Skip to main content
Log in

The Effects of Corruption in a Monetary Union

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

    We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

    Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

Abstract

72% of Europeans in European Monetary Union countries think that corruption is widespread in their country. Corruption can affect the individual country’s performance and, in turn, impact on the performance of the other members of the monetary union. In this article, we will present a monetary union composed of two countries and we will study how the presence of corruption in one member country will affect its economy and the neighbour’s economy. Additionally, we will analyse what measures could reduce the negative spillover effects generated by the presence of corruption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A detailed derivation of Expressions (1) and (2) is given at the beginning of the Appendix.

  2. Many articles include seigniorage as a source of revenue (see Huang and Wei 2006, for example, for developing economies). We decided not to introduce seigniorage in our model because in the European Monetary Union such revenues are considerably small. According to Gross (2004), for the euro area as a whole, seigniorage represents less than one quarter of 1% of GDP, or less than one-half of 1% of government revenues.

  3. We thank an anonymous referee for this comment.

  4. Further, the performance of tax authorities is affected by the costs of tax collection. When revenue collection costs are high, the governments are able to use less of the resources collected. According to the OECD (2015), the average cost of tax collection in the EU was €0.97 per 100 units of revenue in 2013. Some of the European Monetary Union (EMU) countries like Slovakia and Germany stand out with collection costs above 1% of the total revenue collected.

  5. Following the related literature − see Alesina and Tabellini (1987), Debelle and Fischer (1994), Alesina and Stella (2010), among others - we assume that the inflation target of the authorities has been normalised to zero. However, as the European Central Bank inflation target is below 2%, it is worth pointing out that the results would not be qualitatively altered by assuming a positive inflation target.

  6. We thank an anonymous referee for very helpful comments in this section.

  7. A similar analysis could be performed assuming a reduction in the relative weight associated to public spending in country 1.

  8. \( \hat{\gamma_1} \) is implicitly determined in the Appendix.

References

  • Acocella N, Di Bartolomeo G, Tirelli P (2007a) Monetary conservatism and fiscal coordination in a monetary union. Econ Lett 94:56–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acocella N, Di Bartolomeo G, Tirelli P (2007b) Fiscal leadership and coordination in the EMU. Open Econ Rev 18:281–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Stella A (2010) The politics of monetary policy. In Benjamin M. Friedman & Michael Woodford (ed.), Handbook of Monetary Economics 3(18). Elsevier, pp 1001-1054

  • Alesina A, Tabellini G (1987) Rules and discretion with noncoordinated monetary and fiscal policies. Econ Inq 25:619–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma RMWJ, Bovenberg LA (1997) Central bank independence and public debt policy. J Econ Dyn Control 21:873–894

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma RMWJ, Bovenberg LA (1998) Monetary union without fiscal coordination may discipline policymakers. J Int Econ 45:239–258

  • Beetsma RMWJ, Bovenberg LA (2001) The optimality of a monetary union without a fiscal union. J Money Credit Bank 33:179–204

  • Beetsma RMWJ, Giuliodori M (2010) The macroeconomic costs and benefits of the EMU and other monetary unions: an overview of recent research. J Econ Lit 48:603–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campos N, Dimova R, Saleh A (2010) Whither corruption? A quantitative survey of the literature on corruption and growth, CEPR discussion paper no. 8140, London

  • De Grauwe P (2000) Monetary policies in the presence of asymmetries. J Common Mark Stud 38:593–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debelle G, Fischer S (1994) How independent should central banks be? In Goals, guidelines and constraints facing monetary policymakers (ed. Jeffrey C. Fuhrer), Federal Reserve Bank, Boston, MA

  • Dimakou O (2015) Bureaucratic corruption and the dynamic interaction between monetary and fiscal policy. Eur J Political Econ 40:57–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2001) Monetary-fiscal policy interactions and commitment versus discretion in a monetary union. Eur Econ Rev 45:977–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2003) Interactions of commitment and discretion in monetary and fiscal policies. Am Econ Rev 93:1522–1542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2020) Special Eurobarometer 502, Corruption Report, June 2020. https://doi.org/10.2837/91891

  • Foresti P (2018) Monetary and fiscal policies interaction in monetary unions. J Econ Surv 32:226–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gross D (2004) Profiting from the euro? Seigniorage gains from euro area accession. J Common Mark Stud 42:795–813

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gründler K, Potrafke N (2019) Corruption and economic growth: new empirical evidence. Eur J Political Econ 60:101810. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2019.08.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hefeker C (2010) Taxation, corruption and the exchange rate regime. J Macroecon 32:338–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hefeker C, Zimmer B (2011) Uncertainty and fiscal policy in an asymmetric monetary union. Open Econ Rev 22:163–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang H, Wei SJ (2006) Monetary policies for developing countries: the role of institutional quality. J Int Econ 70:239–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. Q J Econ 110:681–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mo P (2001) Corruption and economic growth. J Comp Econ 29:66–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2015) Tax administration 2015: comparative information on OECD and other advanced and emerging economies, OECD publishing, Paris.

  • Scheve K (2004) Public inflation aversion and the political economy of macroeconomic policymaking. Int Organ 58:1–34

  • Transparency International (2018) Corruption Perceptions Index 2018

  • Ugur M (2014) Corruption's direct effects on per-capita income growth: a meta-analysis. J Econ Surv 28:472–490

Download references

Funding

We acknowledge financial support from Ministerio de Ciencia, Innovación y Universidades (PID2019-105982GB-I00/AEI/10.13039/501100011033). Universitat Rovira i Virgili and Generalitat de Catalunya (2019PFR-URV-B2–53 and 2017 SGR 770).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Ferré, Montserrat and Manzano, Carolina (2020): “Independent Central Banks: Low Inflation at no Cost? A Model with Fiscal Policy”, International Journal of Central Banking, 16, 233-286.

Ferré, Montserrat, García, Judit and Manzano, Carolina (2018): “Tax Efficiency, Seigniorage and Central Bank Conservativeness”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 56, 2018–230.

De Frutos, M. Ángeles and Manzano, Carolina (2014): “Market Transparency, Market Quality, and Sunshine Trading”, Journal of Financial Markets, 17, 174–198.

Ferré, Montserrat and Manzano, Carolina (2014): “Rational Partisan Theory with fiscal policy and an independent central bank”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 42, 27–37.

Ferré, Montserrat and Manzano, Carolina (2013): “Central Bank Coordinated Intervention: a Microstructure Approach”, European Journal of Finance, 19, 113–126.

Ferré, M. (2012), “The effects of uncertainty about countries’ compliance with the Stability and Growth Pact”, Journal of Policy Modeling vol. 34, 660–674.

Manzano, Carolina and Vives, Xavier (2011): “Public and Private Learning from Prices, Strategic Substitutability and Complementarity, and Equilibrium Multiplicity”, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 47, 3, 346–369.

Ramajo, J. and M. Ferré (2010), “Purchasing Power Parity Revisited: Evidence from old and new tests for an OECD panel”, Applied Economics, vol. 42, 2243–2260.

Ferré, Montserrat and Manzano, Carolina (2009): “When do central banks prefer to intervene secretly?”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, 14, 378–393.

Ferré, M. (2008), “Fiscal Policy Coordination in the EMU”, Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 30, 221–235.

Ramajo, J., A. García and M. Ferré (2007) “The Effects of Public Expenditure on Private Consumption: A Disaggregated Analysis for Spain (1970-1997)”, International Economic Journal, vol. 21, 115–131.

Ramajo, J., A. García and M. Ferré (2006), “Explaining Aggregate Private Saving Behaviour: New Evidence from a Panel of OECD countries”, Applied Financial Economics Letters, 2, 311–315.

Ferré, M. (2005), “Should Fiscal Authorities Co-operate in a Monetary Union with Public Deficit Targets?”, Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 43, no. 3, pp. 539–550.

De Frutos, M. Ángeles and Manzano, Carolina (2005): “Trade disclosure and price dispersion”, Journal of Financial Markets, 8, 183–216.

Manzano, Carolina (2002): “The effect of the transparency of order flows in a dealer market with several securities”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, 11 (2), 212–227.

Ferré, M. and S.G. Hall (2002), “Foreign Exchange Market Efficiency and Cointegration”, Applied Financial Economics, 12, 131–139.

De Frutos, M. Ángeles and Manzano, Carolina (2002): “Risk aversion, transparency and market perfomance”, Journal of Finance, 57 (2), 959–984.

Manzano, Carolina (1999): “Price-signal relations in an imperfectly competitive financial market with public and private information”, Journal of Accounting Research, 37(2), 451–464.

Manzano, Carolina (1998): “The structure of the set of critical equilibria in an incomplete financial markets framework”, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 30, 147–173.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Montserrat Ferre.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

We initially derive the expressions for output and public spending for country 1. To ease the notation we omit the subscript 1 in the following two proofs.

Derivation of Expression (1).

Output of a representative firm is given by X = Lλ, where X denotes the real output, L represents labour and λ indicates the output elasticity. Distortionary taxes are levied on production. The firm maximises profit, given by: (1 − τ)PLλ − WL, where τ denotes the tax rate on total revenue of firms, P represents the price level and W is the nominal wage. Solving for the firm’s labour demand, assuming it can hire the labour it demands at the given nominal wage, taking logs, we have x = a(p − τ − w) + b, where lower-case letters denote logs of nominal variables, a = λ/(1 − λ), b = λ ln λ/(1 − λ), and ln (1 − τ) ≈  − τ. Following Debelle and Fischer (1994), for simplicity, we set λ = 0.5, so that a = 1 and we approximate ln λ to 0. Hence, x = p − τ − w.

In addition, following Alesina and Tabellini (1987), Debelle and Fischer (1994) and Beetsma and Bovenberg (2001), among others, we assume that workers are represented by a centralised trade union, which sets nominal wage (in logs) and it has the following objective function: E((w − p)2)/2. The first order condition of this optimisation problem immediately yields w = pe. Therefore, x = p − pe − τ. Finally, approximating p − pe by π − πe, where π represents the inflation rate and πe the expected inflation rate, we get the aggregate supply equation of the model, i.e., x = π − πe − τ.

Derivation of Expression (2).

The government budget constraint in nominal terms is given by PtGt = ϕτtPtXt, where Gt denotes public spending and ϕ the degree of institutional quality. Dividing the government budget constraint by nominal income, PtXt, yields gt = ϕτt, where gt is public spending as a share of Xt.

Proof of Proposition 1.

Substituting Expressions (1), (2) and (3) into (4) and (5), it follows that

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{L}_1=\frac{1}{2}\left[{\pi}^2+{\delta}_1{\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_1-{\overline{x}}_1\right)}^2+{\gamma}_1{\left({\phi \tau}_1-{\overline{g}}_1\right)}^2\right]\\ {}{L}_2=\frac{1}{2}\left[{\pi}^2+{\delta}_2{\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_2-{\overline{x}}_2\right)}^2+{\gamma}_2{\left({\tau}_2-{\overline{g}}_2\right)}^2\right],\mathrm{and}\\ {}{L}_{CCB}=\frac{1}{2}\left[{\pi}^2+{\delta}_{CCB}{\left(z\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_1\right)+\left(1-z\right)\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_2\right)-\left(z{\overline{x}}_1+\left(1-z\right){\overline{x}}_2\right)\right)}^2\right].\end{array}} $$

The first-order conditions of the fiscal authorities’ optimisation problems are given by

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\frac{{\partial L}_1}{{\partial \tau}_1}=-{\delta}_1\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_1-{\overline{x}}_1\right)+{\phi \gamma}_1\left({\phi \tau}_1-{\overline{g}}_1\right)=0,\mathrm{and}\ \\ {}\frac{{\partial L}_2}{{\partial \tau}_2}=-{\delta}_2\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_2-{\overline{x}}_2\right)+{\gamma}_2\left({\tau}_2-{\overline{g}}_2\right)=0.\end{array}} $$

Hence,

$$ {\tau}_1=\frac{{\overline{g}}_1}{\phi }-\frac{\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}{\phi \left({\phi}^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)}\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)+\frac{\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}{\phi^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}\left(\pi -{\pi}^e\right),\mathrm{and} $$
(17)
$$ {\tau}_2={\overline{g}}_2-\frac{\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)+\frac{\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}\left(\pi -{\pi}^e\right). $$
(18)

For the central bank, the first-order condition of its optimisation problem implies that

$$ \frac{\partial {L}_{CCB}}{\partial \pi }=\pi +{\delta}_{CCB}\left(z\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_1\right)+\left(1-z\right)\left(\pi -{\pi}^e-{\tau}_2\right)-\left(z{\overline{x}}_1+\left(1-z\right){\overline{x}}_2\right)\right)=0. $$

Thus,

$$ \pi =\frac{\delta_{CCB}}{1+{\delta}_{CCB}}\left({\pi}^e+z\left({\tau}_1+{\overline{x}}_1\right)+\left(1-z\right)\left({\tau}_2+{\overline{x}}_2\right)\right). $$
(19)

Plugging Expressions (17) and (18) into (19), it follows that

$$ \pi =\frac{z\frac{\phi^2}{\phi^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}+\left(1-z\right)\frac{1}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}}{\Delta}{\pi}^e+z\frac{\phi }{\left({\phi}^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)\Delta}\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)+\left(1-z\right)\frac{1}{\left(1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}\right)\Delta}\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right), $$
(20)

where \( \Delta =\frac{1}{\delta_{CCB}}+z\frac{\phi^2}{\phi^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}+\left(1-z\right)\frac{1}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}} \). Using the rational expectation hypothesis, we know that π  =  πe. Then, from (20), (17) and (18), we obtain Expressions (7)–(9).

Proof of Corollary 2.

We differentiate the expressions for output (Eqs. 10 and 11), public spending (Eqs. 12 and 13) and inflation (Eq. 9) with respect to ϕ. Therefore, we obtain the following expressions:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{x}_1^{\ast }=-\frac{2\phi \frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}{\overline{x}}_1+\left(\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}-{\phi}^2\right){\overline{g}}_1}{{\left({\phi}^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)}^2},\frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{g}_1^{\ast }=\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\frac{\left({\phi}^2-\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right){\overline{x}}_1+2\phi {\overline{g}}_1}{{\left({\phi}^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)}^2},\\ {}\frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{\pi}^{\ast }=z{\delta}_{CCB}\frac{2\phi \frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}{\overline{x}}_1+\left(\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}-{\phi}^2\right){\overline{g}}_1}{{\left({\phi}^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)}^2},\mathrm{and}\\ {}\frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{x}_2^{\ast }=\frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{g}_2^{\ast }=0.\end{array}} $$

Hence, \( \frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{x}_1^{\ast }>0\ \mathrm{and}\ \frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{\pi}^{\ast }<0 \) if and only if \( {\gamma}_1>{\overline{\gamma}}_1 \), where the expression of \( {\overline{\gamma}}_1 \) is given in the statement of this corollary. Finally, taking into account the assumption that \( \frac{{\overline{x}}_1}{{\overline{g}}_1}<\frac{\phi {\gamma}_1}{\delta_1} \), we can conclude that \( \frac{\partial }{\partial \phi }{g}_1^{\ast }>0 \).

Proof of Corollary 3.

a) Substituting Expressions (9), (10) and (12) into (4) for country 1 and differentiating the resulting expression with respect to ϕ, we have

$$ \frac{\partial {L}_1^{\ast }}{\partial \phi }={\gamma}_1\frac{p\left({\gamma}_1\right)}{{\left({\delta}_1+{\phi}^2{\gamma}_1\right)}^3\left(\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}+1\right)}, $$

where \( p\left({\gamma}_1\right)={p}_2{\gamma}_1^2+{p}_1{\gamma}_1+{p}_0 \), with

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{p}_2=-\left(z\left(1-z\right){\phi}^4{\delta}_{CCB}^2{\overline{g}}_1\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)+{\phi}^3\left({z}^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2+{\delta}_1\right)\left(1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}\right)\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right){\overline{g}}_1\right),\\ {}{p}_1=2z\left(1-z\right){\phi}^3{\delta}_1{\delta}_{CCB}^2{\overline{x}}_1\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)+\phi {\updelta}_1\left({\updelta}_1\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1-{\overline{g}}_1\right)+{z}^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2\left(2\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)\right)\left(1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}\right)\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right),\mathrm{and}\ \\ {}{p}_0=z\left(1-z\right){\delta}_1^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2\left(2\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)+{\delta}_1^3\left(1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}\right)\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right){\overline{x}}_1.\end{array}} $$

Notice that p2 < 0 and p0 > 0 . This allows us to guarantee that there exists a unique positive root of the polynomial p(γ1), denoted by \( {\overset{\sim }{\gamma}}_1 \). Hence, we can conclude that \( \frac{\partial {L}_1^{\ast }}{\partial \phi }<0 \) if and only if \( {\gamma}_1>{\overset{\sim }{\gamma}}_1 \). Moreover, in order to show that

$$ {\overline{\gamma}}_1>{\overset{\sim }{\gamma}}_1 $$
(21)

it suffices to prove that \( p\left({\overline{\gamma}}_1\right)<0 \). Direct computations yield \( p\left({\overline{\gamma}}_1\right)=-2{\delta}_1^3\frac{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}{\phi {\overline{g}}_1}{\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)}^3<0\ \mathrm{and} \), hence, (21) is satisfied.

b) Taking into account that the output and public spending of country 2 are not affected by the level of corruption in country 1, we have that \( \frac{\partial {L}_2^{\ast }}{\partial \phi }={\pi}^{\ast}\frac{\partial {\pi}^{\ast }}{\partial \phi } \). Combining the positiveness of π and Corollary 2, it follows that \( \frac{\partial {L}_2^{\ast }}{\partial \phi }<0 \) if and only if \( {\gamma}_1>{\overline{\gamma}}_1 \).

Proof of Corollary 4.

Note that country 2 has the same losses whether there is corruption in country 1 or not if \( {L}_2^{\ast}\left(\phi \right)-{L}_2^{\ast }(1)=0. \) Using Expression (4) for country 2 and Corollary 2c, the previous equality is equivalent to

$$ \frac{1}{2}{\left({\pi}^{\ast}\left(\phi \right)\right)}^2-\frac{1}{2}{\left({\pi}^{\ast }(1)\right)}^2=0, $$

and, hence, π(ϕ) = π(1). Using Expression (9), the previous equality can be rewritten as

$$ z\frac{\phi {\delta}_{CCB}}{\phi^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1^R\right)+\left(1-z\right)\frac{\delta_{CCB}}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)=z\frac{\delta_{CCB}}{1+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}\left({\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)+\left(1-z\right)\frac{\delta_{CCB}}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right). $$

Isolating the value of \( {\overline{g}}_1^R \), it follows that \( {\overline{g}}_1^R=\frac{\phi^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}{\phi \left(1+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)}\left({\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)-\phi {\overline{x}}_1 \), which can be rewritten as \( {\overline{g}}_1^R={\overline{g}}_1-\Psi \), where the expression of Ψ is given in the statement of this corollary.

Proof of Corollary 5.

Using the expression of Ψ, we get that

$$ {L}_1^{\ast}\left(\Psi \right)-{L}_1^{\ast }(0)=\frac{\phi {\gamma}_1\Psi}{2\left({\delta}_1+{\gamma}_1\right){\left({\delta}_1+{\phi}^2{\gamma}_1\right)}^2\left({\delta}_2+{\gamma}_2\right)}l\left({\gamma}_1\right), $$

where \( l\left({\gamma}_1\right)={l}_3{\gamma}_1^3+{l}_2{\gamma}_1^2+{l}_1{\gamma}_1+{l}_0, \) with

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{l}_3=\left(1-\phi \right){\phi}^3\left({\delta}_2+{\gamma}_2\right){\overline{g}}_1,\\ {}{l}_2=\phi \left[\left({\left(1-\phi \right)}^2{\delta}_1{\overline{g}}_1-\left(1+\phi \right){z}^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2{\overline{g}}_1-\left(\left(1-{\phi}^2\right){\delta}_1+2{z}^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2\right)\phi {\overline{x}}_1\right)\left({\delta}_2+{\gamma}_2\right)-2\phi z\left(1-z\right){\gamma}_2{\delta}_{CCB}^2\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)\right],\\ {}\begin{array}{c}{l}_1=-{\delta}_1\Big[\left(\left(1-\phi \right)\left(\left(1+\phi \right){\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right){\delta}_1+{z}^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2\left(\left(1+{\phi}^2\right){\overline{x}}_1+\left(1+\phi \right){\overline{g}}_1\right)\right)\left({\delta}_2+{\gamma}_2\right)\\ {}\begin{array}{c}+2\left(1+{\phi}^2\right)z\left(1-z\right){\gamma}_2{\updelta}_{CCB}^2\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right)\Big],\mathrm{and}\\ {}{l}_0=-2z\left(1-z\right){\delta}_1^2{\gamma}_2{\delta}_{CCB}^2\left({\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2\right).\end{array}\end{array}\end{array}} $$

Note that \( l\left({\delta}_1\frac{\left(1+\phi \right){\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1}{\phi {\overline{g}}_1}\right)<0 \) and limγ1 ⟶ ∞l(γ1) > 0. Then, applying the Descartes’ rule, we can conclude that there exists a unique value of γ1, denoted by \( \hat{\gamma_1} \), that satisfies \( {L}_1^{\ast}\left(\Psi \right)-{L}_1^{\ast }(0)=0. \) Moreover, we know that \( \hat{\gamma_1}\in \left({\delta}_1\frac{\left(1+\phi \right){\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1}{\phi {\overline{g}}_1},\infty \right) \). Therefore, if \( {\gamma}_1<\hat{\gamma_1} \), country 1 is better off with its required public spending target. Otherwise, if \( {\gamma}_1>\hat{\gamma_1} \), country 1 is worse off with its required target.

Proof of Corollary 6.

Using the expression of Ψ, it follows that the inequality \( {L}_1^{\ast}\left(\Psi \right)>{L}_1^{NM\ast } \) is equivalent to \( \frac{\phi^2{\left(1-\phi \right)}^2{\gamma}_1^2{\overline{g}}_1^2}{\left({\delta}_1+{\phi}^2{\gamma}_1\right){\left({\delta}_1+{\gamma}_1\right)}^2}{\left({\gamma}_1-{\delta}_1\frac{\left(1+\phi \right){\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1}{\phi {\overline{g}}_1}\right)}^2>\frac{\phi^2{\delta}_{CCB}^2}{{\left({\phi}^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}\right)}^2}{\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)}^2-{\left(z\frac{\delta_{CCB}}{1+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}\left({\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right)+\left(1-z\right){\delta}_{CCB}\frac{{\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}\right)}^2. \)

Note that if γ1 is high enough, the previous inequality is satisfied and, consequently, in this case country 1 prefers to leave the monetary union. By contrast, if \( {\gamma}_1=\hat{\gamma_1} \), then \( {L}_1^{\ast}\left(\Psi \right)={L}_1^{\ast }(0) \). It is easy to see that this value is lower than \( {L}_1^{NM\ast } \) whenever \( \frac{{\overline{x}}_2+{\overline{g}}_2}{1+\frac{\delta_2}{\gamma_2}}<\frac{\phi }{\phi^2+\frac{\delta_1}{\gamma_1}}\left(\phi {\overline{x}}_1+{\overline{g}}_1\right). \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ferre, M., Garcia, J. & Manzano, C. The Effects of Corruption in a Monetary Union. Open Econ Rev 32, 539–557 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-020-09608-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-020-09608-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation