Skip to main content
Log in

Will quadratic voting produce optimal public policy?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Under quadratic voting people are able to buy votes with money. The claims that rational voters will make efficient electoral choices rest on assumptions about how voters acquire and share information. Specifically, that all voters share common knowledge about the probability that any one of them will be the decisive voter, but do not (appear to) share knowledge in any specialized way within special interest groups. This paper asserts that quadratic voting is no more likely to promote efficiency than the current system of one-person-one-vote. Information costs are critical. If information is costly, organized interest groups on either side of an issue provide low-cost information to their members and sharing common knowledge across groups is less likely. Then, small differences lead to large welfare losses. If information is free, special-interest groups provide opportunities for collusion that undermines the efficiency of quadratic voting. Even if collusion could be prevented, the dual uses of money to buy votes and to disseminate information organizes interest groups as if their members were colluding. The role of information and the fact that voting is not costless create efficiency biases under quadratic voting that favor political organization and concentrated values. To the extent that these attributes are overrepresented in the present system, quadratic voting will only make it worse.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A generalization of this finding is proposed by Tideman and Plassmann (2017), who argue that no social choice mechanism is likely to be efficient unless “all parties involved … bear the marginal social costs of their actions.”

  2. Weights depend on the distribution of benefits within the group.

  3. Some of the problems, including collusion and voter misinformation are discussed by Weyl (2017).

  4. Without equilibria, the idea of efficiency is moot.

  5. From Eq. (1) and consistent with free riding in large groups, we know that λ will be very small. For visual effect, we have assumed that\(\lambda^{P} = 1/4\) and \(\lambda^{O} = 1/2\), since only the ratio matters in determining the political outcome, Qe.

  6. It can be shown that Xi = M/N maximizes \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {X_{i}^{{\frac{1}{2}}} }\), subject to \(M = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {X_{i} }\) for all i.

  7. Let m=M/N be the optimal allocation of M within an interest group and consider any unequal distribution m+δ and m − δ (0<δ<m) between two members. Collusive allocation of m yields \(2\sqrt m\) votes for the two individuals and the alternative allocation yields \(\sqrt {m + \delta } + \sqrt {m - \delta }\) votes. Collusion then gains \(G = 2\sqrt m - \sqrt {m + \delta } - \sqrt {m - \delta } > 0\) votes and the amount of votes gained by collusion increases with increases in variation, δ, because \(\partial G/\partial \delta = 2\delta (m^{2} - \delta^{2} )^{{ - \frac{1}{2}}} > 0\).

References

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, J. C., & Porter, P. K. (1985). Majority voting and Pareto optimality. Public Choice, 46(2), 173–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, J. C., & Porter, P. K. (1988). A theory of competitive regulatory equilibrium. Public Choice, 59(1), 51–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, J. C., & Porter, P. K. (2004). Political equilibrium and the provision of public goods. Public Choice, 120(3–4), 247–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harberger, A. C. (1954). Monopoly and resource allocation. American Economic Review, 44(2), 77–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lalley, S.P. & Weyl, E.G. (2018). Quadratic voting: How mechanism design can radicalize democracy. American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings. http://aeaweb.org.

  • Posner, E. A. & Weyl, E. G. (2013). Quadratic voting as efficient capital governance. The University of Chicago, Institute for Law and Economics. http://www.lawuchicago.edu/Lawecon/index.html.

  • Posner, E. A., & Weyl, E. G. (2017). Special issue: Quadratic voting and the public good. Public Choice, 172(1–2), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, E. A., & Weyl, E. G. (2019). Radical markets: Uprooting capitalism and democracy for a just society. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, N., & Plassmann, F. (2017). Efficient collective decision-making, marginal cost pricing, and quadratic voting. Public Choice, 172(1–2), 45–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weyl, E. G. (2017). The robustness of quadratic voting. Public Choice, 172(1–2), 75–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Philip K. Porter.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Goodman, J.C., Porter, P.K. Will quadratic voting produce optimal public policy?. Public Choice 186, 141–148 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00767-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00767-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation