Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Where and When Carbon Storage can be Bought Cost Effectively from Private Forest Owners

  • Published:
Environmental Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The role of time in estimating the cost of forest carbon is often ignored in the literature, nor does the literature address the issues of where and when the purchase of forest carbon storage becomes socially beneficial. In our study, we identify the spatial and temporal allocations of forest carbon investments that are socially beneficial based on empirical analysis. We use the Central and Southern Appalachian region in the Eastern United States as a case study over three periods (i.e., 1992–2001, 2001–2006, and 2006–2011) that are roughly in line with moderate, upturn, and downturn market conditions. The areas from which it is socially beneficial to buy carbon storage are mainly in flat terrain and further away from urban boundaries, hence facing lower development pressure and lower urban net returns. These areas also have less urban land and more forestland. The mapping of carbon cost over the three market conditions in our case study also indicates that the socially beneficial carbon area shrinks as the opportunity cost increases when the real-estate market evolves from a moderately growing to a booming market. The socially beneficial carbon area shrinks further as the demand from urban development on forestland collapses when the real-estate market enters a downturn stage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Forest management practices can provide substantial carbon storage (Khanal et al., 2016; Galik et al., 2013; Latta et al., 2011). We assume fixed forest management practices in this paper as we focus on carbon storage benefits from incentive payments that affect decisions at the extensive margin.

  2. In addition, the 1992 NLCD retrofit data still may not be seamless with NLCD data in later years. Although the retrofit data minimize discrepancies between the original 1992 NLCD and the NLCD data in later years, the discrepancies are not eliminated completely. Around 37,000 grid cells in our sample have losses of urban land between 1992 and 2001. We drop the grid cells with discrepancies in forestland shares greater than or equal to 1%.

  3. If we rewrite Eq. (1) as \(\log \left( {\frac{{Sh_{ft \,+\, 1}}}{{Sh_{ft}}}} \right) = f(x)\), where \(f(x)\) is the right-hand side of Eq. (1) that comprises the independent variables and their coefficients plus the error term. Reorganizing the above equation gives \(Sh_{ft + 1} = Sh_{ft} \ast e^{f(x)}\). The \(e^{f(x)}\) is a growth rate of forestland.

  4. To check for robustness, we used different cut-off values. When we increased the cut-off value to four or more, the rural dummy was no longer statistically significant.

  5. The time periods in 1992–2001 are 10 years and 5 years for 2001–2006 and 2006–2011. In order to keep the time window consistent, we also carry out the analysis by pooling 2001–2011 in a single regression instead of in separate regressions for 2001–2006 and 2006–2011. This model specification, however, aggregates the data between a fast-growing real-estate market and a downturn market. The estimated coefficients are not statistically significant for some of the key variables during 2001–2006. The regression results are presented in Appendix A.

    We also did another robustness check on the cut-off time that defines the moderate and upturn market by pooling 1992–2006. The regression results for this check are presented in Appendix B. The estimation lead to a marginal cost of carbon ($2.22 per ton) that is between the estimates from 1992–2001 ($1.84 per ton) to 2001–2006 ($12.09 per ton).

  6. To test whether the market conditions have different impacts on land-use decisions, we conducted a joint F test on whether the coefficients are equal among the three periods and also a Chow test to test the same. Both the joint F tests and the Chow test lead to rejection of the null hypothesis that coefficients are equal across the three time periods at a 1% significance level. These results indicate that the coefficients are different in the three time periods, justifying our decision to run separate regressions for the different time periods.

  7. The DWH test comprises two-stage regressions. The first stage regresses \(DNR_t\) on a set of instrumental variables (IV) and exogenous variables. Out of the first-stage regression, we calculate the residuals and then combine these residuals as regressors into the second-stage regression. In the second-stage regression, the dependent variable is \(\log \left( {\frac{{Sh_{ft \,+\, 1}}}{{Sh_{ft}}}} \right)\) and independent variables include the residuals and the same set of variables specified in Eq. (1). If the estimated coefficients of the residual are statistically significant, then the DNR is endogenous, otherwise, it is not. Given that we have interactions of DNRs and other exogenous variables in our forestland change model, we adopt a nonlinear functional form specified in Kelejian (1971), including the squared term of the regressors and their interactions.

  8. The net present value (NPV) of the social cost of CO2 in 2015 at 3% discount rate is $36/ton in 2007 dollars. Using a conversion factor of 3.67 between CO2 and carbon, we calculate the NPV of the social cost of carbon as $132.12. This NPV is based on a 40-year period from 2010 to 2050, hence the annuity value is $5.72 or $6.01 in 2010 dollars. Social costs of CO2 estimated based on impacts to particular local communities will be different across different areas. However, the focus of this study is on potential for carbon payments that would be deployed at large scales (across this region or nationally). As a result, we use a single, aggregate, social cost to compare targeted areas across different time periods (market conditions) on the same basis, rather than considering local variation in these costs.

  9. The unobservable component of the model will come from a range of sources, including individual variation in decision-making over conversion decisions as well as limitations on our ability to resolve some aspects of the economic data to the grid-cell level.

References

  • Alig R, Adam D, McCarl B, Callaway JM, Winnett S (1997) Assessing effects of mitigation strategies for global climate change with an intertemporal model of the U.S. forest and agriculture sectors. Environ Resour Econ 9:259–274

    Google Scholar 

  • Alig RJ, Latta G, Adams DM, McCarl B (2010) Mitigating greenhouse gases: the importance of land base interactions between forests, agriculture, and residential development in the face of changes in bioenergy and carbon prices. Forest Policy Econ 12:67–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antle J, Capalbo S, Mooney S, Elliott E, Paustian K (2003) Spatial heterogeneity, contract design, and the efficiency of carbon sequestration policies for agriculture. J Environ Econ Manag 42(2):231–250. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0095-0696(02)00038-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbier EB, Burgess JC (1997) The economics of tropical forest land use options. Land Econ 73(2):174–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay K, Heath A (2015) The costs of housing developments on sites with elevated landslide risk in the UK. IOP Conference Series: Earth and Environmental Science 26(2015):012037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen G, Hayes D, McGuire AD (2017) Contributions of wildland fire to terrestrial ecosystem carbon dynamics in North America from 1990 to 2012. Global Biogeochem Cy 31:878–900

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Cho S, Lee J, Roberts R, Yu ET, Armsworth PR (2018) Impact of market conditions on the effectiveness of payments for forest-based carbon sequestration. Forest Policy Econ 92:33–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clutter MC, Mendell BC, Newman DH, Wear DN, Greis J (2005) Strategic factors driving timberland ownership in the U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, South. U.S.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deng S, Shi Y, Jin Y, Wang L (2011) A GIS-based approach for quantifying and mapping carbon sink and stock values of forest ecosystem: a case study. Energy Proced 5:1535–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domestic Policy Council (2013) Technical support document: technical update of the social cost of carbon for regulatory impact analysis under executive order 12866. https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2016-12/documents/sc_co2_tsd_august_2016.pdf

  • Drechsler M, Johst K, Wätzold F (2017) The cost-effective length of contracts for payments to compensate land owners for biodiversity conservation measures. Biol Conserv 207:72–79. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2017.01.014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsheikh R, ARBM Shariff, Amiri F, Ahmad NB, Balasundram SK, MAM Soom (2013) Agriculture land suitability evaluator (ALSE): a decision and planning support tool for tropical and subtropical crops. Comput Electron Agric 93:98–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) (2013) Inventory of U.S. greenhouse gas emissions and sinks: 1990 –2011. Technical Report. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 1200 Pennsylvania Ave., N.W. Washington, DC 20460 U.S.A.

  • Federal Housing Finance Agency (2016) Monthly purchase-only indexes (estimated using sales price data)—U.S. and Census Division (seasonally adjusted and unadjusted) January 1991. House Price Index Datasets, Last updated January 2016.

  • Ferraro PJ (2011) The future of payments for environmental services. Conserv Biol 25:1134–1138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foldvary EF (1997) The business cycle: a geo-Austrian synthesis. Am J Econ and Sociol 56(4):521–541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foldvary EF (2007) The Depression of 2008 Berkeley, Gutenberg, 2007

  • Fritz B, Cligerman J, Mcllmoil R, Hansen E, Hartz L, Hereford A, Vanderberg M, Arano K, Deng J, Strager J, Strager M, Donohue C (2014) An assessment of natural assets in the appalachian region: forest resources. Appalachian Regional Commission, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Fry JA, Coan MJ, Homer CG, Meyer DK, Wickham JD (2009) Completion of the National Land Cover Database (NLCD) 1992-2001 Land Cover Change Retrofit product: U.S. Geological Survey Open-File Report 2008-1379, p 18.

  • Funk JM, Aguilar-Amuchastegui N, Baldwin-Cantello W, Busch J, Chuvasov E, Evans E, Griffin B, Harris N, Ferreira MN, Petersen K, Phillips O, Soares MG, van der Hoff RJA (2019) Securing the climate benefits of stable forests. Climate Policy 19(7):845–860. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2019.1598838

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galik CS, Murray BC, Mercer DE (2013) Where is carbon? Carbon sequestration potential from private forestland in the southern US. J Forest 11(1):17–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galik CS, Latta GS, Gambino C (2019) Piecemeal or combined? Assessing greenhouse gas mitigation spillovers in US forest and agriculture policy portfolios. Climate Policy 19(10):1270–1283. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2019.1663719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gren I-M, Zeleke AA (2016) Policy design for forest carbon sequestration: a review of the literature. Forest Policy Econ 70:128–136. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gulati S, Vercammen J (2005) The optimal length of an agricultural carbon contract. Can J Agr Econ 53:359–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes DJ, McGuire AD, Kicklighter DW, Gurney KR, Burnside TJ, Melillo JM (2011) Is the northern high latitude land-based CO2 sink weakening? Global Biogeochem Cy 25(3):GB3018. https://doi.org/10.1029/2010gb003813

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes DJ, Turner DP, Stinson G, McGuire AD, Wei Y, West TO, Heath LS, deJong B, McConkey BG, Birdsey RA, Kurz WA, Jacobson AR, Huntzinger DN, Pan Y, Post WM, Cook RB (2012) Reconciling estimates of the contemporary North American carbon balance among terrestrial biosphere models, atmospheric inversions and a new approach for estimating net ecosystem exchange from inventory-based data. Glob Change Biol 18:1282–1289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homer CG, Dewitz JA, Yang L, Jin S, Danielson P, Xian G, Coulston J, Herold ND, Wickham JD, Megown K (2015) Completion of the 2011 National Land Cover Database for the conterminous United States–representing a decade of land cover change information. Photogramm Eng and Rem S 81(5):345–354

    Google Scholar 

  • Houghton RA (2005) Aboveground forest biomass and the global carbon balance. Glob Change Biol 11:945–958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoyt H (1933) One hundred years of land values in Chicago. Rpt. NY: Amo Press & The New York Times, 1970

  • Ireland KB, Hansen AJ, Keane RE et al. (2018) Putting Climate Adaptation on the Map: Developing Spatial Management Strategies for Whitebark Pine in the Greater Yellowstone Ecosystem. Environ Manage 61:981. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-018-1029-2

  • Jack BK, Kousky C, Sims KRE (2008) Designing payments for ecosystem services: lessons from previous experience with incentives-based mechanisms. Proc Natl A Sci 105:9465–9470. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0705503104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian HH (1971) Two-stage least squares and econometric systems linear in parameters but nonlinear in the endogenous variables. J Am Stat Assoc 66:373–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khanal PN, Grebner DL, Munn IA, Grado SC, Grala RK, Henderson JE (2016) Evaluating non-industrial private forest landowner willingness to manage for forest carbon sequestration in the southern United States. Forest Policy Econ 75:112–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.07.004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim T, Langpap C (2014) Incentives for carbon sequestration using forest management. Environ Resour Econ 59:1–31. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9827-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim Y, Cho, SH (2018) How spatial targeting of incentive payments for forest carbon storage can be adjusted for competing land uses. Reg Environ Change. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10113-018-1411-x

  • Latta G, Adams DM, Alig RJ, White E (2011) Simulated effects of mandatory vs voluntary participation in private forest carbon offset markets in the US. J Forest Econ 17(2):127–141. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2011.02.006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lennox GD, Armsworth PR (2011) The suitability of short or long conservation contracts under ecological and socio-economic uncertainty. Ecol Model 222:2856–2866

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu X, Cho SH, Hayes D, Armsworth P (2019) Potential efficiency gains in payment programs from resolving spatial and temporal heterogeneity in the cost of supply forest carbon. J Environ Manage 250:109421. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2019.109421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lubowski RN, Plantinga AJ, Stavins RN (2006) Land-use change and carbon sinks: econometric estimation of the carbon sequestration supply function. J Environ Econ Manag 51:135–152. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2005.08.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason C, Plantinga A (2011) Contracting for impure public goods: carbon offsets and additionality. NBER Working Papers 16963, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • McGuire AD, Melillo JM, Joyce LA, Kicklighter DW, Grace AL, Moore B,III, Vorosmarty CJ (1992) Interactions between carbon and nitrogen dynamics in estimating net primary productivity for potential vegetation in North America. Global Biogeochem Cy 6:101–124. https://doi.org/10.1029/92GB00219

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire AD, Melillo JM, Kicklighter DW, Pan Y, Xiao X, Helfrich J, Moore III B, Vorosmarty CJ, Schloss AL (1997) Equilibrium responses of global net primary production and carbon storage to doubled atmospheric carbon dioxide: sensitivity to changes in vegetation nitrogen concentration. Global Biogeochem Cy 11(2):173–189. https://doi.org/10.1029/97GB00059

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Monge JJ, Bryant HL, Gan J, Richardson JW (2016) Land use and general equilibrium implications of a forest-based carbon sequestration policy in the United States. Ecol Econ 127:102–120. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.03.015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mönkkönen M, Juutinen A, Mazziotta A, Miettinen K, Podkopaev D, Reunanen P, Salminen H, Tikkanen O-P (2014) Spatially dynamic forest management to sustain biodiversity and economic returns. J Environ Manage 134:80–89. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2013.12.021

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS), USDA (2014) Agricultural Statistics Annual. Retrieved from https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/Ag_Statistics/2014/index.php

  • Nielsen ASE, Plantinga AJ, Alig RJ (2014) Mitigating climate change through afforestation: new cost estimates for the United States. Resour Energy Econ 36:83–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pan Y, Birdsey R, Fang J, Houghton R, Kauppi P, Kurz W, Phillips O, Shvidenko A, Lewis S, Canadell J, Ciais P, Jackson R, Pacala S, McGuire D, Piao S, Rautiainen A, Sitch S, Hayes D (2011) A large and persistent carbon sink in the world’s forests. Science 300:988–993. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1201609

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ren H, Li L, Liu Q, Wang X, Li Y, Hui D, Jian S, Wang J, Yang H, Lu H, Zhou G, Tang X, Zhang Q, Wang D, Yuan L, Xubing Che X (2014) Spatial and temporal patterns of carbon storage in forest ecosystems on Hainan Island, Southern China. PloS ONE 9(9):e108163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robillard CM, Kerr JT (2017) Assessing the shelf life of cost-efficient conservation plans for species at risk across gradients of agricultural land use. Conserv Biol 31(4):837–847. https://doi.org/10.1111/cobi.12886

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith WB, Miles PD, Perry CH, Pugh SA (2009) Forest resources of the United States, 2007. Gen. Tech. Rep. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Washington Office, Washington, DC, WO-78

    Google Scholar 

  • Southern Tier Central Regional Planning and Development Board (2012) Steep slopes and land use decisions—guidance for planning boards to consider steep slopes in land use decisions http://www.stcplanning.org/usr/Program_Areas/Flood_Mitigation/SCAP_steepslopes%202010_02_21_CR.pdf

  • Stavins R (1999) The costs of carbon sequestration: a revealed-preference approach. Am Econ Rev 89(4):994–1009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stavins R, Adam BJ (1990) Unintended impacts of public investments on private decisions: The depletion of forested wetlands. Am Econ Rev 80:337–352

    Google Scholar 

  • Stavins R, Richards K (2005) The cost of U.S. forest-based carbon sequestration. Report prepared for the Pew Center on global climate change

  • Thamo T, Pannell DJ, Kragt ME, Robertson MJ, Polyakov M (2017) Dynamics and the economics of carbon sequestration: common oversights and their implications. Mitig Adapt Strat Gl 22(7):1095–1111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Forest Service, United States Department of Agriculture (2015) Who owns America’s trees, woods, and forests? Results from the U.S. Forest Service 2011-2013 National Woodland Owner Survey. https://www.fs.fed.us/nrs/pubs/inf/nrs_inf_31_15-NWOS-whoowns.pdf

  • U.S. Geological Survey (USGS) (2013). http://www.usgs.gov/. Accessed 3 Dec 2013

  • U.S. Geological Survey, Gap Analysis Program (GAP) (2016) Protected Areas Database of the United States (PAD-US), version 1.4 Combined Feature Class

  • USDA (2012) Census of Agriculture. Retrieved from https://www.nass.usda.gov/Publications/AgCensus/2012/

  • USDA Forest Service (2015) Forest Inventory and Analysis National Program. Available at http://www.fia.fs.fed.us/

  • van Kooten GC, Sohngen B (2007) Economics of forest ecosystem carbon sinks: a review. Working Paper 2007-02. Resource Economics and Policy Analysis (REPA) Research Group, Department of Economics, University of Victoria

  • White LH (2008) How did we get into this financial mess? Issue 110 of Cato Institute briefing papers. https://www.cato.org/publications/briefing-paper/how-did-we-get-financial-mess

Download references

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge the Agriculture and Food Research Initiative Competitive Grant no. 11401442 and Multistate Project no. TEN00507 (Multistate no. W4133) from the USDA National Institute of Food and Agriculture through the project “Developing a Cost-Effective Payment System for Forest Carbon Sequestration” and “Costs and Benefits of Natural Resources on Public and Private Lands: Management, Economic, Valuation, and Integrated Decision-Making,” respectively. We also gratefully acknowledge G. Chen for generating carbon model outputs and K. Clark, B. Wilson, J. Menard, L. Lambert, T. Kim, and S. Kwon for helpful discussion and data support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiangping Liu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

Table 4 Regression results for periods 1992–2001 and 2001–2011

Appendix B

Table 5 Regression results for periods 1992–2006

Appendix C

Table 6 Instrumental variable (IV) regression results for period 2001–2006

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, X., Cho, SH., Armsworth, P.R. et al. Where and When Carbon Storage can be Bought Cost Effectively from Private Forest Owners. Environmental Management 67, 930–948 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-021-01427-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-021-01427-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation