Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-hgkh8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T21:31:51.430Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

READING KEYNES AT THE ZERO LOWER BOUND: THE GREAT DEPRESSION, THE LIQUIDITY TRAP, AND UNCONVENTIONAL POLICY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 June 2018

Richard Sutch*
Affiliation:
Distinguished Professor Emeritus of Economics, University of California, Riverside; and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research. Contact the author at richard.sutch@ucr.edu.

Abstract

John Maynard Keynes’s analysis of the Great Depression has strong parallels to recent theorizing about the post-2008 Great Recession. There are also remarkable similarities between the two historical episodes: the collapse of demand for new fixed investment, the role of the zero lower bound liquidity trap in hampering conventional monetary policy, the multi-year period of near-zero short-term rates, and the protracted period of subnormal prosperity. A major difference between then and now is that monetary authorities in the recent situation actively pursued an unconventional policy with massive purchases of long-term securities. Keynes couldn’t convince authorities of his era to pursue such a plan, but it was precisely the monetary policy he advocated for a depressed economy stuck at the zero lower bound of nominal interest rates.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I have received valuable advice from Ingo Barens, Michael Bauer, Susan Carter, John Cochrane, William Collins, Robert Dimand, Barry Eichengreen, Christopher Hanes, Joshua Hausman, Matthew Jaremski, Sarah John, Stephen Marglin, Gabriel Mathy, Pierluigi Molajoni, Larry Neal, Haelim Park, Peter Temin, and participants at the History of Economics Society Conference at Michigan State University, 2015. The editor and the readers for the Journal of the History of Economic Thought provided welcome guidance concerning the structure of the argument and many helpful specific suggestions. Financial support was provided by the Edward A. Dickson Endowment, University of California, Office of the President.

References

REFERENCES

Akerlof, George A., and Shiller, Robert J.. 2009. Animal Spirts: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Anderson, Richard G. 2010. “The First U.S. Quantitative Easing: The 1930s.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses 17 (30 June 2010): 12.Google Scholar
Basile, Peter F., Landon-Lane, John, and Rockoff, Hugh. 2010. “Money and Interest Rates in the United States during the Great Depression.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, Number 16204, July 2010. Also available in Wood, Geoffrey, Mills, Terence, and Crafts, Nicholas, eds., Monetary and Banking History: Essays in Honour of Forrest Capie. Chapter 7. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression.” American Economic Review 73, 3 (June): 257276.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2002. “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here.” Remarks before the National Economists Club, Washington, DC, November 21.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2015. The Courage to Act: A Memoir of a Crisis and its Aftermath. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S., and Lown, Cara S.. 1991. “The Credit Crunch.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 205239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, E. Cary. 1956. “Fiscal Policy in the Thirties: A Reappraisal.” American Economic Review 46, 5 (December): 857879.Google Scholar
Butkiewicz, James L. 2008. “Governor Eugene Meyer and the Great Contraction.” Research in Economic History 26: 273307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calomiris, Charles W., Mason, Joseph, and Wheelock, David. 2011. “Did Doubling Reserve Requirements Cause the Recession of 1937–1938? A Microeconomic Approach.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, Number 16688, January.Google Scholar
Cargill, Thomas F. 1992. “Irving Fisher Comments on Benjamin Strong and the Federal Reserve in the 1930s.” Journal of Political Economy 100, 6 (Centennial issue, December): 12731277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carter, Susan B., Sigmund Gartner, Scott, Haines, Michael R., Olmstead, Alan L., Sutch, Richard, and Wright, Gavin, eds. 2006. Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Time to the Present. Millennial edition. Five volumes. Cambridge: New York Office of Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cecchetti, Stephen G. 1988. “The Case of the Negative Nominal Interest Rates: New Estimates of the Term Structure of Interest Rates during the Great Depression.” Journal of Political Economy 96, 6 (December): 11111141.Google Scholar
Chambers, David, Dimson, Elroy, and Foo, Justin. 2015. “Keynes, King’s, and Endowment Asset Management.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, Number 20421, August 2014. Also in Brown, Jeffrey R. and Hoxby, Caroline M., eds., How the Financial Crisis and Great Recession Affected Higher Education. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2015: 127150.Google Scholar
Chawner, Lowell J. 1941. “Capital Expenditures for Manufacturing Plant and Equipment: 1915 to 1940.” Survey of Current Business 21, 3 (March): 915.Google Scholar
Childs, C. F. 1947. Concerning U. S. Government Securities: A Condensed Review of the Nation’s Currency, Public Debt, and the Market for Representative United States Government Loans, 1635–1945—Also a Chronology of Government Bond Dealers. Chicago: C. F. Childs and Company.Google Scholar
Dickson, Paul, and Allen, Thomas B.. 2004. The Bonus Army: An American Epic. New York: Walker and Company.Google Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 2015. “John Maynard Keynes Narrates the Great Depression: His Reports to the Philips Electronics Firm.” Paper presented at the Canadian Economics Association conference, Ryerson University, Toronto, May 2015; and the History of Economics Society conference, Michigan State University, East Lansing, June 2015. Cited with permission. https://charlesgide2016.sciencesconf.org/82666/document. Accessed 14 May 2018.Google Scholar
Dominguez, Kathryn M., Fair, Ray C., and Shapiro, Matthew D.. 1988. “Forecasting the Depression: Harvard versus Yale.” American Economic Review 78, 4 (September): 595612.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Gauti B. 2003. “How to Fight Deflation in a Liquidity Trap: Committing to Being Irresponsible.” International Monetary Fund, IMF Working Paper WP/03/64, March.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Gauti B. 2006. “The Deflation Bias and Committing to Being Irresponsible.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38, 2 (March): 283321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Gauti B. 2008. “Great Expectations and the End of the Depression.” American Economic Review 98, 4 (September): 14761516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Pugsley, Benjamin. 2006. “The Mistake of 1937: A General Equilibrium Analysis.” Monetary and Economic Studies 24 (Special edition, December): 151190.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Gauti, and Woodford, Michael. 2003. “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 139211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. 1992. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. 2015. Hall of Mirrors: The Great Depression, the Great Recession, and the Uses —and Misuses—of History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald, and Ferguson, Thomas. 1984. “Monetary Policy, Loan Liquidation, and Industrial Conflict: The Federal Reserve and the Open Market Operations of 1932.” Journal of Economic History 44, 4 (December): 957983.Google Scholar
Feenberg, Daniel, Miron, Jeffrey, Stern, Hanna, and Reichner, Esther D., contribs. National Bureau of Economic Research, Macrohistory Data Base. Online data base http://www.nber.org/databases/macrohistory/contents/. Accessed 16 April 2018.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Schwartz, Anna Jacobson. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1954. The Great Crash, 1929. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Gilboy, Elizabeth W. 1939. “The Propensity to Consume: Reply.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 53, 4 (August): 633638.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J., and Veitch, John M.. 1986. “Fixed Investment in the American Business Cycle, 1919–83.” In Gordon, Robert J., ed., The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 267357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert E. 2016. “Macroeconomics of Persistent Slumps.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, Number 22230, May.Google Scholar
Hanes, Christopher. 2006. “The Liquidity Trap and US Interest Rates in the 1930s.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38, 1 (February): 163194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Joshua K. 2016. “Fiscal Policy and Economic Recovery: The Case of the 1936 Veterans’ Bonus.” American Economic Review 106, 4 (April): 11001143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Joshua K., and Wieland, Johannes F.. 2014. “Abenomics: Preliminary Analysis and Outlook.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawtrey, Ralph G. 1933. Trade Depression and the Way Out. London: Longmans, Green and Co.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1937. “Mr. Keynes and the ‘Classics’: A Suggested Interpretation.” Econometrica 5, 2 (April): 147159.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. [1939] 2001. Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. Second edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1939. “Mr. Hawtrey on Bank Rate and the Long-term Rate of Interest.” The Manchester School 10, 2 (December): 144152.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1942. “The Monetary Theory of D. H. Robertson.” Economica 9, New Series 33 (February): 5357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoover, Kevin D. 2006. “Doctor Keynes: Economic Theory in a Diagnostic Science.” In Backhouse, Roger E. and Bateman, Bradley W., eds., The Cambridge Companion to Keynes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 7897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A. 2012. “Gold Sterilization and the Recession of 1937–38.” Financial History Review 19, 3 (December): 249267.Google Scholar
Jalil, Andrew, and Rua, Gisela. 2015. “Infiation Expectations and Recovery from the Depression in 1933: Evidence from the Narrative Record.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, Number 2015-029. http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2015.029. Accessed 16 April 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1928] 1973. “Is There Inflation in the United States?” Memorandum reproduced in Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 13, The General Theory and After, Part I, Preparation. New York: Macmillan St. Martin’s Press, pp. 5259.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1929] 1981. “A British View of the Wall Street Slump.” New York Evening Post, 25 October 1929. Reprinted in Donald Moggridge, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 20, Activities 1929–1931, Rethinking Employment and Unemployment Policies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 13.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1930a] 1971. A Treatise on Money. Two volumes. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1930b] 1978. “The Great Slump of 1930.” The Nation and Athenæum, 20 and 27 December 1930. Reprinted in John Maynard Keynes, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, edited by Johnson, Elizabeth and Moggridge, Donald. Volume 9, Essays in Persuasion. London: Royal Economic Society, pp. 135147.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1931a] 1970. “An Economic Analysis of Unemployment.” In Wright, Philip Quincy, ed., Unemployment as a World-Problem: Lectures on the Harris Foundation. Reprint edition. Freeport: Books for Libraries Press, 1970, pp. 3–42. Reprinted in Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 13: The General Theory and After, Part I, Preparation. New York: Macmillan St. Martin’s Press, 1973, pp. 343367.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1931b] 1981. “A Note on Economic Conditions in the United States.” Remarks prepared for the Economic Advisory Council and reproduced in Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 20: Activities 1929–1931, Rethinking Employment and Unemployment Policies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 561588.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1932. “A Note on the Long-Term Rate of Interest in Relation to the Conversion Scheme.” Economic Journal 42 , 167 (September): 415423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1933. “From Keynes to Roosevelt: Our Recovery Plan Assayed; The British Economist Writes an Open Letter to the President Finding Reasons, in Our Policies, for Both Hopes and Fears.” New York Times, 31 December 1933, p. 115.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1934] 1973. “Poverty in Plenty: Is the Economic System Self-Adjusting?” The Listener, 21 November 1934. Reprinted in Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 13, The General Theory and After, Part I, Preparation. New York: Macmillan St. Martin’s Press, pp. 485492.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1936] 1973. General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan. Reprinted in Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 7: The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Macmillan St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1936b] 1973. “Fluctuations in Net Investment in the United States.” Economic Journal 46, 183 (September) 540–547. Reprinted as Appendix 2 in Moggridge, Donald, ed., The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 7: The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Macmillan St. Martin’s Press, 1973, pp. 386393.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1937. “The General Theory of Employment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 51, 2 (February): 209223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 1998. “It’s Baaack! Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 137205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 2010. “That ’30s Feeling.” New York Times, 17 June, editorial page.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 2013. “Monetary Policy in a Liquidity Trap.” The Conscience of a Liberal. New York Times Blog, 11 April 2013. https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/11/monetary-policy-in-a-liquidity-trap/. Accessed 11 May 2018.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1934. “Gross Capital Formation, 1919–1933.” National Bureau of Economic Research Bulletin, Number 52, 15 November.Google Scholar
Lutz, Friedrich A. 1940. “The Structure of Interest Rates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 55, 1 (November): 3663.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory, Miron, Jeffrey A., and Weil, David N.. 1987. “The Adjustment of Expectations to a Change in Regime: A Study of the Founding of the Federal Reserve.” American Economic Review 77, 3 (June): 358374.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H. 2003. A History of the Federal Reserve. Volume 1: 1913–1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Modigliani, Franco, and Sutch, Richard. 1966. “Innovations in Interest Rate Policy.” American Economic Review 56, 2 (March): 178197.Google Scholar
Moggridge, Donald, ed. 1973. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volumes 13 and 14: The General Theory and After, Part I, Preparation, and Part II, Defence and Development. New York: Macmillan St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Moggridge, Donald, ed. 1979. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 29: The General Theory and After: A Supplement. New York: Macmillan; Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moggridge, Donald, ed. 1981–82. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volumes 20 and 21: Activities 1929–1931: Rethinking Employment and Unemployment Policies and Activities 1931–, 1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Moggridge, Donald, and Howson, Susan. 1974. “Keynes on Monetary Policy, 1910–1946.” Oxford Economic Papers 26 (New Series), 2 (July): 226247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moody’s Investors Services. 2016. “Rating Symbols and Definitions.” Moody’s Corporation. Online publication SP9121 / PBC_79004, December. https://www.moodys.com/research/Moodys-Rating-Symbols-Definitions–PBC_79004. Accessed 16 April 2018.Google Scholar
Nocera, Joe. 2008. “As Credit Crisis Spiraled, Alarm Led to Action.” New York Times, 2 October.Google Scholar
Park, Haelim, and Van Horn, Patrick. 2015. “Did the Reserve Requirement Increases of 1936–1937 Reduce Bank Lending? Evidence from a Quasi-Experiment.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 47, 5 (August): 791818.Google Scholar
Postel-Vinay, Natacha. 2016. “What Caused Chicago Bank Failures in the Great Depression? A Look at the 1920s.” Journal of Economic History 76, 2 (September): 478519.Google Scholar
Robertson, Dennis H. 1940. Essays in Monetary Theory. London: P.S. King and Son.Google Scholar
Romer, Christina D., and Romer, David H.. 2013. “The Most Dangerous Idea in Federal Reserve History: Monetary Policy Doesn’t Matter.” American Economic Review 103, 3 (May): 5560.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert J. [2000] 2005. Irrational Exuberance. Second edition. New York: Broadway Books.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1938. “The Downturn of 1937.” Review of Economics and Statistics 20, 3 (August): 97110.Google Scholar
Stauffer, Robert F. 2002. “Another Perspective on the Reserve Requirement Increments of 1936 and 1937.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 25, 1 (Autumn): 161179.Google Scholar
Sutch, Richard. 2006. “Business Fluctuations and Cycles.” In Carter, Susan B., Gartner, Scott Sigmund, Haines, Michael R., Olmstead, Alan L., Sutch, Richard, and Wright, Gavin, eds., Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Time to the Present. Millennial edition. Volume 3. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 71145.Google Scholar
Sutch, Richard. 2011. “The Impact of the 1936 Corn Belt Drought on American Farmers’ Adoption of Hybrid Corn.” In Libecap, Gary D. and Steckel, Richard H., eds., The Economics of Climate Change: Adaptations Past and Present. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 195223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tobin, James. 1958. “Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk.” Review of Economic Studies 25, 2 (February): 6586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. 1943. Banking and Monetary Statistics: 1914–1941. September.Google Scholar
US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. 2008, 2009, 2011, 2014, and 2015. “Federal Reserve Press Release,” 25 November 2008, 30 December 2008, 18 March 2009, 21 September 2011, 30 July 2014, 29 October 2014, 16 December 2015.Google Scholar
Werner, Richard. 2013. “Quantitative Easing and the Quantity Theory of Credit.” Royal Economics Society Newsletter, 5 July 2013. http://www.res.org.uk/view/art5jul13features.html. Accessed 16 April 2018.Google Scholar
Wigmore, Barrie A. 1987. “Was the Bank Holiday of 1933 Caused by a Run on the Dollar?” Journal of Economic History 47, 3 (September): 739755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodford, Michael. 2012. “Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Economic Policy Symposium on the Changing Policy Landscape, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 31 August 2012.Google Scholar
Wright, Philip Quincy, ed. [1931] 1970. Unemployment as a World-Problem: Lectures on the Harris Foundation. Reprint edition. Freeport: Books for Libraries Press.Google Scholar