Skip to main content
Log in

Offending Frequency and Responses to Illegal Monetary Incentives

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Criminology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Objectives

We examine how responsive offenders are to illegal monetary incentives. We draw from rational choice theory, prospect theory, and models of labor supply to develop expectations regarding the relationship between criminal efficiency, which is the average earnings per offense, and frequency of offending.

Methods

We use OLS, fixed effects, and first-difference estimators to analyze data from 152 incarcerated male inmates from Quebec, Canada to study within individual monthly changes in criminal efficiency and offending frequency.

Results

There is an inverse relationship between criminal efficiency and frequency of offending, net of individual fixed effects, for market crimes, but not property crimes. We also find that the supply of crime is inelastic, meaning it is not highly sensitive to illegal wage changes.

Conclusions

In the months that offenders have an average bigger pay-off per crime, they offended less frequently. We conjecture that this negative relationship could be explained by two mechanisms: an income effect and/or through reference dependence. However, we are not able to disentangle between the two mechanisms. Moreover, we note that criminal efficiency is likely endogenous and should be treated as such in future scholarship.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Much of what is known about offending frequency is rooted in the criminal career literature. Interest in offending frequency surfaced in the 1980s and 1990s and has largely been associated with studies that compare predictors of participation and frequency to test the veracity of the criminal career framework (e.g., Blumstein 1986; Blumstein and Cohen 1987; Nagin and Smith 1990; Smith et al. 1991).

  2. This distinction is analogous to the difference economists refer to as the extensive versus intensive margin.

  3. To be clear, the terms ‘risk seeking’ and ‘risk averse’ are defined in terms of the amount of risk an individual is willing to take in relation to the expected payoff of a gamble.

  4. Some readers may at first glance object to frequency appearing on both the right-hand side and left-hand side of this equation. However, the choice problem this represents is in which a potential offender must choose how many offenses in which to participate based on their expectation of how lucrative each offense is represents a direct analog to a standard choice problem in labor supply in which a worker must choose how many hours to supply to the market based on the hourly wage ($/hour). In this case, similar to frequency in the current application, hours would technically appear on either side of the equation.

  5. About 57% of respondents reported being incarcerated in 2000 or 2001; about 21% in 1998 or 1999; 17% in 1996 or 1997; and 4% in 1994 or 1995. As sensitivity analysis, we conducted our analyses with respondents who were incarcerated in 2000 or 2001 (57% of the sample) and results were consistent with our main results.

  6. While robbery is often categorized as a violent crime, in the current context, robbery tends to be a low frequency non-transactional crime and therefore included as a property crime.

  7. This measure is similar to other studies that group together offense types as a measure of specialization (e.g., Thomas 2015; Piquero 2000).

  8. In a traditional wage regression in which earnings (rate) was the dependent variable, these values can be treated using a traditional selection correction model in which the model parameters are corrected to adjust for selection bias (see Loughran et al. 2013). However, given that in the present case the unobserved values are on the right-hand side as opposed to the left-hand side, such a correction is not applicable.

References

  • Adams C, Webley P (2002) Small business owners’ attitudes on VAT compliance in the UK. J Econ Psychol 22(2):195–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adler PA (1993) Wheeling and dealing: an ethnography of an upper-level drug dealing community. Columbia University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Agan AY, Makowsky MD (2018) The minimum wage, EITC, and criminal recidivism. (Abstract no. 3097203). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3097203

  • Agnew R (1994) Delinquency and the desire for money. Justice Q 11(3):411–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. In: Fielding NG, Clarke A, Witt R (eds) The economic dimensions of crime. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 13–68

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1974) A theory of social interactions. J Polit Econ 82(6):1063–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1985) Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor. J Labor Econo 3(1):S33–S58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM (1992) The division of labor, coordination costs, and knowledge. Q J Econ 107(4):1137–1160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A (1986) Criminal careers and “career criminals”. vol 2. National Academy Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A, Cohen J (1987) Characterizing criminal careers. Science 237(4818):985–991

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burt RS (2002) The social capital of structural holes. In: Guillen MF, Collins R, England P, Meyer M (eds) New directions in economic sociology. Russell Sage Foundation, New York, NY, pp 202–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Babcock L, Loewenstein G, Thaler R (1997) Labor supply of New York City cabdrivers: one day at a time. Q J Econ 112(2):407–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charest M (2004) Peut-on se fier aux delinquants pour estimer leurs gains criminels? Criminologie 37(2):63–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke RVG, Cornish DB (eds) (1986) The reasoning criminal: Rational choice perspectives on offending. Springer-Verlag

  • Cromwell P, Olson JN (2005) The reasoning burglar: motives and decision-making strategies In: Cromwell P (ed.), 4th edn., In their own words: criminals on crime (An Anthology), Roxbury Publishing, Los Angeles, pp 42–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Cullen FT, Larson MT, Mathers RA (1985) Having money and delinquent involvement. The neglect of power in delinquency theory. Crim Justice Behav 12(2):171–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day C, Collins L, Degenhardt L, Thetford C, Maher L (2004) Reliability of heroin users’ reports of drug use behaviour using a 24 month timeline follow-back technique to assess the impact of the Australian heroin shortage. Addict Res Theory 12(5):433–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dembo R, Hughes P, Jackson L, Mieczkowski T (1993) Crack cocaine dealing by adolescents in two public housing projects: a pilot study. Hum Organ 52(1):89–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desroches FJ (2005) The crime that pays: Drug trafficking and organized crime in Canada. Canadian Scholars’ Press, Edmonton, ON, Canada

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I (1973) Participation in illegitimate activities: a theoretical and empirical investigation. J Polit Econ 81(3):521–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagan J, Freeman RB (1999) Crime and work. Crime Justice 25:225–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felson RB, Osgood DW, Cundiff PR, Wiernik C (2018) Life in the fast lane: drugs, hedonistic lifestyles, and economic crime. Crime Delinq 65:1292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleisher MS (1995) Beggars and thieves: Lives of urban street criminals. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman RB (1999) The economics of crime. In: Handbook of labor economics, vol 3, pp 3529–3571

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freedman D, Thornton A, Camburn D, Alwin D, Young-DeMarco L (1988) The life history calendar: a technique for collecting retrospective data. Sociol Methodol 18:37–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gottfredson MR, Hirschi T (1990) A general theory of crime. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grogger J (1998) Market wages and youth crime. J Labor Econ 16(4):756–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagan J, McCarthy B (1992) Streetlife and delinquency. Br J Sociol 43(4):533–561

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagan J, McCarthy B (1998) Mean streets: Youth crime and homelessness. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Heath C, Larrick RP, Wu G (1999) Goals as reference points. Cogn Psychol 38(1):79–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horney J, Marshall IH (1991) Measuring lambda through self-reports. Criminology 29(3):471–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horney J, Osgood DW, Marshall IH (1995) Criminal careers in the short-term: intra-individual variability in crime and its relation to local life circumstances. Am Sociol Rev 60:655–673

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson BA (1969) Outside the law: a thief’s primer. Transaction Books, New Brunswick, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs BA (2010) Deterrence and deterrability. Criminology 48(2):417–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs BA, Wright R (1999) Stick-up, street culture, and offender motivation. Criminology 37(1):149–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacques S, Wright R (2015) Code of the suburb: Inside the world of young middle-class drug dealers. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs BA, Topalli V, Wright R (2003) Carjacking, streetlife and offender motivation. Br J Criminol 43(4):673–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. In: MacLean LC, Ziemba WT (eds) Handbook in the fundamentals of decision making (Part 1, 2013. World Scientific, Singapore, pp 99–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz LF, Autor DA (1999) Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In: Ashenfelter OC, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1463–1555

    Google Scholar 

  • Keane M, Rogerson R (2015) Reconciling micro and macro labor supply elasticities: a structural perspective. Ann Rev Econ 7(1):89–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi B, Rabin M (2006) A model of reference-dependent preferences. Q J Econ 121(4):1133–1165

    Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi B, Rabin M (2007) Reference-dependent risk attitudes. Am Econ Rev 97(4):1047–1073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kruttschnitt C, Carbone-Lopez K (2006) Moving beyond the stereotypes: Women’s subjective accounts of their violent crime. Criminology 44(2):321–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis D, Mhlanga B (2001) A life of crime: the hidden truth about criminal activity. Int J Market Res 43(2):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran TA (2019) Behavioral criminology and public policy. Criminol Public Policy 18(4):737–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran TA, Nguyen H, Piquero AR, Fagan J (2013) The returns to criminal capital. Am Sociol Rev 78(6):925–948

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie DL, De Li S (2002) The impact of formal and informal social controls on the criminal activities of probationers. J Res Crime Delinq 39(3):243–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matza D, Sykes GM (1961) Juvenile delinquency and subterranean values. Am Sociol Rev 26(5):712–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy B, Hagan J (2001) When crime pays: Capital, competence, and criminal success. Soc Forces 79(3):1035–1060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer JA (1974) Schooling, experience, and earnings. Columbia University Press, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris NA, Slocum LA (2010) The validity of self-reported prevalence, frequency, and timing of arrest: an evaluation of data collected using a life event calendar. J Res Crime Delinq 47(2):210–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morselli C, Tremblay P (2010) Interviewing and validity issues in self-report research with incarcerated offenders: The Quebec Inmate Survey (2000–2001). In: Bernasco W (ed) Offenders on offending: learning about crime from offenders. Willan, New York, pp 68–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Morselli C, Tremblay P (2004) Criminal achievement, offender networks and the benefits of low self-control. Criminology 42(3):773–804

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morselli C, Tremblay P, McCarthy B (2006) Mentors and criminal achievement. Criminology 44(1):17–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers SL (1983) Estimating the economic model of crime: Employment versus punishment effects. Q J Econ 98(1):157–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin DS, Smith DA (1990) Participation in and frequency of delinquent behavior: a test for structural differences. J Quant Criminol 6(4):335–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen H, Kamada T, Ramakers A (2020) On the margins: considering the relationship between informal work and reoffending. Justice Q 5:1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen H, Loughran TA (2017) On the reliability and validity of self-reported illegal earnings: implications for the study of criminal achievement. Criminology 55(3):575–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ouellet F (2018) Stop and go: explaining the timing of intermittency in criminal careers. Crime and Delinquency 65:630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ouellet F, Bouchard M (2017) Only a matter of time? The role of criminal competence in avoiding arrest. Justice Q 34(4):699–726

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paternoster R (2010) How much do we really know about criminal deterrence? J Crim Law Criminol 100:765–824

    Google Scholar 

  • Paternoster R, Bushway SD (2009) Desistance and the ‘feared self’: toward an identity theory of criminal desistance. J Crim Law Criminol 99(4):1109–1156

    Google Scholar 

  • Pezzin LE (1995) Earning prospects, matching effects, and the decision to terminate a criminal career. J Quant Criminol 11(1):29–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero A (2000) Frequency, specialization, and violence in offending careers. J Res Crime Delinq 37(4):392–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pogarsky G (2002) Identifying “deterrable” offenders: Implications for research on deterrence. Justice Q 19(3):431–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pogarsky G, Roche SP, Pickett JT (2018) Offender decision-making in criminology: contributions from behavioral economics. Ann Rev Criminol 1:379–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reppetto TA (1974) Residential crime. Ballinger Publishing Company, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Reuter PH, MacCoun RJ, Murphy P, Abrahamse A, Simon B (1990) Money from crime: a study of the economics of drug dealing in Washington, D.C. Rand Corporation, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts J, Mulvey EP, Horney J, Lewis J, Arter ML (2005) A test of two methods of recall for violent events. J Quant Criminol 21(2):175–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sampson RJ, Laub JH (1993) Crime in the making: pathways and turning points through life. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Scarr HA, Pinsky JL, Wyatt DS (1973) Patterns of Burglary. National Institute of Law Enforcement and Criminal Justice, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Schubert CA, Mulvey EP, Steinberg L, Cauffman E, Losoya SH, Hecker T, Chassin L, Knight GP (2004) Operational lessons from the pathways to desistance project. Youth Violence Juv Justice 2(3):237–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw CR (1930) The jack-roller: a delinquent boy’s own story. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Shover N (1996) Aging criminals: changes in the criminal calculus. In: Cromwell P (ed) Their own words: criminals on crime. Roxbury Publishing Company, Los Angeles, pp 57–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Shover N, Thompson CY (1992) Age, differential expectations, and crime desistance. Criminology 30(1):89–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sjoquist DL (1973) Property crime and economic behavior: Some empirical results. Am Econ Rev 63(3):439–446

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith DA, Visher CA, Jarjoura GR, O’Leary V (1991) Dimensions of delinquency: exploring the correlates of participation, frequency, and persistence of delinquent behavior. J Res Crime Delinq 28(1):6–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steffensmeier DJ (1986) The fence: In the shadow of two worlds. Rowman and Littlefield, Totowa

    Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan ML (1989) “Getting paid”: Youth crime and work in the inner city. Cornell University Press, Ithica

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH (1999) Mental accounting matters. J Behav Decis Mak 12(3):183–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas KJ (2015) Delinquent peer influence on offending versatility: can peers promote specialized delinquency? Criminology 53(2):280–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson M, Uggen C (2012) Dealers, thieves, and the common determinants of drug and nondrug illegal earnings. Criminology 50(4):1057–1087

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tremblay P, Morselli C (2000) Patterns in criminal achievement: Wilson and Abrahamse revisited. Criminology 38(2):633–657

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tunnell KD (1992) Choosing crime: the criminal calculus of property offenders. Nelson-Hall Publishers, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Uggen C (2000) Work as a turning point in the life course of criminals: a duration model of age, employment, and recidivism. Am Sociol Rev 65(4):529–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uggen C, Thompson M (2003) The socioeconomic determinants of ill-gotten gains: within-person changes in drug use and illegal earnings. Am J Sociol 109(1):146–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Weele TJ, Ding P (2017) Sensitivity analysis in observational research: introducing the E-value. Ann Intern Med 167(4):268–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Gerwen N, Blokland A, Rijken AJ (2019) Assessing the accuracy of life event calendar data in an offender sample. Justice Q 36(3):532–566

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi WK (1986) The risks and rewards of criminal activity: a comprehensive test of criminal deterrence. J Labor Econ 4(3, Part 1):317–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitbeck LB, Hoyt DR, Yoder KA (1999) A risk-amplification model of victimization and depressive symptoms among runaway and homeless adolescents. Am J Community Psychol 27(2):273–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams T (1989) The cocaine kids: the inside story of a teenage drug ring. Addison-Wesley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson JQ, Abrahamse A (1992) Does crime pay? Justice Q 9(3):359–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittebrood K, Nieuwbeerta P (2000) Criminal victimization during one’s life course: The effects of previous victimization and patterns of routine activities. J Res Crime Delinq 37(1):91–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright RT, Decker SH (1994) Burglars on the job: Streetlife and residential break-ins. Northeastern University Press, Boston, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright R, Decker SH (1997) Armed robbers in action: stickups and street culture. University Press of New England, Lebanon

    Google Scholar 

  • Yacoubian GS Jr (2003) Assessing the efficacy of the calendar method with Oklahoma City arrestees. J Crime Justice 26(1):117–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoshihama M, Gillespie B, Hammock AC, Belli RF, Tolman RM (2005) Does the life history calendar method facilitate the recall of intimate partner violence? Comparison of two methods of data collection. Social Work Res 29(3):151–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Richard Felson, Sue-Ming Yang and the anonymous reveiwers for their thoughtful comments on prior versions of this manuscript. On a special note, we would like to dedicate this manuscript to Carlo Morselli, who was a pioneer in the study of criminal achievement and the social organization of illegal markets. Carlo's creativeness, tenacity and investment in mentoring has inspired countless indviduals.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Holly Nguyen.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

See Table 8.

Table 8 Panel models predicting illegal labor supply—lagged criminal efficiency (Robust Standard Errors)

Appendix B

Pathways to Desistance and National Supported Work Measures

Pathway Measures

Frequency of Offending Subjects reported the frequency in which they engaged in income-generating crime during the recall period. Income-generating crimes include shoplifting, buying/receiving/selling stolen property, using checks/credit cards illegally, stealing a car or motorcycle, selling marijuana, selling other drugs, stealing something worth more than $100, entering a building to steal, taking something by force using a weapon, and taking something by force with no weapon.

Illegal Earnings Participants were asked, “Have you made money in other ways over the past N months, including from activities that are illegal?” If the respondent answered in the affirmative, the interviewer asked a follow-up question: “You mentioned that you had made money during the past N months from ways besides working. Did you make any money during this month from activities that are illegal?” For each month in which subjects engaged in any illegal work, they were asked to specify the amount of money per week they earned from all illegal activities during that month.

Criminal Efficiency was measured as the average payoff per crime, calculated by dividing total illegal earnings by the total number of crimes committed each month in which offenders were active.

Legal Job The legal employment variable was derived from a life-event calendar, which recorded detailed information regarding the total number of weeks each subject spent in legitimate employment and under-the-table legal work. This information was then aggregated across each observation period. If the respondent reported any time in legitimate employment in the recall period, s/he was coded as being involved in legal work in the recall period.

Street Time Is the proportion of time the respondent was not in a secure facility.

Specialization we consider the unique number of crime types reported by an individual in the observation period and generate an indicator equal to 1 if the individual reported engaging in one unique crime types during the observation period and 0 if otherwise.

Drug Use Because drug dependency is associated with increased illegal earnings and an “earnings imperative” (Uggen and Thompson 2003), we include a binary indicator if the respondent reported using.

National Supported Work (NSW)

Frequency of Offending Respondents were asked how many times they had engaged in income-generating crime during the 9-month recall period with a mean frequency of 29.6.

Illegal Earnings after answering questions about illegal weekly wages, respondents were asked, “About how much money altogether would you say you made illegally since the month of assignment?” Respondents reported a mean of $14,500 illegal earnings over a 9-month period.

Criminal Efficiency was measured as the average payoff per crime, calculated by dividing total illegal earnings by the total number of crimes committed each month in which offenders were active.

Legal Job This variable reflects the total number of hours the respondent worked across all legal jobs in the recall period. On average, respondents spent 57 h doing legal work over the 9-month period.

Street Time Is a variable that indicates the proportion of time the respondent was not incarcerated.

Specialization Is a measure that indicates that the respondent engaged in only one type of offense.

Drug Use Is a binary measure that = 1 if the respondent reported using illicit drugs and 0 = if the respondent abstained from using illicit drugs.

Appendix C

See Table 9.

Table 9 Description of pathways and national supported work samples

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nguyen, H., Loughran, T.A., Morselli, C. et al. Offending Frequency and Responses to Illegal Monetary Incentives. J Quant Criminol 38, 239–265 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-021-09492-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-021-09492-y

Keywords

Navigation