Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Why do they JUST DO IT? A Theory of Outsourcing and Working Conditions

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Nike and other brand companies have long been criticized for outsourcing their production to contract factories with dismal working conditions. Despite the overwhelming amount of interest, there exists no theory for studying this topic. The current paper fills this gap. The framework embeds a compensating-wage-differentials model into the global sourcing model of Antràs and Helpman (2004). In the model, the most productive firms in the North make high profits and outsource their manufacturing production to contract factories in the South. Manufacturing production is inherently dangerous. The level of working conditions depends on their provision cost and on the country’s labor productivity. To attract workers, factories pay wages that can compensate for poor working conditions. Despite being higher, factory wages might not meet workers’ basic needs, but the reason is that the country’s labor productivity is too low. In the benchmark model, the only source of comparative advantage between the two countries is the difference in their labor productivities. Thus, a low-productivity country can attract more outsourcing contracts since its factories can produce at lower costs. The paper also studies an extension in which factory workers misperceive the true level of working conditions and in which factories might not comply with local legal standards. Under this extension, factory workers are not appropriately compensated for inferior working conditions. Moreover, differences in the degree of workers’ misperception and of factory noncompliance can be additional sources of comparative advantage between the countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See more details in Locke (2003) and Nike (2019).

  2. See, e.g., Moran (2002), Rosen (2002), and Sluiter (2009).

  3. See, e.g., Antràs and Helpman (2004, 2008), Grossman and Helpman (2004), and Grossman, et al. (2005).

  4. The literature on offshoring is also somewhat connected to this first strand. The seminal paper is Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008). Other important papers include Bergin et al. 2009; Crinò 2010; Rodriguez-Clare 2010; Wright 2014; and Goel 2017. This literature has studied the impact of offshoring on wages and on employment but has completely ignored the connection to working conditions. The current paper fills this gap.

  5. See Rosen (1987) for a summary.

  6. This literature is summarized in Brown (2000), Basu et al. (2003), and Donado and Wälde (2015).

  7. As it will be clear along the paper, individuals in the North (i = N) can work in one of five different types of occupations. They can either provide headquarter services (j = h), manufacturing services (j = m), fixed costs services (j = f), entry costs services (j = e), or produce the homogeneous good (j = y). In the South (i = S), individuals can only work in one of two occupations. They can either provide manufacturing services (j = m) or produce the homogeneous good (j = y).

  8. Empirical support for this assumption can be found in Fletcher et al. (2011), Cottini and Lucifora (2013), and Barnay (2014).

  9. See, e.g., Permanyer (2014) and the references therein.

  10. Note that setting \(u_{\min \limits }=0\) does not change the results of this paper in any significant way. The only point of introducing \(u_{\min \limits }>0\) in Eq. 2 is to capture the recurrent idea from the nonacademic literature that factory workers might not be able to meet their basic needs. Allowing for \(u_{\min \limits }>0\) also simplifies the presentation and discussion of the model’s main predictions below.

  11. The other reason is that only the North has the knowledge to produce final manufacturing goods (see below).

  12. Since all manufacturing firms are always located in the North, the superscript i on the variables directly associated with those manufacturing firms (hi, pi, qi, ri, πi, fi) only denotes the country in which they outsource their manufacturing stage m.

  13. See also Antràs (2016, ch. 4) and Antràs and Yeaple (2014, sect. 5.3). This assumption is typically made to abstract from the horizontal (FDI) dimension in which firms might replicate the same production process in another country to save on transportation costs or tariffs.

  14. See also Antràs 2016, ch. 4.

  15. See Chen and Chan (1999), Markkanen (2009: 23-28), and Conradi and Portich (2011).

  16. This can be seen after plugging Eq. 6 in Eq. 18.

  17. AMRC and HKCIC (1997). See also Chen and Chan (1999).

  18. In reality, factory owners might not have perfect knowledge on some working conditions either. For example, some occupational diseases might take several years to manifest, and even employers might not be aware of the causal link between a particular disease and factory production. However, what is important for the argument is that factory owners have more knowledge than workers. To simplify the model, the paper assumes that factory owners perceive working conditions as they truly are, while workers underperceive them.

  19. AMRC and HKCIC (1997). See also Chen and Chan (1999).

  20. I am especially thankful to two anonymous referees who suggested most of the ideas discussed in this section.

  21. See, e.g., Glass and Saggi (2001), Naghavi and Ottaviano (2008), Rodríguez-Clare (2010), Bøler et al. 2015, and Goel (2017).

  22. See, e.g., Edmonds and Pavcnik (2005) and Levine and Rothman (2006).

References

  • AMRC and HKCIC (1997) Asia Monitor Resource Centre and Hong Kong Christian Industrial Committee. Working conditions in sports shoe factories in China: Making shoes for Nike and Reebok. Available at http://www.corpwatch.org/article.php?id=3031

  • Antràs P, Helpman E (2004) Global sourcing. J Polit Econ 112(3):552–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs P, Helpman E (2008) Contractual frictions and global sourcing. In: Helpman E, Marin D, Thierry V (eds) The Organization of Firms in a Global Economy. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 9–54

  • Antràs P, Yeaple SR (2014) Multinational firms and the structure of international trade. In: Gopinath G, Helpman E, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of International Economics, vol 4. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 54–130

  • Antràs P (2016) Global production: Firms, contracts and trade structure. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ashenfelter O, Smith RS (1979) Compliance with the minimum wage law. J Polit Econ 87(2):333–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnay T (2014) Health, work and working conditions: A review of the European economic literature. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1148, OECD Publishing

  • Basu K, Horn H, Romn L, Shapiro J (2003) International labor standards: History, theory, and policy options. Blackwell Publishing Ltd, Malden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bergin PR, Feenstra RC, Hanson GH (2009) Offshoring and volatility: Evidence from Mexico’s maquiladora industry. Am Econ Rev 99(4):1664–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boler EA, Moxnes A, Ulltveit-Moe KH (2015) R&D, international sourcing, and the joint impact on firm performance. Amer Econ Rev 105(12):3704–3739

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown DK (2000) International trade and core labour standards: A survey of the recent literature. OECD Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers, No. 43, OECD Publishing

  • Chen M-, Chan A (1999) China’s “market economics in command”: Footwear workers’ health in jeopardy. Int J Health Serv 29(4):793–811

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor T (2002) We are not machines: Indonesian Nike and Adidas workers. Global Exchange, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Conradi FL, Portich P (2011) Footwear industry (in 88. leather, fur and footwear). In: McCann M, Stellman J M (eds) Encyclopedia of Occupational Health and Safety. International Labor Organization, Geneva

  • Cottini E, Lucifora C (2013) Mental health and working conditions in Europe. Ind Labor Rel Rev 66(4):958–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crin R (2010) Service Offshoring and White-Collar Employment. Rev Econ Stud 77(2):595–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond P (1977) Insurance theoretic aspects of workers’ compensation. In: Blinder A S, Friedman P (eds) Natural Resources, Uncertainty and General equilibrium Systems: Essays in Memory of Rafael Lusky. Academic Press, New York, pp 67–89

  • Donado A, Wälde K (2012) How trade unions increase welfare. Econ J 122(563):990–1009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donado A, Wälde K (2015) How bad is globalization for labour standards in the North? Working Paper

  • Edmonds E V, Pavcnik N (2005) The effect of trade liberalization on child labor. J Int Econ 65(2):401– 419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ernst & Young (1997) Environmental and labor practice audit. Available at http://www.corpwatch.org/article.php?id=2488

  • Fletcher JM, Sindelar JL, Yamaguchi S (2011) Cumulative effects of job characteristics on health. Health Econ 20(5):553–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass AJ, Saggi K (2001) Innovation and wage effects of international outsourcing. Eur Econ Rev 45(1):67–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goel M (2017) Offshoring - effects on technology and implications for the labor market. Eur Econ Rev 98:217–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenhouse S (1997) Nike shoe plant in Vietnam is called unsafe for workers. The New York Times

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (2004) Managerial incentives and the international organization of production. J Int Econ 63(2):237–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Rossi-Hansberg E (2008) Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1978–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossmanm GM, Helpman E, Szeidl A (2005) Complementarities between outsourcing and foreign sourcing. Am Econ Rev 95(2):19–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall JC, Leeson PT (2007) Good for the goose, bad for the gander: International labor standards and comparative development. J Labor Res 28(4):658–676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuruvilla S, Liu M, Li C, Chen W (2020) Field opacity and practice-outcome decoupling: Private regulation of labor standards in global supply chains. ILR Review 73(4):841–872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine DI, Rothman D (2006) Does trade affect child health?. J Health Econ 25(3):538–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locke RM (2003) The promise and perils of globalization: The case of Nike. In: Kochan T A, Schmalensee R L (eds) Management: Inventing and Delivering Its Future. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 39–70

  • Locke RM, Kochan T, Romis M, Qin F (2007a) Beyond corporate codes of conduct: Work organization and labour standards at Nike’s suppliers. Int Labour Rev 146(1-2):21–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locke RM, Qin F, Brause A (2007b) Does monitoring improve labor standards? lessons from Nike. Ind Labor Rel Rev 61(1):3–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markkanen P (2009) Shoes, glues, and homework: Dangerous work in the global footwear industry. Baywood Publishing Company, Amityville

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran T H (2002) Beyond sweatshops: Foreign direct investment and globalization in developing countries. Brookings Institution Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Naghavi A, Ottaviano G (2008) Outsourcing, contracts,and innovation networks. In: Brakman S, Garretsen H (eds) Foreign Direct Investment and the Multinational Enterprise. The MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 67–87

  • Nike (2019) Nike, inc. annual report on form 10-k. Nike, Inc., Beaverton

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Rourke D (1997) Smoke from a hired gun: A critique of Nike’s labor and environmental auditing in vietnam as performed by Ernst & Young. Available at http://www.corpwatch.org/article.php?id=966

  • Permanyer I (2014) Assessing individuals’ deprivation in a multidimensional framework. J Dev Econ 109:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell B, Skarbek D (2006) Sweatshops and third world living standards: Are the jobs worth the sweat?. J Labor Res 27(2):263–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell B (2014) Out of poverty: Sweatshops in the global economy. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rodríguez-Clare A (2010) Offshoring in a Ricardian world. Amer Econ J Macroecon 2(2):227–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1974) Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition. J Polit Econ 82(1):34–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1987) The theory of equalizing differences. In: Ashenfelter O, Layard R (eds) Handbook of Labor Economics, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 641–692

  • Rosen EI (2002) Making sweatshops: The globalization of the U.S. apparel industry. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1985) Commodities and capabilities. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Sluiter L (2009) Clean clothes: A global movement to end sweatshops. Pluto Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Spar DL (2002) Hitting the wall: Nike and international labor practices. Harvard Business School Case 9-700-047

  • Viscusi WK (1980) Imperfect job risk information and optimal workmen’s compensation benefits. J Publ Econ 14(3):319–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright GC (2014) Revisiting the employment impact of offshoring. Eur Econ Rev 66:63–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alejandro Donado.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The author would like to thank two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions.

I would like to thank two anonymous referees, Hartmut Egger, Thomas Eife, and participants at several workshops and conferences for helpful comments and suggestions.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 387 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Donado, A. Why do they JUST DO IT? A Theory of Outsourcing and Working Conditions. Open Econ Rev 32, 559–586 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-020-09609-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-020-09609-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation