assumptions on the probability r to get sick after an infection.
Figure 7

The number N2(t) of sick individuals as a function of assumptions on the probability r to get sick after an infection.

Why are these numbers important from a public health perspective? The data section shows that Hubei and South Korea seem to have managed to keep the long-run ratio rρ¯ from (12) at 1 in 1,000 (Hubei) or 1 in 5000 (South Korea). If we believe that these values are long-run values, then either the individual probability r to get sick after infection of the long-run infection rate ρ¯ must be much lower than the standard values shown in Table 2 or sickness probabilities r must be lower.

As no information is available at this point about the share of individuals that are already immune to CoV-2 in Germany, one might well hope that Germany is heading towards a Hubei long-run equilibrium. As data quality was often argued to be an issue, our long-run ratio rρ¯ with r=0.01 would correspond to 6.7 in 1,000 individuals that were sick at some point in the long-run (N2ever). This would imply that – in the case of no public intervention – the peak in the number of sick individuals would only be around 180,000 individuals (as the first row of Table 3 shows). The blue time path of N2(t) of Figure 7 would be relevant.

Infections via individuals without symptoms

We also inquire into the effect of η, i. e. into the share of healthy individuals that can infect other individuals. The value of η in Table 2 is 0.4 and we now vary it between .25 and .75. While there were qualitative changes (see appendix A.4), there are no quantitative changes that would be of importance for any public health questions.

6 The effect of policy measures

Given that an undamped spread of CoV-2 in society leads to high reported incidences N2(t), public health measures are attempting to reduce social contacts. The fewer social contacts, the lower infections per day. These contacts are captured by the parameter a in (2). Now assume the number of contacts per individual is restricted in some exogenous manner. Individuals are not allowed to watch soccer matches, go to conferences, or move around freely in their region or country. What is the effect of these measures? We also ask whether it makes a difference whether such measures are taken at the beginning of the outbreak of infections or when the measures are delayed for 1 month.

6.1 The experiments

We model policy measures by assuming a time path for a. The first major policy measure, ‘shut down’ for simplicity, took place as of 14 March 2020. Sports events from professional to amateur leagues and schools were closed. This measure is planned to continue until 19 April 2020. As our quantitative analysis starts on 24 February, we employ parameters from Table 2 for the unrestricted epidemic. In particular, we keep the value for the contact intensity a of individuals from Table 2. After 20 days, we reduce a to a lower level alow for the duration of this policy measure. After 37 days, i. e. on 20 April, we return to the original level, assuming that sports events and schooling resumes. Formally,

(16)a(t)=aalow=a/2afort<20days20dayst57dayst>57days

captures the shut down initiated on 13 March. For all shut down scenarios we assume that alow is 50 % lower compared to a.

To understand whether a later intervention is more effective, we counterfactually assume that the intervention starts 32 days later. Here we set

(17)a(t)=aalowafort<5252t89t>89.

We call this the ‘delayed shut down’.

Finally, we investigate into the effect of extending the shut down. We extend the period with lower social contact rate alow to last for 74 days, i. e.

(18)a(t)=aalowafort<2020t94t>94.

This is our ‘extended shut down’.

6.2 The quantitative effects of policy measures

Baseline analysis

For this baseline analysis, we do not recalibrate the model as a in our scenarios changes after T, the day providing the last observation used for calibration. Parameter values are therefore given by the values in Table 2. The effect of various forms of shut downs are captured by a drop of the contact rate a by 50 % to alow, as shown in (16).

The results are shown in Figure 8. Our main variable for judging policy measures is the number N2(t) of individuals that are simultaneously sick.

First, the policy is effective. Reducing contacts reduces the speed of infections and new cases of sickness – but also the transition from healthy in state 1 to healthy (with infection) in state 4. The case without shut down is illustrated by the red curve in Figure 8. It is identical to the curve in Figure 5. The shut down from (16) which reflects the planned closing of schools in Germany until in mid-April is drawn as the green curve. It reduces the rise of the number of sick individuals until mid-April. Afterwards, the number of sick individuals will rise more quickly again. The peak is reached in June and this peak is lower than the one without the shut down. In this respect the shut down is a good policy measure. When the shut down is extended (the black curve), the peak is further shifted to the right and also smaller.[24]

Figure 8 The effect of a shut down.
Figure 8

The effect of a shut down.

Quantitatively speaking, the shut down prolongs the epidemic in terms of its end as defined by t100new also employed in Table 3 (100 or fewer new incidences are reported per day). For the shut down currently in place and for the delayed shut down, the end is beginning of July. For the longer shut down, the end is beginning of August. Concerning the peak demands on the health system, the shut down as currently in place, and also an extended shut down, hardly have any effect. There is a certain delay – which helps the health sector to prepare for higher numbers in the future. But the level of the peak, as Figure 8 shows, hardly changes. This is a fairly bleak outlook.

To be fair, we should stress at this point that the assumption that a shut down reduces the contact rate and thereby the infection rate by 50 % is open to empirical investigation. At this point, this is a model assumption for which empirical evidence is still lacking. Hartl et al. (2020) show that statistically convincing evidence will be available at the earliest beginning of April. It seems fair to say, however, that it can hardly be expected at this point that current measures reduce the infection rate by 50 %. Hence, the above evaluation of the shut down might even be too optimistic.[25]

Is a delayed shut down a good idea?

Interestingly, a delayed shut down (blue curve) is almost as good as an extended shut down and in some respect is even better: A delayed shut down reduces the peak in the number of sick individuals. Hospitals are therefore less crowded with a delayed shut down as opposed to an immediate shutdown. This implies, more generally speaking, that there is an optimal timing for a shut down.

Why is there an optimal point for a shut down? Imagine the shut down takes place early (green curve in Figure 8). Then the number of sick individuals does not increase that quickly. The downside is that, once the shut down is over, there are a lot of healthy individuals left that can become sick. The number of new incidences jumps up and the peak is reached quickly. When the shut down takes place later (the blue curve in Figure 8), the number of sick individuals is larger at the moment the shut down starts. Once the shut down is over, the number of healthy individuals that are left to become sick is not as large as in the case of an early shut down. As a consequence, the peak is less high.[26]

In a perfect world with complete knowledge about the number of sick individuals, the long run infection rate ρ¯, the individual risk r to become sick from an infection and other parameters employed in this model, policy makers should therefore choose the optimal point in time for an intervention. In the world we live in, this information is not available, neither from a medical, nor from a statistical and data processing perspective. The finding nevertheless makes the strong point that policy interventions should be conditioned on the current situation in a country or region. Ideas that policy measures must be the same for all regions in Germany at all points in time are strongly contradicted.[27]

The policy effects with lower ρ¯

To return to the uncertainty about the value of the long-run share ρ¯ of infected individuals, we vary r in Table 3 such that we could also study a “data-quality adjusted Hubei-scenario” where rρ¯ implies that there are 6.7 in 1,000 (ever) sick individuals. This was discussed after Figure 7. We now study changes in ρ¯ at unchanged r=0.1 such that we end up at rρ¯=6.7/1000. We therefore reduce ρ¯ by a factor of 10. We do recalibrate our model for this scenario as ρ¯ affects the calibration outcome. The fit is similarly good to the one discussed after Figure 4. Given the new parameter values, we change the contact rate according to the shut down (16) and the extended shut down (18).

Figure 9 The effect of changes in the long-run infection rate ρ¯\bar{\rho }.
Figure 9

The effect of changes in the long-run infection rate ρ¯.

Let us start with the long-run effects. As we know from (12), the long-run effects with ρ¯ reduced by a factor of 10 are 10 times lower. This is visible in the right part of Figure 9 displaying N2ever(t). Once the epidemic is over, there will be 550,000 individuals that were sick at some point, one tenth of the level in Figure 4. Again, this estimate is independent of any policy measure as the latter do not affect rρ¯.

Concerning short-run effects, we see that in the case of no intervention (or interventions that do not have an effect), the peak comes earlier for N2(t). The red curve in Figure 9 peaks in mid-April in contrast to early to mid-May for the higher long-run infection rate of Figure 8. The effect of the shut down currently in place looks qualitatively similar to the effect when ρ¯ is higher. By contrast, the extended shut down in Figure 9 does not display a strong rise in growth rates of N2(t) once it is over. It is directly followed by the decline in the number of sick individuals.

Most importantly, however, theses Figures 9 and 8 display a strong quantitative difference. If the long run infection rate in Germany is in the “data-quality adjusted Hubei range”, the peaks are at a much lower level. In the case without policy measures and in the case where the current shut down (16) is the only policy measure, the peaks of the simultaneously sick number of individuals is just above 200,000. This strongly contrasts to earlier values above 1 million. Another difference consists in the quantitative difference here between the extended shut down and the shut down. In the scenario with a lower long-run infection rate, an extended shut down implies that the peak of N2(t) will be much lower than the peak of the normal shut down. This was not the case in Figure 8. This points to the fact that shut downs need to be sufficiently strong relative to the overall potential number of sick individuals.

When the long-run infection rate is in this Hubei-range, then the epidemic is also over more quickly than in the case of an infection rate of two thirds. In any case, the epidemic will last until June, in the case of extended shut downs (or other measures) it can even last until mid-July.

7 Conclusion

We have developed a model that allows us to study the spread of an infection in a society. We have solved this model and calibrated it to the COVID-19 epidemic in Germany. We employ the observed number of reported infections to match the initial increase of the number of sick individuals. In addition, we employ parameter values from the medical literature to quantify e. g. long-run infection rates or individual risks to become sick after an infection. Given uncertainty about the precision of these parameter values, we undertook robustness checks with respect to this long-run measure.

When we studied the effect of policy measures in Germany, we found that any intervention that reduces the contact rate of individuals reduces the strength of the epidemic. Both the peak of the number of simultaneously sick individuals as well as the individual sickness risk go down. This decrease is stronger the longer the policy measure lasts.

We also find, however, that there is an optimal point in time when an intervention, effective for a fixed length of time (say, 3 weeks), should start. When the intervention starts too early, there are “too many” healthy individuals left at the end of the intervention. The rise in the number of sick individuals would be accelerated. When the intervention starts later, the number of sick individuals is larger initially. Once the intervention is over, there are, as a consequence, not so many healthy individuals left and the peak is smaller. While implementing optimal schemes for real world societies probably requires too much information, this finding points towards implementing policy measures which are contingent on the current situation (number of sick individuals per capita) of a region or country.

In the long-run, for given parameters, the number of sick individuals is not affected by policy measures when the latter only reduce contact rates of individuals. All findings are subject to large uncertainty given little knowledge about long-run infection rates following a CoV-2 epidemic and individual sickness rates. It seems to be certain, however, that the epidemic will last at least until July, given the public health measures in place. Even in the case of a good scenario with extremely low long-run infection rates, the peak of the number of simultaneously sick individuals will lie above 200,000 individuals.

Many extensions of this framework are worth undertaking. First, optimal behaviour of individuals could be taken into account. The activity parameter a is like the outcome of decisions of individuals on how much to work and how much to enjoy social interactions. One can imagine a trade-off between reducing the risk of getting infected by lowering a and working fewer hours and thereby experiencing lower labour income. The same trade-off is present at the aggregate level to be tackled by a government. Such a trade-off might also include behavioural features like anxiety as in Caplin and Leahy (2001), potentially in a simplified way as presented in Wälde and Moors (2017). These extensions will help us to better understand the challenges posed by this pandemic.

A more detailed modelling of the long-run infection rate would also be useful. The path of social contacts over time should have an influence on the share of infected individuals in the long-run. A more detailed matching mechanism than the one employed here – borrowed in spirit from search and matching models – should be developed. This would also broaden the applicability of our framework to other epidemics and pandemics. The central trade-off faced by decisions makers about health costs vs. economic considerations should also be included in future work. Data on employment effects of COVID-19 should be forthcoming soon. A theoretical framework that allows to look at labour market effects should then prove useful to quantify this trade-off.

Finally, the calibration process employed here can be extended to full structural estimation. Further, the effects of the policy measures in place since 14 March can be estimated or calibrated. The calibration in this paper employs data up to the point where measures of 14 March should start having an effect. By the end of March, the intervention regime discussed above and the corresponding (reduced) contact rate could be quantified. This would provide a good idea of the effects of these policy measures.

Appendix A

A.1 Data sources

Data sources and calculations

The data used in this note is taken from two sources: (i) the World Health Organisation’s Situation reports on the progress of COVID-19, and (ii) the dataset put together by the nCoV-2019 Data Working Group (Dong et al. (2020)). In particular, wherever available the data from the nCoV-2019 Group is used instead of the data from the WHO, in an effort to remain as consistent as possible by using only one source at a time. Data from the nCoV-2019 Group is used as it provides a centralised and standardised repository of multiple official sources.

Figures 1 and 2 showing the number of new confirmed cases at a date t were produced by computing the difference between the cumulative total number of confirmed cases at t minus the cumulative total number of confirmed cases at t1, i. e.

new casest=total casesttotal casest1.

As detailed in the Table 1, the infection rate is computed by dividing the cumulative total number of confirmed cases as of the time of writing by the population of the corresponding country in 2019. Meanwhile, the risk factor is simply the inverse of that fraction and is given by the total population divided by the cumulative total number of confirmed cases, i. e.

Infection Rate in %=total casespopulation2019×100Risk of infection=population2019total cases.

A.2 Intermediate steps for (15)

Recall (2) and write it as

λ12(t)=aN1(t)αN2(t)+ηN4(t)βρ¯N2(t)+N4(t)N1(t)+N2(t)+N4(t)γ=aN1(t)NNαN2(t)NN+ηN4(t)NNβρ¯p2(t)+p4(t)p1(t)+p2(t)+p4(t)γ

where the fraction in squared brackets was multiplied by N/N as well and we employed ps(t)=Ns(t)/N. Applying this to term one and two as well,

λ12(t)=ap1(t)αp2(t)+ηp4(t)βNβαρ¯p2(t)+p4(t)p1(t)+p2(t)+p4(t)γ.

If we want homogeneity of degree 0, we would set α=β. Employing the transition rate λ14 from (4) and taking λ24 from (5) into account, our model in (7) becomes

(19)p˙1(t)=λ12t+1rrλ12(t)p1(t)=λ12(t)rp1(t)
(20)=arp1(t)αp2t+ηp4(t)βNβαρ¯p2(t)+p4(t)p1(t)+p2(t)+p4(t)γp1(t)
(21)p˙2(t)=λ12(t)p1(t)λ23+nrec1p2(t),
(22)=ap1(t)αp2(t)+ηp4(t)βNβαρ¯p2(t)+p4(t)p1(t)+p2(t)+p4(t)γp1(t)λ23+nrec1p2(t)
(23)p˙3(t)=λ23p2(t)
Simplifying, we get (15) in the main text.

A.3 Goodness of fit

We provide a graphical illustration of how well our parameter choice via the minimization procedure in (14) fits the data.

Figure 10 Enlarged version of Figure 4 with data and model fit.
Figure 10

Enlarged version of Figure 4 with data and model fit.

A.4 Comparative statics for η

We assume that a share η of individuals in state 4 can infect individuals in state 1. This captures the fact that some infected individuals do not display symptoms but are nevertheless infectious. We vary the parameter η here to see how much the dynamics of prevalence N2(t) is affected by this parameter.

Figure 11 The effect of how infectious (η) infected individuals without symptoms are.
Figure 11

The effect of how infectious (η) infected individuals without symptoms are.

As this figure shows, the magnitude of η only has minor effects on prevalence N2(t). This is in strong contrast to the importance of, say, r on prevalence as shown in Figure 7.

Acknowledgment

We are grateful to Matthias an der Heiden, Michael Bauer, Matthias Birkner, Christian Dormann, Oliver Emrich, Hoang Khieu, Dietmar Leisen, Kai Pastor, Olaf Posch, Ricardo Reis, Julien Riou, Perikles Simon, William Cannon Warren and members of the modelling initiative of the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Epidemiologie for comments and discussions. We are deeply indebted to Damir Stijepic for the initial numerical solutions and the initial calibration. We would also like to thank the editor and a referee for their support. Our biggest debt of gratitude is owed to Matthias Birkner who has been advising and teaching us on stochastic models for many years.

References

Achdou, Y., J. Han, J. Lasry, P. Lions, and B. Moll. 2020. “Income and Wealth Distribution in Macroeconomics: A Continuous-Time Approach.” mimeo Princeton University. 10.1093/restud/rdab002Search in Google Scholar

Akbarpour, M., and M. Jackson. 2018. “Diffusion in Networks and the Virtue of Burstiness.” PNAS 115(30): 1–9. 10.1073/pnas.1722089115Search in Google Scholar

an der Heiden, M., and U. Buchholz. 2020. “Modellierung Von Beispielszenarien der SARS-CoV-2-Epidemie 2020 in Deutschland.” pp. 1–11. https://doi.org/10.25646/6571.2. Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, R., B. Anderson, and R. May. 1992. Infectious Diseases of Humans: Dynamics and Control. Oxford university press. Search in Google Scholar

Atkeson, A. G. 2020. “What Will Be the Economic Impact of COVID-19 in the US? Rough Estimates of Disease Scenarios.” NBER working paper 26867. 10.3386/w26867Search in Google Scholar

Balcan, D., B. Goncalves, H. Hu, J. Ramasco, V. Colizza, and A. Vespignani. 2010. “Modeling the Spatial Spread of Infectious Diseases: The Global Epidemic and Mobility Computational Model.” Journal of Computational Science 1(3). 10.1016/j.jocs.2010.07.002Search in Google Scholar

Barro, R., J. Ursua, and J. Wenig. 2020. “The Coronavirus and the Great Influenza Epidemic Lessons from the ‘Spanish Flu’ for the Coronavirus’s Potential Effects on Mortality and Economic Activity.” CESifo Working Paper 8166. https://www.cesifo.org/en/publikationen/2020/working-paper/coronavirus-and-great-influenza-epidemic-lessons-spanish-flu. 10.2139/ssrn.3556305Search in Google Scholar

Bayer, C., A. D. Rendall, and K. Wälde. 2019. “The Invariant Distribution of Wealth and Employment Status in a Small Open Economy with Precautionary Savings.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 85: 17–37. 10.1016/j.jmateco.2019.08.003Search in Google Scholar

Bayer, C., and K. Wälde. 2010. “Matching and Saving in Continuous Time: Proofs.” CESifo Working Paper 3026-A. 10.2139/ssrn.1597602Search in Google Scholar

Caplin, A., and J. Leahy. 2001. “Psychological Expected Utility Theory And Anticipatory Feelings.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(1): 55–79. 10.1162/003355301556347Search in Google Scholar

Chinazzi, M., J. Davis, M. Ajelli, C. Gioannini, M. Litvinova, S. Merler, A. Pastore y Piontti, K. Mu, L. Rossi, K. Sun, C. Viboud, X. Xiong, H. Yu, H. Yu, E. Halloran, I. Jr. Longini, and A. Vespignani. 2020. “The Effect of Travel Restrictions on the Spread of the 2019 Novel Coronavirus (COVID-19) Outbreak.” Science 1–17. 10.1126/science.aba9757. Search in Google Scholar

Deutsche Gesellschaft für Epidemiologie. 2020. “Stellungnahme der Deutschen Gesellschaft Für Epidemiologie (DGEpi) zur Verbreitung des Neuen Coronavirus (SARS-CoV-2).” Deutsche Gesellschaft Für Epidemiologie. pp. 1–4. Search in Google Scholar

Diamond, P. A. 1982. “Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilibrium.” Journal of Political Economy 90: 881–894. 10.1086/261099Search in Google Scholar

Dong, E., H. Du, and L. Gardner. 2020. “An Interactive Web-based Dashboard to Track COVID-19 in Real-time.” The Lancet Infectious Diseases 1–2. 10.1016/S1473-3099(20)30120-1. Search in Google Scholar

Dorn, F., C. Fuest, M. Göttert, C. Krolage, S. Lautenbacher, S. Link, A. Peichl, M. Reif, S. Sauer, M. Stöckli, K. Wohlrabe, and T. Wollmershäuser. 2020. “Die Volkswirtschaftlichen Kosten des Corona-Shutdown Für Deutschland: Eine Szenarienrechnung.” ifo Schnelldienst 73(4). Search in Google Scholar

Eichenbaum, M., S. Rebelo, and M. Trabandt. 2020. “The Macroeconomics of Epidemics.” https://sites.google.com/site/mathiastrabandt/home/downloads/EichenbaumRebeloTrabandt_EpidemicsMacro.pdf?attredirects=0. 10.3386/w26882Search in Google Scholar

Ferguson, N. M., D. Laydon, G. Nedjati-Gilani, N. Imai, K. Ainslie, M. Baguelin, S. Bhatia, A. Boonyasiri, Z. Cucunubá, G. Cuomo-Dannenburg, A. Dighe, I. Dorigatti, H. Fu, K. Gaythorpe, W. Green, A. Hamlet, W. Hinsley, L. C. Okell, S. van Elsland, H. Thompson, R. Verity, E. Volz, H. Wang, Y. Wang, P. G. Walker, C. Walters, P. Winskill, C. Whittaker, C. A. Donnelly, S. Riley, and A. C. Ghani. 2020. “Impact of Non-pharmaceutical Interventions (NPIs) to Reduce COVID19 Mortality and Healthcare Demand.” Imperial College COVID-19 Response Team. pp. 1–20. Search in Google Scholar

Gros, C., R. Valenti, K. Valenti, and D. Gros. 2020. “Strategies for Controlling the Medical and Socio-economic Costs of the Corona Pandemic.” https://arxiv.org/abs/2004.00493. Search in Google Scholar

Guan, W., Z. Ni, Y. Hu, W. Liang, C. Ou, J. He, L. Liu, H. Shan, C. Lei, d. Hui, B. Du, L. Li, G. Zeng, K.-Y. Yuen, R. Chen, C. Tang, T. Wang, P. Chen, J. Xiang, S. Li, J.-l. Wang, Z. Liang, Y. Peng, L. Wei, Y.-h. Hu, P. Peng, J.-m. Wang, J. Liu, Z. Chen, Z. Li, Z. Zheng, S. Qiu, J. Luo, C. Ye, S. Zhu, and N. Zhong. 2020. “Clinical Characteristics of Coronavirus Disease 2019 in China.” The New England Journal of Medicine 1–12. 10.1101/2020.02.06.20020974. Search in Google Scholar

Hartl, T., K. Wälde, and E. Weber. 2020. “Bundesliga, Schulen, Kinos – Wann Wissen Wir, Ob die Maßnahmen Gegen Corona Etwas Gebracht Haben?” https://www.macro.economics.uni-mainz.de/corona-blog/. Einschätzung vom 23. März. Search in Google Scholar

Hellewell, J., S. Abbott, A. Gimma, N. Bosse, C. Jarvis, T. Russell, J. Munday, A. Kucharski, W. Edmunds, S. Funk, and R. Eggo. 2020. “Feasibility of Controlling COVID-19 Outbreaks by Isolation of Cases and Contacts.” The Lancet Global Health 8:e488–e496. 10.1016/S2214-109X(20)30074-7Search in Google Scholar

Hethcote, H. 2000. “The Mathematics of Infectious Diseases.” SIAM Review 42(4): 559–653. 10.1137/S0036144500371907Search in Google Scholar

Kaplan, G., B. Moll, and G. L. Violante. 2018. “Monetary Policy According to HANK.” American Economic Review 108:697–743. 10.3386/w21897Search in Google Scholar

Khieu, H., and K. Wälde. 2020. “Capital Income Risk and the Dynamics of the Wealth Distribution.” mimeo Johannes Gutenberg University Mainz. 10.2139/ssrn.3502017Search in Google Scholar

Deutsche Krankenhausgesellschaft. 2020. “Coronavirus: Fakten und Infos.” https://www.dkgev.de/dkg/coronavirus-fakten-und-infos/. Search in Google Scholar

Lachmann, A. 2020. “Correcting Under-reported COVID-19 Case Numbers.” pp. 1–5. medRxiv preprint. https://doi.org/10.1101/2020.03.14.20036178. 10.1101/2020.03.14.20036178Search in Google Scholar

Lauer, S., K. Grantz, Q. Bi, F. Jones, Q. Zheng, H. Meredith, A. Azman, N. Reich, and J. Lessler. 2020. “The Incubation Period of Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19) From Publicly Reported Confirmed Cases: Estimation and Application.” Annals of Internal Medicine 1–7. 10.7326/M20-0504. Search in Google Scholar

Linton, N., T. Kobayashi, Y. Yang, K. Hayashi, A. R. Akhmetzhanov, S.-m. Jung, B. Yuan, R. Kinoshita, and H. Nishiura. 2020. “Incubation Period and Other Epidemiological Characteristics of 2019 Novel Coronavirus Infections with Right Truncation: A Statistical Analysis of Publicly Available Case Data.” Journal of Clinical Medicine 9(2) (538): 1–9. 10.3390/jcm9020538Search in Google Scholar

Mortensen, D. T. 1982. “Property Rights and Efficiency in Mating, Racing, and Related Games.” American Economic Review 72: 968–979. Search in Google Scholar

Nishiura, H., T. Kobayashi, A. Suzuki, S.-M. Jung, K. Hayashi, R. Kinoshita, Y. Yang, B. Yuan, A. Akhmetzhanov, and N. Linton. 2020. “Estimation of the Asymptomatic Ratio of Novel Coronavirus Infections (COVID-19).” International Journal of Infectious Diseases 1–7. Journal Pre-proof. 10.1016/j.ijid.2020.03.020. Search in Google Scholar

Pissarides, C. A. 1985. “Short-run Equilibrium Dynamics of Unemployment Vacancies, and Real Wages.” American Economic Review 75:676–690. Search in Google Scholar

Riou, J., and C. Althaus. 2020. “Pattern of Early Human-to-human Transmission of Wuhan 2019 Novel Coronavirus. (2019-nCoV), December 2019, to January 2020.” Eurosurveillance 25(4). 10.2807/1560-7917.ES.2020.25.4.2000058Search in Google Scholar

Robert Koch Institut (RKI). 2020. “COVID-19: Fallzahlen in Deutschland und Weltweit.” https://www.rki.de/DE/Content/InfAZ/N/Neuartiges_Coronavirus/Fallzahlen.html. Search in Google Scholar

Ross, S. M. 1993. Introduction to Probability Models, 5th ed. San Diego: Academic Press. 10.1016/B978-0-12-598455-3.50004-0Search in Google Scholar

Simon, P. 2020. “Deutschland, Welches Horrorszenario Willst Du? Man Sollte die Katastrophe Vom Ende Her Berechnen!” pp. 1–3. mimeo University Mainz. Search in Google Scholar

Statistisches Bundesamt. 2020. “Bevölkerungsstand.” https://www.destatis.de/DE/Themen/Gesellschaft-Umwelt/Bevoelkerung/Bevoelkerungsstand. Search in Google Scholar

Toda, A. A. 2020. “Susceptible-infected-recovered (SIR) Dynamics of Covid-19 and Economic Impact.” Covid Economics, Vetted and Real-time Papers, 1. 43–63. CEPR press. Search in Google Scholar

Wälde, K., and A. Moors. 2017. “Current Emotion Research in Economics.” Emotion Review 9: 271–278. 10.1177/1754073916665470Search in Google Scholar

Wilder-Smith, A., C. Chiew, and V. Lee. 2020. “Can We Contain the COVID-19 Outbreak with the Same Measures as for SARS?” Lancet Infect Dis. 10.1016/S1473-3099(20)30129-8Search in Google Scholar

World Health Organization. 2020. “Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19): Situation Report – 46.” https://www.who.int/docs/default-source/coronaviruse/situation-reports/20200306-sitrep-46-covid-19.pdf?sfvrsn=96b04adf_4. Search in Google Scholar

Wu, Z., and J. M. McGoogan. 2020. “Characteristics of and Important Lessons from the Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19) Outbreak in China: Summary of a Report of 72?314 Cases from the Chinese Center for Disease Control and Prevention.” JAMA. https://doi.org/10.1001/jama.2020.2648. 10.1001/jama.2020.2648Search in Google Scholar

Ying, Y., P. Mo, Y. Xiao, O. Zhao, Y. Zhang, and F. Wang. 2020. “Post-discharge Surveillance and Positive Virus Detection in Two Medical Staff Recovered from Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19), China, January to February 2020.” Euro Surveill. 25(10): 1–4. 10.2807/1560-7917. Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2020-04-24
Published in Print: 2020-06-26

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 25.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/ger-2020-0031/html
Scroll to top button