The Fourth Market theory and interest rate benchmarking in the Islamic finance industry

Ahmed Tahiri Jouti (Al Maali Institute, Casablanca, Morocco)

ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance

ISSN: 2289-4365

Article publication date: 28 December 2020

Issue publication date: 6 July 2021

2709

Abstract

Purpose

This paper aims to understand the issue of interest rate benchmarking in Islamic financial institutions (IFIs) from a macro-economic perspective and assessing the relevance of creating a Sharīʿah-compliant profit rate benchmark to solve this issue. This paper also aims at suggesting an Islamic alternative that will handle both the negative economic impact on IFIs as well as on their financial performance.

Design/methodology/approach

The paper is based on literature review of conventional finance and Islamic finance theories to construct a theoretical model to assess the impact of interest rate benchmarking on the ability of IFIs to achieve the objectives of the Islamic economy.

Findings

The macro-economic perspective concludes that conceiving a profit rate benchmark for the Islamic finance industry is not relevant to raising the Sharīʿah credibility of the industry. Indeed, several adjustments need to be introduced in terms of the business model.

Research limitations/implications

The recommendations of this paper require the involvement of financial authorities and governments for their implementation. Indeed, the adjustments require a macro-economic review.

Practical implications

The paper considers a profit rate benchmark irrelevant and inefficient. Instead, it suggests the necessary adjustments in terms of business model and economic approach for IFIs to achieve their objectives.

Social implications

The paper considers zakat implementation and the adjustment of IFIs as the real path to implement a fair wealth distribution in the society.

Originality/value

The creation of a profit rate benchmark has always been the only solution for the pricing issue in IFIs. This paper challenges this idea and tries to give a deeper understanding of the situation.

Keywords

Citation

Tahiri Jouti, A. (2021), "The Fourth Market theory and interest rate benchmarking in the Islamic finance industry", ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 46-65. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJIF-05-2020-0094

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2020, Ahmed Tahiri Jouti.

License

Published in ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence maybe seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


Introduction

The detractors of the Islamic finance industry consider its banking model and products as a tricky way to attract customers with a religious concern while applying the same conventional financial mechanisms. Several researches conducted in dual banking systems confirmed this perception in countries such as Indonesia (Bougatef and Korbi, 2018), Malaysia (Chong and Liu, 2009; Lee and Isa, 2017) and others. Indeed, Islamic banks take into account interest rates when determining profit rates (for both financing products and term deposit accounts).

In practice, conventional interest rates such as London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR), euro Interbank Offered Rate (EURIBOR), Singapore Interbank Offered Rate (SIBOR) and Kuala Lumpur Interbank Offered Rate (KLIBOR) serve as the main benchmarks for the pricing of Islamic financial products since they are allowed by various Islamic scholars on the basis of non-availability of substitutes (Mohd Yusof et al., 2016). The Islamic International Fiqh Academy (IIFA), on its part, in its Eighth Conference held in Jeddah, 18–19 Shawwal/10–11 April 1993, issued Resolution no. 7 calling for the creation of a new benchmark that is acceptable from a Sharīʿah (Islamic law) perspective as an alternative to interest-based rates for determining profit margins (International Islamic Fiqh Academy, 1993).

In this context, many research papers explored new paths to identify adequate alternatives to interest rate benchmarking and suggested models and indexes that can serve as Islamic pricing benchmarks for Islamic financial institutions (IFIs). Nevertheless, none of these suggestions has been implemented in practice. This leads us to question the relevance of creating a Sharīʿah-compliant profit rate index and the willingness of IFIs to adopt it in their pricing policies.

This paper aims at challenging the idea that creating a new Sharīʿah-compliant profit rate index is sufficient to replace current interest rate indices. The paper defends the idea that having a Sharīʿah-compliant pricing policy in Islamic banks requires major changes in the economic rules and in the business model as well as the acceptance of these changes by both shareholders and customers of Islamic banks.

Therefore, the literature review presents the main suggestions to replace interest rate benchmarking and discusses their relevance from a macro-economic perspective based on both conventional and Islamic finance backgrounds. In the second part, the paper constructs a macro-economic model that defines the reasons behind the irrelevance of interest rate benchmarking and suggests alternative approaches.

Literature review

Alternatives to interest rate benchmarking

Researchers have adopted two different approaches to tackle the pricing index issue in Islamic finance. The first is to suggest a unique profit rate benchmark that would apply to all products regardless of the underlying contracts, such as:

  • The rate of dividend of Islamic bank deposits and investment accounts model proposed by ‘Umar and Sahatah (2000), as quoted in Shehatah (2002), where the interest rate is replaced by a profit rate. This suggestion is irrelevant since the rate of return paid to investment account holders is generally based on the interest rate of term deposit holders in conventional banks, as is the case in Malaysia (Ito, 2013).

  • The inter-Islamic-banks market index proposed by Usmani (2007) would create an Islamic interbank market by creating a common pool that invests in asset-backed instruments and tangible assets. The shares in this pool would be freely negotiable and the value of these shares may serve as an index for Islamic pricing. This suggestion is interesting. Nevertheless, it requires the willingness of the financial authorities to set up an Islamic interbank market. It also requires a significant number of players. Indeed, for financial authorities, interest rate benchmarking may be perceived as a monetary policy transmission mechanism to IFIs. Therefore, any Islamic pricing alternative would alter this mechanism.

The second path consists of suggesting a methodology to calculate a profit rate benchmark per sector, project or product based on real economy factors. A survey conducted in different countries (Bangladesh, Indonesia, Iran, Oman and Pakistan) concluded that none of the real economic activities or trends can be represented by any one economic variable. Therefore, the Islamic financial world should adopt different benchmarks for different economic sectors (Ghauri, 2015). Among the suggestions adopting this path, we can find the use of:

  • Rental index as an alternative to interest rate for Islamic home financing (Mohd Yusof et al., 2016). Nevertheless, if this proposal seems relevant for home financing, it is important to identify equivalent indexes for other economic sectors.

  • Islamic pricing benchmark based on the Asset Pricing Theory (APT) (Omar et al., 2010). The model serves as a viable benchmark rate for the whole market. It recognizes four macroeconomic variables as having good return predictability for all sectors, notably industry production growth, money supply changes, ringgit exchange rate and the Kuala Lumpur Composite Index returns.

In practice, none of these suggestions have been implemented. This leads us to question the relevance and adequacy of a Sharīʿah-compliant pricing index for the Islamic finance industry to fit market practices and constraints. Certainly, adjusting the Islamic pricing method requires economic reforms. Therefore, it is important to compare the conventional and Islamic visions of money and its role in the economy.

The role of money in Islam

Islamic and conventional scholars agree on the functions undertaken by money in a defined economy. Islamic scholars consider the medium of exchange function as the main function of money (Al-Ghazālī, 1980; Ibn Rushd, the grandson, 1995). The other functions, unit of accounts and store of value, are just derived from its principal function.

From the conventional perspective, money plays the same functions but is considered as a commodity that has a price, notably the rate of interest (Say, 1803; Walras, 1886). This price is defined based on equilibrium between the demand for investment and savings which represent the supply of capital (Marshall, 1920).

The preference for liquidity theory, as advocated by Keynes (1936), defines the interest rate as the price that equilibrates the desire to hold wealth in the form of cash with the available quantity of cash. Actually, Keynes declared that the concept of hoarding may be regarded as a first approximation to the concept of liquidity preference and that interest is in fact the reward of “not hoarding”.

In Islam, money is not a commodity that has a price, and hoarding is considered a financial crime (Asad et al., 2014). Therefore, instead of rewarding the “not hoarding” behavior, Islamic law prevents such practices through the application of zakat (alms) (Al-Suwailem, 2013).

The impact of money on market prices

The Equation of Exchange by Fisher (1911) gives an explanation about the impact of money on prices. The equation is composed of two sides: the first side comprises the quantity of money in circulation (M) and the velocity of circulation of money (V); and the second side includes the quantities of goods exchanged (Q) and the prices of these goods (P).

M x V=P x (Q)

According to Fisher (1911), a doubling in V will double P, provided M and Q remain as before. Similarly, a doubling in M will double P, provided V and Q remain as before. Therefore, increasing V or M will have an impact on market prices (P).

Moreover, any change in the interest rates applied will increase or decrease the quantity of money in circulation (M) and will lead to a change in terms of market prices (P) (Keynes, 1936). These changes will have a significant impact on investment and employment.

From the Islamic perspective, market prices go up or down if and only if the quantities of goods exchanged increase or decrease. Increasing or decreasing the quantity of money is not deemed as the right option. Moreover, Islam provides zakat as a solution to increase the velocity of circulation of money in a proper manner (i.e. fighting against hoarding), to safeguard the purchasing power and stabilize market prices (Al-Suwailem, 2013).

The experience of Worgl, an Austrian municipality, seems to be relevant to understand the link between zakat and economic cycles (Boyle, 2015). The principles underlying the Worgl experience are similar to those of zakat.

Unterguggeberger, Worgl’s burgomaster, set up a plan to stimulate the economy of the municipality. The town authorities issued local notes that were called tickets for services rendered. These notes decreased in value by one cent every month. Therefore, the recipients had two options. The first option was to buy a stamp from the municipality to extend the life of the local notes; otherwise, as a second option, they needed to spend their notes immediately in shops that used them to pay taxes to the municipality. Then, the municipality used them again to pay the bills. During the first month, the coins issued by the municipality had made the complete cycle no less than twenty times. Moreover, the stamp taxes collected went to the poor relief fund and unemployment decreased. The stamp taxes were designed to fight against hoarding and were paid to the poor, adopting the same principles underlying zakat.

Literature review gap

The literature related to interest rate benchmarking in the Islamic finance industry focused more on its application on IFIs and product levels. The macro-economic aspects appear to be neglected such as the impact of interest rates on prices and on real economy markets.

It is worth noting that the conclusions and findings related to theories of conventional economics are still valid in the context of hybrid financial systems. The aim of this paper is to address the issue of interest rate benchmarking based on the macro-economic principles underlying conventional finance and Islamic finance.

Research methodology

The objectives of this paper are to identify the impact of adopting interest rate benchmarking on achieving the macro-economic objectives of the Islamic finance industry and to issue recommendations for adjusting the business model. The research methodology adopted is as depicted in Figure 1.

The first step presents a literature review to identify the principles underlying conventional finance and Islamic finance in terms of the role of money in the economy and the impact of monetary policies on prices and on the behavior of people. The second step consists of conceiving a research model with four scenarios to assess the dual financial systems and their impacts on the Islamic finance industry. The construction of the research model would contribute to the third step; that is, issuing appropriate recommendations that take into account the macro-economic context of IFIs.

Model construction: Islamic financial institutions in dual financial systems

The research model consists of a virtual economy that is composed of three markets of essential goods and services, four profiles of economic actors and four scenarios.

  1. The three markets composing the economy are:

    • The first market, for raw materials and agricultural products;

    • The second market, for industrial goods; and

    • The third market, for services.

  2. Moreover, this economy gathers four profiles of economic actors:

    • “Profile 1” comprises people that invest their capital by themselves in at least one of the three markets. Generally, “Profile 1” actors would increase or decrease their risk exposures depending on market conditions.

    • “Profile 2” includes people that invest their capital by collaborating with “Profile 1” and have the necessary expertise in terms of portfolio diversification but are ready to share the profits and bear the losses. “Profile 2” actors would try to diversify their investments to mitigate the risks; but during unfavorable market conditions, they will decrease their investments.

    • “Profile 3” brings together people that would need to collaborate with “Profile 1” to invest in the markets and do not have the necessary expertise to diversify their portfolios. “Profile 3” actors would prefer hoarding rather than investing and sharing profits and losses if they are not assisted.

    • “Profile 4” gathers people other than investors. These are pure workers without any wealth to invest. Therefore, reducing investments would have a negative impact on employment and purchasing power of this category of people.

  3. The research model consists of four scenarios. Each scenario aims at identifying the macro-economic impacts based on the outputs of economic theories discussed in the literature review part:

    • Scenario 1 is the basic scenario where conventional and Islamic theories of money and economics are not applied.

    • Scenario 2 is the scenario where Islamic principles and perception of money are applied.

    • Scenario 3 is the scenario where conventional principles and perception of money are applied.

    • Scenario 4 is the scenario where both Islamic and conventional principles are applied while conventional financial institutions are dominating the economy.

Scenario 1: a ribā-free economy

To better understand the economic mechanisms in an economy operating without ribā (interest), let us start with defining the necessary assumptions underlying this scenario:

  • Ribā is not practiced (conventional banking and all forms of ribā-based transactions are forbidden).

  • The only principles applied in these three markets are ‘al-ghunm bi al-ghurm’ and ‘al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān’ (the one who deserves a profit shall bear the loss, if there is any; and to deserve a profit, a person shall bear the loss, if there is any). Accordingly, to make a profit in this economy, it is compulsory to get involved in a commercial activity in one of these markets while bearing the risk of loss.

  • Products are characterized by atomicity, and there is a lack of friction when it comes to cost and information.

  • The existence of an efficient governance system in these markets reduces the agency costs (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).

  • There are no investment or financial institutions in this economy.

The following describes the macro-economic impact on markets and financial behavior under this scenario:

  • A preference for hoarding: Generally, in such economies, hoarding practices spread and people tend to acquire and hold money because of the fear that prices will fall and losses will be incurred (Asad et al., 2014). There would be no disincentive to hoarding because doing so would not entail any loss of interest and money would not lose value. These practices are justified by the loss aversion phenomenon as discussed in the prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979). When market conditions are not stable, people would prefer hoarding instead of consuming or investing in the absence of fixed income instruments that would reward their preference for liquidity (Keynes, 1936).

  • Profiles of economic agents, investment and consumption levels: In this configuration, sharing the profits and losses would discourage people (from all profiles) from investing in one of these three markets, especially during cycles of significant instability of prices. Moreover, reducing investments would have a negative impact on employment and consumption levels that would create a vicious cycle decreasing the size of markets.

  • Impact on market prices: To increase sales volume, businesses would offer sales on credit as well as spot sales to their customers. From a Sharīʿah perspective, prices in sales on credit and in spot sales can be different. Moreover, the level of prices in both options would be defined based on the offer and demand in these markets. Figure 2 summarizes the conclusions of Scenario 1.

Scenario 2: a ribā-free economy with zakat

In Scenario 1, hoarding represents the reaction of people in a ribā-free economy. Islam forbids ribā and considers hoarding one of the worst economic crimes since it diverts resources from the economy and affects the circulation of money (Asad et al., 2014). It suggests zakat as an alternative system and institution to fight against hoarding practices.

Assumptions underlying Scenario 2:

  • Ribā is not practiced (conventional banking and all forms of ribā-based transactions are forbidden).

  • The only principles applied in these three markets are ‘al-ghunm bi al-ghurm’ and ‘al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān’ (the one who deserves a profit shall bear the loss, if there is any; and to deserve a profit, a person shall bear the loss, if there is any). Accordingly, to make a profit in this economy, it is compulsory to get involved in a commercial activity in one of these markets while bearing the risk of loss.

  • Products are characterized by atomicity, and there is a lack of friction when it comes to cost and information.

  • The existence of an efficient governance system in these markets reduces the agency costs (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).

  • There are no investment or financial institutions in this economy.

  • Zakat is deducted from all the eligible people and redistributed to needy people in line with Sharīʿah principles.

Macro-economic impact on markets and financial behavior:

  1. Eradicating hoarding effects: In this economy, zakat contributes effectively to gradually reducing hoarding practices. Indeed, money loses its value automatically if it does not circulate since people would pay zakat on it on a yearly basis. In this context, the three previous profiles (Profiles 1, 2 and 3) can adopt one of the following economic behaviors:

  • Investing their funds and getting a profit that will be used to pay zakat, safeguard the capital and have an additional return;

  • Spending their funds and acquiring fixed assets on which zakat is not levied.

  • Maintaining their funds and accepting to pay zakat.

These three options would enhance investment and consumption in the economy while using the collected zakat to safeguard the purchasing power of Profile 4.

  • (2) Profiles of economic agents, investment and consumption levels: In this scenario, Profile 1 and Profile 2 would prefer to invest rather than keeping their cash assets aside. Cash assets would lose automatically 2.5% of their value on a yearly basis while their investment can provide them with a return that will safeguard their wealth, pay zakat and generate a return. For Profile 3, not investing would be justified by the absence of trustworthy financial and/or investment institutions that can provide the necessary expertise to people in this category. Nevertheless, it is worth noting that for this category of people, investing is the best option.

The collected amounts of zakat would serve to support the purchasing power of people from Profile 4 in case of economic instability and thus would contribute not only in reducing the negative impacts on the economic cycle but also in reviving it as per the Worgl experience.

  • (3) Impact on market prices: As per the previous scenario, there are two prices in the markets: spot prices and term prices. To understand the impact of introducing zakat on market prices, Fisher’s (1911) Equation of Exchange seems to be the most appropriate tool. In the very short term, introducing zakat would increase the velocity of circulation of money, but later the production capacity of the economy would improve and prices would come back to their initial level. Therefore, introducing zakat in a correct and efficient way would eradicate hoarding, enhance investment and consumption cycles without deeply affecting prices in the market. The only challenge in this scenario is that people belonging to Profile 3 would see their wealth decreasing throughout the years if they cannot find appropriate investment opportunities. Figure 3 summarizes the conclusions of Scenario 2.

Scenario 3: a ribā-based economy

As a response to hoarding practices in Scenario 1, ribā-based instruments and mechanisms can be seen as a solution to stimulate the economy and optimize money circulation.

Assumptions underlying the scenario:

  • Ribā is practiced (conventional banking and all forms of ribā-based transactions are allowed).

  • Products are characterized by atomicity, and there is a lack of friction when it comes to cost and information.

  • There are investment and financial institutions with a business model based on ribā practices.

  • No zakat is collected in this economy.

Macro-economic impacts on markets and financial behavior:

  1. Creating a fourth market in the economy (money market): Allowing ribā-based transactions in the economy would transform “money” to a “commodity” that is traded with a price (interest rate). Granting a loan of US$100 with an interest rate of 5% would mean selling US$100 at US$105.

Therefore, such practices would lead to creating a fourth market in the economy but with different rules than those of the three existing markets. Actually, in this market, all the involved parties would get fixed income (fixed interest rates) or a variable income (variable interest rates) but would never bear a loss. Actually, the al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān principles are broken in this market, and income has no connection with real economy activities.

  • (2) Profiles of economic agents, investment and consumption levels: In this scenario, introducing ribā practices would dramatically change the rules and principles underlying this economy. First, Profiles 1, 2 and 3 would always have a second choice, direct investing (or through equity) in the three markets, or investing in the fourth market. The latter is less risky with a predefined guaranteed return while investing directly in the three markets would be riskier and the return would not be guaranteed. Therefore, the fourth market would attract more investors than the three markets (through equity) due to the loss aversion phenomenon (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979).

Secondly, people belonging to Profile 1 would have the choice to raise funds through instruments in line with al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān principles (option 1) or ribā-based instruments (option 2). In practice, unless they have deep religious concerns, they will prefer the second option because financing with debt would enhance the value of the firm, as propounded by Modigliani and Miller (1963), and would not affect their control over their activity and business.

People belonging to Profile 1 would prefer raising funds in the fourth market in the absence of any serious and credible alternative.

  1. (3) Impact on market prices: Integrating the fourth market in the economy would have the following impacts:

  • Most businesses would prefer to sell commodities on spot, and the fourth market institutions would grant the necessary loans to customers if they could not afford spot sales. This would lead to reducing and replacing term sales.

  • In the previous scenarios, the term and spot prices were determined separately based on the demand and supply in each market and on each commodity. In this scenario, the fourth market becomes the term price market for all commodities [1] and prices are defined based on the demand and supply of ‘money’ (the new commodity) instead of the demand and supply of each of the commodities. Moreover, this fourth market would transfer the demand and supply related to the term sales compartment to the spot sales compartment, which can lead to more pressure on spot prices.

  • In this scenario, the fourth market controls the investment and exchange flows in the economy and replaces the term sales compartment in each of the three existing markets. Indeed, the fourth market would grow rapidly and would reach a very important size that would enable it to control the whole economy. For instance, when interest rates go up, the number of people able to obtain financing would decrease and so would the market prices (Fisher, 1896; Yohe and Karnosky, 1969).

In most Islamic finance literature, the prohibition of ribā is linked to exploitation and injustice. Some authors (Farooq, 2012) argued that the relationship between ribā and exploitation/injustice is evident, but this is not so when it comes to commercial bank interest. Nevertheless, in this scenario, it is clear that it is not only about the relationship between individuals; rather, it is also a macro-economic issue where institutions creating a new market can control the whole economy and have an impact on prices. Figure 4 summarizes the conclusions of Scenario 3.

Scenario 4: a dual financial system economy

In different countries of the Muslim world, Islamic finance was introduced to satisfy the needs of segments with religious concerns to achieve financial inclusion while evolving side by side with conventional finance.

Assumptions underlying the scenario:

  • The three markets are governed by ‘al-ghunm bi al-ghurm’ and ‘al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān’ principles.

  • Ribā is practiced (conventional banking and all forms of ribā-based transactions are allowed).

  • Products are characterized by atomicity, and there is a lack of friction when it comes to cost and information.

  • There are two types of investment and financial institutions – ribā-based business model and Sharīʿah-compliant business model – competing together in the same market.

  • Zakat is not compulsory in this economy.

Macro-economic impact on markets and financial behavior:

  1. Market competition and influence on Islamic financial institutions: This scenario consists of introducing IFIs in a ribā-based economy where they will be competing with well-established conventional financial institutions in a hostile context. This hostility comes mainly from the inappropriate legal and regulatory frameworks but also from the economic rules, practices and customers’ behavior towards financial products and services.

As a result, IFIs adopt a pragmatic approach that seeks to adjust their operational model to comply with current practices to ensure the viability of their businesses. Therefore, the risk profile of Islamic banks is almost identical to conventional banks in terms of product features and financial mechanisms to calculate the profit.

  • (2) Profiles of economic agents, investment and consumption levels: In this scenario, the fourth market still exists and is still more attractive to Profiles 1, 2 and 3 than direct investment in the three markets where al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān principles are strictly applied. Therefore, for IFIs to attract more customers including those with religious concerns, they have to offer investment instruments that have a similar risk profile to those of the fourth market institutions.

    Indeed, in the absence of guaranteed returns or deposit insurance, IFIs engage in natural income smoothing such as Profit Equalization Reserves (PER) and Investment Risk Reserves (IRR) (FAS 11, AAOIFI) and profit waiver when the profit is inferior to the targeted return rate (Taktak, 2011). In some contexts, IFIs offer commodity murābaḥah (tawarruq) or wakālah-based investment accounts offering fixed and guaranteed income to depositors.

    Moreover, for IFIs to implement income smoothing, they are oriented towards fixed income financing instruments such as murābaḥah and ijārah applying the same pricing mechanisms and interest rate benchmarks.

    Therefore, the macro-economic impacts of the fourth market on the economy are still valid and the introduction of IFIs has not changed anything.

  • (3) Impact on market prices: Introducing IFIs is supposed to end or reduce and replace the fourth market as well as its practices and impacts. Nevertheless, adopting practices and product features similar to conventional products would keep the same impacts on market prices:

    • Businesses would sell commodities on spot prices and the fourth market institutions as well as IFIs would grant the necessary financing to customers.

    • Introducing Islamic term sales does not affect the fourth market since they are benchmarking both the risk profile of conventional products and their pricing mechanisms.

    • In this context, the term prices are still defined in the fourth market and applied to term sales in Islamic financial transactions.

Overall, instead of competing with the fourth market, IFIs become a part of it while keeping the same impacts on investment, consumption and market prices. Therefore, it seems obvious that implementing a Sharīʿah-compliant profit rate benchmark would not lead automatically to establishing a macro-economic context that is in line with the requirements of al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān principles. Indeed, a Sharīʿah-compliant profit rate would be just an instrument to control the other three markets as per interest rates’ benchmarks. Table 1 summarizes the impacts of each scenario on investment, consumption and prices.

The main challenge for the Islamic finance industry is to set up a model that comes closest to Scenario 2 in terms of economic impact. Instead of controlling the investment and consumption flows as well as the term prices, IFIs need to be in fact a neutral vehicle for investment.

The way forward for an Islamic alternative to the fourth market

When analyzing the fourth scenario, “an economy based on a dual financial system”, it would seem that the Islamic alternative could not be serious enough to compete with the fourth market institutions. This conclusion is true if we introduce IFIs without taking into account the necessary economic mechanisms.

Obviously, Scenario 2 is the most suitable economic context for IFIs that can help professional and non-professional investors to find adequate investment opportunities in the three markets while applying the ‘al-ghunm bi al-ghurm’ and ‘al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān’ principles. To do so, it is required to implement zakat, to apply ‘al-ghunm bi al-ghurm’ and ‘al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān’ principles, and to review the business model of IFIs.

Implementing zakat

Zakat constitutes the fundamental component of the Islamic alternative to the fourth market. Before launching IFIs, the zakat institution as a pillar of this ecosystem shall be prioritized because it ensures the stability of the system as a whole (Al-Suwailem, 2013). In our context, implementing zakat would enable IFIs to compete with the fourth market institutions.

Breaking the hegemony of the fourth market on financial flows in the economy.

In our context, implementing zakat would give an advantage to Islamic investment instruments compared to investment instruments in the fourth market. When a person X who is eligible to pay zakat has a conventional term deposit, he has to get rid of the interest received and pay zakat (2.5%) on the invested capital. Therefore, person X will always have a negative return (−2.5%) whatever the interest rate offered.

From another perspective, when a person Y who is eligible to pay zakat has a Sharīʿah-compliant investment instrument, he will receive a return that can be used to pay zakat (2.5% of the invested capital – more or less depending on the underlying investment portfolio) and if there is any surplus, it will be for the ownership of person Y. Therefore, a Sharīʿah-compliant investment instrument is more interesting from a financial perspective than conventional financial investment instruments.

Therefore, implementing zakat would direct deposits to Islamic investment instruments and would break the hegemony of financial institutions in the fourth market on investment and consumption flows in the economy.

Enhancing the return of investment instruments in Islamic financial institutions.

IFIs grant financing to Profile 1 (direct investors) but also to other profiles (for consumption purposes if needed). In case of default, zakat can be used to fulfill the financial commitments towards these institutions as per the Baitul Maal Wa Tamwil experience in Indonesia where zakat is used as a buffer in the case of poor borrowers’ default (Wulandari and Kassim, 2016).

In this case, the Return on Assets (RoA) related to the investment portfolio of IFIs would be steady without the need to engage in smoothing mechanisms that can be criticized from a Sharīʿah perspective. Moreover, employing zakat mechanisms would enhance the attractiveness of investment instruments in IFIs.

Creating a new generation of direct investors (profile 1).

Employing zakat to assist indebted people during hard times would encourage IFIs to provide appropriate financing and accompaniment to talented people with brilliant entrepreneurship ideas without requiring collateral. Therefore, IFIs, with the assistance of zakat, would create a new generation of direct investors (Profile 1) and thus would achieve the Qurʾānic principle of a fair distribution of wealth among people (Qurʾān, 59:7). Implementing zakat would:

  • encourage new investors and diversify the investment opportunities in the economy;

  • reinforce the investment instruments of IFIs by providing them with a financial advantage; and

  • stabilize the investment instruments’ rate of return by fulfilling the financial commitments of people towards IFIs.

The advantage provided by zakat to IFIs would enable them to compete fiercely with the fourth market institutions. Nevertheless, IFIs need to review their business model and adjust it accordingly.

Rigorously applying al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān principles

To duplicate the conventional investment instruments’ features, IFIs adopt mechanisms that are in line with al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān principles in form but not in substance. These mechanisms aim at ensuring a targeted rate of return (PER and IRR, profit waiver, etc.); and if there is a favorable performance trend of the investment portfolio, the surplus is not shared with the customer; it goes only to the bank.

Adjusting the investment instruments features.

Most of the investment instruments in IFIs are based on tawarruq, muḍārabah and wakālah bi al-istithmār. Tawarruq is the best instrument for exactly duplicating the fourth market experience while muḍārabah and wakālah bi al-istithmār can be deviated easily from their main structures through a number of practices.

  • In muḍārabah-based instruments, IFIs use two mechanisms to guarantee the targeted rates of return to their customers. First, in the case of a return rate lower than the targeted rate of return, IFIs waive part of their profits to reach the target. Secondly, if the rate of return is higher than the targeted rate of return, IFIs can change the profit-sharing ratio at their discretion without the express approval of customers to keep the surplus for the bank. Therefore, the customers do not bear any shortfall and do not benefit from any positive evolution of the financial performance.

  • In instruments based on wakālah bi al-istithmār, the IFIs, which act as the wakīl (agent), receive a fixed fee while the muwwakil (customers) bear losses and get profits generated from the investment portfolio. IFIs use two mechanisms to adapt the financial features of this instrument to the fourth market mechanisms. First, they reduce the wakālah fixed fees to increase the probability of reaching the targeted rate of return for the muwwakil; and in case there is a gap between the targeted and the real rate, the wakīl waives part of his profit to the muwwakil. Second, the wakīl gets 100% of the surplus if there is any. These two mechanisms invert the wakālah structure. Indeed, the muwwakil receives a predefined return while the wakīl gets the remaining part of the profit.

Adjusting the investment instruments to be in line with the Sharīʿah principles is a prerequisite. Therefore, IFIs need to:

  • Renounce the profit waiver practices. If there is any loss or shortfall, the customer is supposed to bear them.

  • Renounce practices that limit the profit share of the customer in case of a surplus.

Applying the right profit calculation sequence.

In the fourth market institutions, money is a commodity that has a price. Therefore, the cost of financing in this market includes three main components: the fixed return that goes to depositors, the margin of the financial institution to cover the operational expenses and the cost of risk and the return that goes to shareholders.

When the IFIs are using interest rate benchmarks, they are applying the profit rate calculation sequence related to the fourth market institutions. Indeed, IFIs are targeting, as explained above, the same level of returns.

Therefore, adjusting the investment instruments’ features to apply rigorously the principles of al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān as discussed above would invert the profit calculation sequence. Hence, the rate of return to serve to depositors will be based on the return on assets. Figure 5 presents both profit calculation sequences.

Adjusting the financing offer features.

To apply rigorously the principles of al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān when conceiving financing products, the underlying contracts should be in line with the financing purposes and the financial features should be in accordance with the practices in real economy markets.

First, in Islamic law, each contract has its own purposes and its utilization should be in line with these purposes. For instance, ijārah (leasing) is more suitable for pay per use needs and short-term financing. Therefore, using the ijārah contract for ownership financing is not appropriate. For this reason, IFIs are adding other contracts to ijārah to achieve ownership financing which creates a hybrid product that is new to the market and that can raise credibility issues.

From another perspective, IFIs would need to adopt financial features as practiced in real economy markets. For example, if, in these markets, an ijārah contract is terminated based on a three months’ notice, IFIs should do the same.

Overall, the dichotomy between IFIs and the real economy starts with the development and implementation of products that are new to the real economy markets and that are exclusively offered by them. Moreover, if these products do not observe rigorously the principles of al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān, their purposes can be easily deviated and the financial features would be disconnected from the reality of the markets.

For decades, innovation in Islamic finance was limited to products. However, it would be more efficient to innovate in terms of business models while keeping the same products (as practiced in the three markets) without any change.

Reviewing the business model

Let us suppose that implementing products with financial features (including pricing) similar to those practiced in the markets would link the IFIs to the real economy. If that is the case, it is necessary to review the current business models to enable a successful integration in these markets. Since most Islamic banking assets are ijārah- or murābaḥah-based, the examples will focus on both of them.

Business model innovation for ijārah-based products.

IFIs in the Islamic alternative should play the role of a neutral vehicle for financing. They should provide their expertise in terms of risk management, investment and innovation while being part of the real economy and participating in its stability and development.

For instance, innovative business models can provide direct investors (Profile 1), professional and non-professional investors (Profiles 2 and 3) and workers (Profile 4) with a number of advantages such as risk diversification, fixed assets management, etc. For example, it is always better for an investor to have a stake in an ijārah fund – managed by a professional financial institution – than to buy a real property for the reasons discussed in Table 2.

For a lessee, dealing with a professional ijārah fund is always better in terms of quality of services and maintenance. Therefore, the IFI should implement the necessary schemes to manage the assets under ijārah such as legal documentation management, maintenance and replacing the lessees [2].

It is worth noting that in practice, there is a rental market that was not impacted by the fourth market institutions because there is no rival product. Therefore, for ijārah, IFIs need to have an adequate internal organization to ensure the services provided by a property owner while applying the market prices. (Such entities can implement decreasing mushārakah with ijārah).

Business model innovation for murābaḥah-based products.

In the absence of term price markets, implementing an alternative to murābaḥah-based products would be more complicated. Nevertheless, the strategy of car makers can be a suitable business model to apply to murābaḥah-based products. Indeed, most car makers (such as Renault, PSA and Toyota) have their own finance companies granting loans to people willing to buy their cars. Therefore, it is possible to allow large corporations to set up their own finance entities that would be specialized mainly in sales on credit (through murābaḥah).

To increase their sales, car makers generally offer sales on credit through their finance companies. Based on the market conditions, car makers may decide to offer low interest-rate (or even 0% interest-rate) loans to their customers and pay the interest required by their finance companies, thus reducing their profit margins. This business model is similar to the concept of positive banking (Al Rabiah, 2012).

This model can be adjusted to be in line with Sharīʿah principles. In fact, large corporations can create their own separate finance entities that would be in charge of sales on credit. On a regular basis, large corporations would decide on the term price based on the market conditions and would give the stock of commodities to the finance entity at its production cost. IFIs could provide adequate funding to finance entities through murābaḥah or mushārakah and would share the profit according to the market conditions. The profit to be shared would be equal to the term price less the cost of production and any direct expenses related to the stock. For customers in difficulty, zakat could be used as discussed above to pay for them. Figure 6 summarizes this business model.

This business scheme can provide large corporations with the necessary funding when selling the stock of commodities to the finance entity; istiṣnāʿ can be used as the underlying contract. Moreover, the finance entity is not necessarily a finance company; it can take several forms.

Summarizing the pillars of the Islamic alternative.

The Islamic alternative aims at competing seriously with the fourth market. First, it should attract more funds to its sphere. Secondly, the IFIs should play the role of neutral vehicles that orientate savings to profitable and impactful projects and businesses. Moreover, the Islamic alternative aims at eliminating the control of the financial sphere on prices. Table 3 summarizes the main ideas of the Islamic alternative.

Conclusion

The pricing model of Islamic financial instruments undermines the Sharīʿah credibility of the whole industry. Hence, looking for a serious alternative seems to be relevant to ensure the independence of the industry and reinforce its credibility. From a macro-economic perspective, the pricing issue is just the tree that hides the forest.

In ribā-based economies, a new market is born where money is considered as a commodity. This new market grows rapidly and starts to control all the investment and financial flows including prices in the real economy markets. It even replaces the term prices and affects the spot prices.

The introduction of Islamic finance in such economies requires a lot of attention. In fact, to be competitive, IFIs start benchmarking the interest rates (for both financing and investment instruments) to find a place in this economy. Thus, instead of offering an alternative to the fourth market, IFIs become a part of it.

Therefore, conceiving a Sharīʿah-compliant profit benchmark for the Islamic finance industry is not a solution and the Islamic alternative as discussed in this paper requires the implementation of a zakat institution and the adjustment of investment instruments and financing products to be linked to the real economy markets. Moreover, IFIs need to focus more on the business model innovation involving zakat and real economy market practices.

This paper calls for the creation of new business models that link IFIs to zakat and that rely on contracts commonly used in the real economy markets with the same financial features while applying rigorously the principles of al-ghunm bi al-ghurm and al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān.

Finally, the pricing mechanism of IFIs requires the review of their business model. It is not only about the creation of a Sharīʿah-compliant profit benchmark. Therefore, the research and financial engineering efforts should be oriented to conceiving new business models instead of focusing on new products.

Figures

Research methodology of the paper

Figure 1.

Research methodology of the paper

Scenario 1 – a ribā-free economy

Figure 2.

Scenario 1 – a ribā-free economy

Scenario 2 – a ribā-free economy with zakat

Figure 3.

Scenario 2 – a ribā-free economy with zakat

Scenario 3 – a ribā based economy

Figure 4.

Scenario 3 – a ribā based economy

Profit calculation sequences in the fourth market and in the Islamic finance alternative

Figure 5.

Profit calculation sequences in the fourth market and in the Islamic finance alternative

Selling on credit based on market conditions

Figure 6.

Selling on credit based on market conditions

Summary of the economic impacts on investment, consumption and prices in each of the scenarios

Scenarios Economic phenomena Impact on investment Impact on consumption Impact on prices
Scenario 1
A ribā-free economy
Preference for hoarding Investment reduced during instability Consumption levels decreased
  • Existence of spot prices and term prices; the prices are defined based on the offer and demand in the markets

  • Prices decrease during instability

Scenario 2
A ribā-free economy with zakat
Eradicates hoarding effects Encourages investment Encourages consumption
  • Existence of spot prices and term prices; the prices are defined based on the offer and demand in the markets

  • Prices increase in the short term but are stabilized in the mid-term

Scenario 3
A ribā based economy
Creates a fourth market Fourth market controls investment flows Fourth market controls consumption
flows
  • Existence of spot prices only

  • Fourth market controls term prices and impacts spot prices

Scenario 4
A dual financial system economy
Integrating IFIs in the fourth market Fourth market controls investment flows Fourth market controls consumption
flows
  • Existence of spot prices only

  • Fourth market controls term prices and impacts spot prices

Comparison between investing in an ijārah fund and in a fixed asset

Ijārah fund Fixed asset investment
Investing in an ijārah fund is having a stake in every fixed asset managed by the fund (diversification) The investor is directly exposed to risks related to the fixed asset investment (no diversification)
The ijārah fund would take in charge all the maintenance and management tasks of the underlying assets (delegation) The investor would need to manage all the aspects linked to the fixed asset (no delegation)
The investor can sell its shares in the ijārah fund whenever cash is needed (liquidity) The investor would need more time to sell the fixed asset when cash is needed (no liquidity)
The ijārah fund would negotiate maintenance fees with professional entities (optimization) The investor would not be able to negotiate fees with professional entities (no optimization)

Source: Author’s own

Macro-economic impact of the various components of the islamic alternative

Component Objective Macro-economic impact
Implementing zakat Reinforcing the attractiveness of Islamic investment instruments Competing with the fourth market to attract funds and break its hegemony and control of financial flows
Enhancing the return of investment instruments in IFIs
Orienting a portion of the investment flows to new, talented investors A fair wealth distribution among the society
Applying rigorously ‘al-ghunm bi al-ghurm’ and ‘al-kharāj bi al-ḍamān’ principles in investment instruments Invert the profit calculation sequence where the profit rate of investment instruments is an output Transforming investment instruments to neutral vehicles for investment
Involving the financial institutions in the real economy sphere through the adoption of practiced financial features and contracts Linking the financing instruments to the real economy and eliminating the control of IFIs on market prices
Reviewing the business model Moving from product-based innovation to business model-based innovation Defining the main trends for business model innovation to correctly implement the different components of the Islamic alternative

Source: Author’s own

Notes

1.

As discussed, the fourth market loans reduce and replace the term sales in the three markets. Therefore, to buy a commodity on credit, the acquisition cost includes the interest rate.

2.

Because IFIs are not interested in getting involved in real economy transactions, they include terms in contracts that delegate the maintenance to the lessee; and if the lessee wants to terminate the contract, he needs to pay all the remaining rentals.

References

Al-Ghazālī, M.M. (1980), “Iḥyāʾ ʿUlūm al-Dīn”, Dār al-Fikr, Damascus, Syria.

Al Rabiah, R. (2012), Positive Banking: Future Banking, Without Interest, 1st ed., Al Raja Printing Press, KSA.

Al-Suwailem, S. (2013), Madkhal Ilā Uṣūl al-Tamwīl al-Islāmī, Namaa for Research and Studies Center, Beirut, Lebanon.

Asad, I.A., Jamal Elatrash, R. and Omar Farooq, M. (2014), “Hoarding versus circulation of wealth from the perspective of Maqasid Al-Shariah”, International Journal of Islamic and Middle Eastern Finance and Management, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 6-21.

Bougatef, K. and Korbi, F. (2018), “The determinants of intermediation margins in Islamic and conventional banks”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 44 No. 6, pp. 704-721.

Boyle, D. (2015), The Money Changes: Currency from Aristotle to e-Cas, Routledge, London, England.

Chong, B.S. and Liu, M.H. (2009), “Islamic banking: interest-free or interest-based?”, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 125-144.

Farooq, M.O. (2012), “Exploitation, profit and the ribā‐interest reductionism”, International Journal of Islamic and Middle Eastern Finance and Management, Vol. 5 No. 4, pp. 292-320.

Fisher, I. (1896), Appreciation and Interest, Macmillan, New York, NY.

Fisher, I. (1911), The Purchasing Power of Money, Duke University, New York, NY.

Ghauri, S.M.K. (2015), “Why interest rate cannot benchmark for Islamic financial product pricing?”, Benchmarking: An International Journal, Vol. 22 No. 7, pp. 1417-1428.

Ibn Rushd, M.A, the grandson (1995), Bidāyat al-Mujtahid wa Nihāyat al-Muqtaṣid, Dār al-Salām, Beirut, Lebanon.

International Islamic Fiqh Academy (1993), “Majallat majmaʿ al-Fiqh al-Islāmī”, Conference on Currencies Issues, 8th Conference, Jeddah, 18-19 Shawwal, 10-11 April 1993, Vol. 3, p. 780.

Ito, T. (2013), “Islamic rates of return and conventional interest rates in the Malaysian deposit market”, International Journal of Islamic and Middle Eastern Finance and Management, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 290-303.

Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976), “Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 No. 4, pp. 305-360.

Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979), “Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk”, Econometrica, Vol. 47 No. 2, pp. 263-291.

Keynes, J.M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Macmillan, London.

Lee, S. and Isa, M. (2017), “Determinants of bank margins in a dual banking system”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 43 No. 6, pp. 630-645.

Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, 1st ed., Macmillan, London.

Modigliani, F. and Miller, M.H. (1963), “Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction”, American Economic Review, Vol. 53 No. 3, pp. 433-443.

Mohd Yusof, R., Bahlous, M. and Haniffa, R. (2016), “Rental rate as an alternative pricing for Islamic home financing: an empirical investigation on the UK market”, International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis, Vol. 9 No. 4, pp. 601-626.

Omar, M.A., Noor, A.M. and Mydin Meera, A.K. (2010), “Islamic pricing benchmark”, ISRA Research Paper 17/2010, International Shari’ah Research Academy for Islamic Finance, Kuala Lumpur.

Say, J.B. (1803), Traité D’Économie Politique, Calmann-Lévy Editeur, Paris.

Shehatah, H. (2002), “Naḥwa muʾashshir islāmī li al-Muʿāmalāt al-Māliyyah al-Ājilah”, Research presented at the Barakah Conference.

Taktak, N.B. (2011), “The nature of smoothing returns practices: the case of Islamic banks”, Journal of Islamic Accounting and Business Research, Vol. 2 No. 2, pp. 142-152.

Umar, M.A.H. and Sahatah, M.F. (2000), Ījād Muʾashshir, University of al-Azhar Book Centre, College of Commerce, Cairo.

Usmani, M.T. (2007), An Introduction to Islamic Finance, Quranic Studies Publishers, Pakistan.

Walras, L. (1886), Théorie de la Monnaie, Imprimerie Corbaz and Cie, Lausanne.

Wulandari, P. and Kassim, S. (2016), “Issues and challenges in financing the poor: case of Baitul maal Wa tamwil in Indonesia”, International Journal of Bank Marketing, Vol. 34 No. 2, pp. 216-234.

Yohe, W.P. and Karnosky, D.S. (1969), Interest Rates and Price Level Changes, 1952-1962, Vol. 51, Federal Reserve Bank, St Louis.

Corresponding author

Ahmed Tahiri Jouti can be contacted at: a.tahiri@almaaligroup.com

About the author

Ahmed Tahiri Jouti holds a PhD in Islamic economics and finance. He is the Co-CEO at Al Maali Group. He led many consulting assignments related to Islamic finance in Africa, the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) and Europe.

Related articles