Skip to main content
Log in

Farmers Follow the Herd: A Theoretical Model on Social Norms and Payments for Environmental Services

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The economic literature on Payments for Environmental Services (PES) has studied extensively the behavioural factors that prevent farmers from signing PES contracts, even when the payments exceed the expected opportunity costs. This article provides a theoretical model of the role played by the interplay of descriptive and injunctive social norms in farmers’ decisions. When they choose to contribute voluntarily to an environmental public good, farmers may be driven by descriptive norms akin to conformity (do as the majority of their peers) as well as by injunctive norms (in line with what society expects them to do), which are the equivalent of a social injunction to act in favour of the environment. The interactions between these two social norms can yield multiple equilibria, depending on the relative weight of the descriptive norm (sensitivity to conformism) and of the injunctive norm (sensitivity to moral pressure) in the utility functions of farmers. More generally, our model can explain why social groups are sometimes trapped in low public-good-contribution equilibria, even when public subsidies to contributors are high. We make policy recommendations to help reach higher contribution equilibria, with a specific focus on the farm policy context.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We will henceforth use the acronym PES as a generic term for these contracts.

  2. When \( p = c + 2\lambda \), \( x^{\prime } = 0 \) so the Nash equilibrium \( e = x^{\prime } \) is actually the polar Nash equilibrium \( e = 0 \). Thus we have only two Nash equilibria in that case.

References

  • Abbott A, Nandeibam S, O’Shea L (2013) Recycling: social norms and warm-glow revisited. Ecol Econ 90:10–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ajzen I (1991) The theory of planned behavior. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 50:179–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allaire G, Cahuzac E, Simioni M (2009) Contractualisation etdiffusionspatiale des mesures agro-environnementales herbagères. Revue d’Etudes en Agriculture et Environnement 90:23–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allcott H (2011) Social norms and energy conservation. J Public Econ 95:1082–1095

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronson E, Wilson TD, Akert RM, Sommers S (2018) Social psychology, 9th edn. Pearson, London, p 621

    Google Scholar 

  • Asheim GB (2010) Strategic use of environmental information. Environ Resour Econ 46:207–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beedell J, Rehman T (2000) Using social-psychology models to understand farmers’ conservation behaviour. J Rural Stud 16:117–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benabou R, Tirole J (2012) Laws and norms. IZA discussion paper 6290

  • Berkowitz AD (2004) The social norms approach: theory, research, and annotated bibliography

  • Bicchieri C (2006) The grammar of society. The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Brekke KA, Nyborg K (2010) Selfish bakers, caring nurses? A model of work motivation. J Econ Behav Organ 75:377–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burton RJF (2004) Seeing through the ‘Good Farmer’s’ eyes: towards developing an understanding of the social symbolic value of ‘Productivist’ behaviour. Sociol Ruralis 44:195–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burton R, Schwarz G (2013) Result-oriented agri-environmental schemes in Europe and their potential for promoting behavioural change. Land Use Policy 30:628–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chabe-Ferret S, Subervie J (2013) How much green for the buck? estimating additional and windfall effects of french agro-environmental schemes by did-matching. J Environ Econ Manag 65:12–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen X, Lupi F, He G, Liu J (2009) Linking social norms to efficient conservation investment in payments for ecosystem services. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 106:11812–11817

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini R, Trost M (1998) Social influence: social norms, conformity and compliance. Handb Soc Psychol 2:151–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini RB, Reno RR, Kallgren CA (1990) A focus theory of normative conduct: recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places. J Pers Soc Psychol 58:1015–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crocker J, Major B, Steele C (1998) Social stigma. In: Gilbert D, Fiske ST, Lindzey G (eds) The handbok of social psychology, 4th edn. Mc Grew Hill, New York, pp 504–553

    Google Scholar 

  • Czajkowski M, Hanley N, Nyborg K (2017) Social norms, morals and self-interest as determinants of pro-environment behaviours: the case of household recycling. Environ Resour Econ 66:647–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Defrancesco E, Gatto P, Runge F, Trestini S (2008) Factors affecting farmers’participation in agri-environmental measures: a northern Italian perspective. J Agric Econ 59:114–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Dessart FJ, Barreiro-Hurlé J, Van Bavel R (2019) Behavioural factors affecting the adoption of sustainable farming practices: a policy-oriented review. Eur Rev Agric Econ 46(3):417–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster J (1989) Social norms and economic theory. J Econ Perspect 3:99–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espinosa-Goded M, Barreiro-Hurle J, Dupraz P (2013) Identifying additional barriers in the adoption of agri-environmental schemes: the role of fixed costs. Land Use Policy 31:526–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Court of Auditors (2011) Is agri-environment support well designed and managed? Special Report No 7, p 82

  • Farrow K, Grolleau G, Ibanez L (2017) Social norms and pro-environmental behavior: a review of the evidence. Ecol Econ 140:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro PJ, Miranda JJ, Price MK (2011) The persistence of treatment effects with norm-based policy instruments: evidence from a randomized environmental policy experiment. Am Econ Rev 101:318–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber R, Bakker M, Balmann A, Berger T, Bithell M, Brown C, Grêt-Regamey A, Xiong H, Le QB, Mack G, Meyfroidt P, Millington J, Müller B, Polhill JG, Sun Z, Seidl R, Troost C, Finger R (2018) Representation of decision-making in European agricultural agent-based models. Agric Syst 167:143–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhfuss L, Preget R, Thoyer S (2014) Préférences individuelles et incitations collectives: quels contrats agroenvironnementaux pour la réduction des herbicides par les viticulteurs ? Revue d’Études en Agriculture et Environnement 95:111–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhfuss L, Préget R, Thoyer S, Hanley N, Le Coent P, Désolé M (2016) Nudges, social norms and permanence in agri-environmental schemes. Land Econ 92:641–655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lähdesmäki M, Siltaoja M, Luomala H, Puska P, Kurki S (2019) Empowered by stigma? Pioneer organic farmers’ stigma management strategies. J Rural Stud 65:152–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Coent P (2016) Agri-environmental schemes: behavioral insights and innovative designs, Unpublished PhD thesis, University of Montpellier

  • Le Coent P, Préget R, Thoyer S (2014) Why pay for nothing? An experiment on a conditional subsidy scheme in a threshold public good game. Econ Bull 34:1976–1989

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis David J, Barham Bradford L, Robinson Brian (2011) Are there spillovers in the adoption of clean technology? The case of organic dairy farming. Land Econ 87(2):250–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Nyberg S, Weibull JW (1999) Social norms and economic incentive in the welfare State. Quart J Econ 114:1–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopes A, Viriyavipart A, Tasneem D (2020) The role of social influence in crop residue management: evidence from Northern India. Ecol Econ 169:106563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mamine F, Fares M, Minviel JJ (2020) Contract design for adoption of agri-environmental practices: a meta-analysis of discrete choice experiments. Ecol Econ 176:106721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mettepenningen E, Vandermeulen V, Delaet K, Van Huylenbroeck G, Wailes E (2013) Investigating the influence of the institutional organisation of agri-environmental schemes on scheme adoption. Land Use Policy 33:20–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mills J, Gaskell P, Ingram J, Chaplin S (2018) Understanding farmers’ motivations for provinding unsubsidised environmental benefits. Land Use Policy 76:697–707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyborg K (2018) Social norms and the environment. Annu Rev Resour Econ 10:405–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyborg K, Howarth RB, Brekke KA (2006) Green consumers and public policy: on socially contingent moral motivation. Resour Energy Econ 28:351–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD—Trade and agriculture Directorate—Environment Directorate (2019) Economic and environmental sustainability performance of environmental policies in agriculture: a literature review, COM/TAD/CA/ENV/EPOC(2029)2/FINAL, p 62

  • Pannell DJ, Claasen R (2020) The roles of adoption and behaviour change in agricultural policy. Appl Econ Perspect Policy 42:31–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rege M (2004) Social norms and private provision of public goods. J Public Econ Theory 6:65–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schroeder CM, Prentice D (1998) Exposing pluralistic ignorance to reduce alcohol use among college students. J Appl Soc Psychol 28:2150–2180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz PW (1999) Changing behavior with normative feedback interventions: a field experiment on curbside recycling. Basic Appl Soc Psychol 21:25–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shang J, Croson R (2009) A field experiment in charitable contribution: the impact of social information on the voluntary provision of public goods. Econ J 119:1422–1439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thoyer S, Préget R (2019) Enriching the CAP evaluation toolbox with experimental approaches: introduction to the special issue. Eur Rev Agric Econ 46(3):347–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Villamayor-Tomas S, Sagebiel J, Olschewski R (2019) Bringing the neighbors in: a choice experiment on the influence of coordination and social norms on farmers’ willingness to accept agro-environmental schemes across Europe. Land Use Policy 84:200–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weibull JW (1995) Evolutionary game theory. MIT Press, Massachusetts

  • Westerink J, Pérez-Soba M, van Doorn A (2020) Social learning and land lease to stimulate the delivery of ecosystem services in intensive arable farming. Ecosyst Serv 44:101149

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raphaële Préget.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Following Rege (2004), we use the replicator dynamics to represent a “virtual” learning process of trial-and error.

“The replicator dynamics say that the growth rate of the population share using a certain strategy equals the difference between the strategy’s current payoff and the current average payoff in the population (Weibull 1995, p. 73).”

In our case, the replicator dynamics is given by:

$$ \dot{x}\left( x \right) = x\left( {U_{i}^{1} \left( x \right) - \bar{U}\left( x \right)} \right) $$

where \( \bar{U}\left( x \right) = xU_{i}^{1} \left( x \right) + \left( {1 - x} \right)U_{i}^{0} \left( x \right) \)

$$ \dot{x}\left( x \right) = x\left( {1 - x} \right)\Delta U\left( x \right)\dot{x}\left( x \right) = x\left( {1 - x} \right)\left[ {p - c + 2\lambda \left( {2x - 1} \right)} \right] $$

Stationary states are determined by \( \dot{x}\left( x \right) = 0 \). Thus, there are three stationary states: \( x = 0 \), \( x = 1 \) and \( x = x^{\prime} = \frac{1}{2} - \frac{p - c}{4\lambda } \).

For \( 0 < x < 1 \), \( \dot{x} > 0 \) if \( \Delta U = p - c + 2\lambda \left( {2x - 1} \right) > 0 \) and thus if and only if \( x > \frac{1}{2} - \frac{p - c}{4\lambda } = x^{\prime } \). Symmetrically, for \( 0 < x < 1 \), \( \dot{x} < 0 \) if \( \Delta U = p - c + 2\lambda \left( {2x - 1} \right) < 0 \) and thus if and only if \( x < \frac{1}{2} - \frac{p - c}{4\lambda } = x^{\prime } \). Hence, \( x = x^{\prime } \) is not an asymptotically stable state because if the share of farmers who enrol in PES moves above \( max\left\{ {0,x^{\prime } } \right\} \), then \( x > x^{\prime } \) and \( \Delta U > 0 \). Therefore, more farmers will enrol in PES. This process will continue until all farmers are enrolled and the asymptotically stable state \( x = 1 \) is reached. Symmetrically, if the share of farmers who enrol in PES moves below \( min\left\{ {1,x^{\prime } } \right\} \), then more farmers will quit the PES. This process will continue until all farmers leave the PES and the asymptotically stable state \( x = 0 \) is reached.

Appendix 2


Case 1: \( \hat{x} \le 0 \Leftrightarrow \sigma \le 2\lambda \)

The weight of the injunctive norm is not too strong relatively to the weight of the descriptive norm. In this first case \( \Delta U \) is always increasing on \( x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) and there are 3 subcases shown on Fig. 8.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Farmer’s utility variation for case 1

1a) If \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) then \( \Delta U > 0 \forall x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \). Thus there is a unique Nash equilibrium in which all farmers enrol in PES (\( x = 1) \).

1b) If \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) and \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then there is a unique \( x^{\prime } \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) such that \( \Delta U\left( {x^{\prime } } \right) = 0 \). In that case there are three Nash equilibria: \( x = 0 \), \( x = 1 \) and \( x = x^{\prime } \). However there are only two asymptotically stable states \( x = 0 \) and \( x = 1 \).

1c) If \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then \( \Delta U < 0 \forall x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) thus there is a unique Nash equilibrium in which no farmer enrols in PES (\( x = 0) \).


Case 2: \( 0 < \hat{x} < 1 \Leftrightarrow 2\lambda < \sigma < 8\lambda \)

The weight of the injunctive norm is not too strong and not too weak relatively to the weight of the descriptive norm. In this second case, \( \Delta U \) is first decreasing until \( \hat{x} \) and then increasing. There are 5 subcases, shown on Fig. 9.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Farmer’s utility variation for case 2

2a) If \( \Delta U_{min} > 0 \) then \( \Delta U > 0 \forall x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) thus there is a unique Nash equilibrium in which all farmers enrol in PES \( (x = 1) \).

2b) If \( \Delta U_{min} \le 0 \) and \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) and \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then there are two \( x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] (x^{\prime } \) and \( x^{\prime \prime } ) \) such that \( \Delta U\left( {x^{\prime } } \right) = \Delta U\left( {x^{\prime \prime } } \right) = 0 \). In that case, there are three Nash equilibria: \( x = x^{\prime } \), \( x = x^{\prime \prime } \) and \( x = 1 \). However there are only two asymptotically stable states in this coordination game: \( x = x^{\prime } \) and \( x = 1 \).

2c) If \( \Delta U_{min} \le 0 \) and \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) and \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then there is a unique \( x^{\prime } \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) such that \( \Delta U\left( {x^{\prime } } \right) = 0 \). In that case there are three Nash equilibria: \( x = 0 \), \( x = 1 \) and \( x = x^{\prime } \). However there are only two asymptotically stable states \( x = 0 \) and \( x = 1 \).

2d) If \( \Delta U_{min} \le 0 \) and \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) and \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then there is a unique \( x^{\prime } \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) such that \( \Delta U\left( {x^{\prime } } \right) = 0 \). In that case there is a unique Nash equilibria: \( x = x' \).

2e) If \( \Delta U_{min} \le 0 \) and \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) and \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then \( \Delta U < 0 \forall x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) thus there is a unique Nash equilibrium in which no farmer enrols in PES (\( x = 0) \).


Case 3: \( \hat{x} \ge 1 \Leftrightarrow \sigma \ge 8\lambda \)

The weight of the injunctive norm is strong relatively to the weight of the descriptive norm. In this last case \( \Delta U \) is always decreasing and there are 3 subcases shown on Fig. 10.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Farmer’s utility variation for case 3

(3a) If \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then \( \Delta U > 0 \forall x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) thus there is a unique Nash equilibrium in which all farmers enrol in PES (\( x = 1) \).

(3b) If \( \Delta U > 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) and \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 1 \) then there is a unique \( x^{\prime } \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) such that \( \Delta U\left( {x^{\prime } } \right) = 0 \). In that case there is a unique Nash equilibria: \( x = x^{\prime } \).

(3c) If \( \Delta U < 0 \) when \( x = 0 \) then \( \Delta U < 0 \forall x \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) thus there is a unique Nash equilibrium in which no farmer enrols in PES (\( x = 0) \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Le Coent, P., Préget, R. & Thoyer, S. Farmers Follow the Herd: A Theoretical Model on Social Norms and Payments for Environmental Services. Environ Resource Econ 78, 287–306 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00532-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00532-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation