Skip to main content
Log in

Structural fund, endogenous move and commitment

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we extend the study on combined tax and infrastructure competition by endogenizing the timing of decisions made by asymmetric countries. We consider how a structural fund affects the endogenous move decision and show that the poor country prefers to be a follower only when the production function is sufficiently concave. We also analyse the effect of the structural fund on total welfare and design a commitment game to ensure that the socially optimal outcome is achieved.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the present paper, we refer to hard and soft infrastructure. Hard infrastructure refers to physical facilities such as transportation and communications networks or electrical power facilities. Soft infrastructure refers to basic institutions that are essential to the functioning of a community, such as health, education, financial and legal systems.

  2. The ESIF consists of five main funds working together to support economic development across all the EU countries. These five funds are the European Regional Development Fund, the Cohesion Fund, the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development, the European Social Fund and the European Maritime and Fisheries Fund.

  3. During the period 2014–2020, the Cohesion Fund has assigned EUR 63.4 billion to activities under the trans-European networks (TENs) which includes infrastructure projects under the Connecting Europe Facility. Also encompassed within the Cohesion Fund are investments towards benefiting the environment such as promoting climate change, energy efficiency, the use of renewable energy and strengthening public transport. According to the data from European Commission, Poland, Romania and Czech Republic are the first three countries who receive the most amount of the Cohesion Fund. See https://ec.europa.eu/regional_policy/en/funding/cohesion-fund/ (downloaded July 2, 2020).

  4. Source: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/factsheets/en/sheet/96/cohesion-fund, downloaded July 21, 2020.

  5. Source: https://cohesiondata.ec.europa.eu/funds/cf, downloaded July 21, 2020.

  6. Kempf and Rota-Graziosi (2010) find that leadership by the small region is the risk dominant outcome using the pre-play stage as in Hamilton and Slutsky (1990). However, Hindriks and Nishimura (2015) show that leadership by the large region becomes the risk dominant equilibrium and can even become Pareto superior simply by reversing the form of asymmetry in Kempf and Rota-Graziosi (2010). Ogawa (2013) analyses the role of capital ownership in leadership in tax competition.

  7. See Altshuler and Goodspeed (2015) for empirical evidence. Wang (1999) asserts that “it is natural and conceivable that, in a real-world situation of tax-setting, the large region moves first” (p. 974). Baldwin and Krugman (2004) also make the same assumption of the large (core) region’s leadership to show that equilibrium tax rates remain higher in the core region than in the small (periphery). The argument there is that the intuitive leadership by the large region is based on its ability to exploit market power. The large region has greater market power that permits itself to benefit from higher tax rates.

  8. Other examples of studies that have used a linear quadratic production function include Bucovetsky (1991, 2009), Peralta and Ypersele (2006) and Itaya et al. (2008).

  9. If \(k_{1}=k_{2}=k\), \(g_{1}=g_{2}=g\) and \(S=0\) we have \(F_{2}-F_{1}= \varepsilon k\) and \(\partial F_{2}/\partial k_{2}-\partial F_{1}/\partial k_{1}=\varepsilon\).

  10. One interesting implication of this result is that there exists a conflict of interest between the two countries if \(\delta <1\). This opens up the possibility of a conditional transfer where the rich country is trying to induce a certain behaviour by the poor country through the structural fund. This is an interesting possibility but lies outside the scope of this study where we assume that the structural fund is exogenously given.

References

  • Altshuler, R., & Goodspeed, T. (2015). Follow the leader? Evidence on European and U.S. tax competition. Public Finance Review, 43(4), 485–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amir, R., & Grilo, I. (1999). Stackelberg versus Cournot equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior, 26, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, C., Bulir, A., Lane, T., & Lipschitz, L. (2009). The dynamic implications of foreign aid and its variability. Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 87–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Krugman, P. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation. European Economic Review, 48(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basile, R., Castellani, D., & Zanfei, A. (2008). Location choices of multinational firms in Europe: The role of EU cohesion policy. Journal of International Economics, 74(2), 328–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S. (1991). Asymmetric tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(2), 167–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S. (2009) An index of capital tax competition. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(6), 727–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2005). Does competition for capital discipline governments? Decentralization, globalization, and public policy. The American Economic Review, 95(3), 817–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalgaard, C. J., Hansen, H., & Tarp, F. (2004). On the empirics of foreign aid and growth. The Economic Journal, 114(496), F191–F216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Mello, L. (2008). The brazilian tax war: The case of value added tax competition among the states. Public Finance Review, 36(2), 169–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dembour, C., & Wauthy, X. (2009). Investment in public infrastructure with spillovers and tax competition between contiguous regions. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39, 679–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomes P., & Pouget F. (2008). Corporate tax competition and the decline of public investment. European Central Bank, 2008, Working Paper Series No. 928.

  • Hamilton, J. H., & Slutsky, S. M. (1990). Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or cournot equilibria. Games & Economic Behavior, 2(1), 29–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hauptmeier, S. F., & Mittermaier, J. R. (2012). Fiscal competition over taxes and public inputs. Regional Science & Urban Economics, 42(3), 407–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hindriks, J., & Nishimura, Y. (2015). A note on equilibrium leadership in tax competition models. Journal of Public Economics, 121, 66–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hindriks, J., Peralta, S., & Weber, S. (2008). Competing in taxes and investment under fiscal equalization. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 2392–2402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann M., & Rota Graziosi G. (2010). Endogenous timing game with non-monotonic reaction functions. CERDI, Etudes et Documents E, 2010, 17.

  • Itaya, J., Okamura, M. & Yamaguchi, C. (2008). Are regional asymmetries detrimental to tax coordination in a repeated game setting? Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2403–2411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janeba, E., & Osterloh, S. (2013). Tax and the city: A theory of local tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 106(6), 89–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kempf, H., & Rota-Graziosi, G. (2010). Endogenizing leadership in tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9–10), 768–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kempf, H., & Graziosi, G. R. (2010). Leadership in public good provision: A timing game perspective. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(4), 763–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar M. S., & Quinn D. P. (2012). Globalization and corporate taxation. IMF Working Paper WP/12/252. Washington, DC: IMF Fiscal Affairs and Finance Department.

  • Normann, H. T. (2002). Endogenous timing with incomplete information and with observable delay. Games and Economic Behavior, 39, 282–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, H. (2013). Further analysis on leadership in tax competition: The role of capital ownership. International Tax & Public Finance, 20(3), 474–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peralta, S. & van Ypersele, T. (2006). Coordination of capital taxation among asymmetric countries. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(6), 708–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pieretti, P., & Zanaj, S. (2011). On tax competition, public goods provision and jurisdictions’ size. Journal of International Economics, 84, 124–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swank, D. (2016). Taxing choices: International competition, domestic institutions and the transformation of corporate tax policy. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(4), 571–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Y. Q. (1999). Commodity taxes under fiscal competition: Stackelberg equilibrium and optimality. American Economic Review, 89(4), 974–981.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. E. (1988). Nash equilibrium in models of fiscal competition. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 229–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1986). A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 296–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zissimos, B., & Wooders, M. (2008). Public good differentiation and the intensity of tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1105–1121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow, G. R., & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We appreciate the valuable discussions of this work with the participants of the workshop at Beijing University of Technology (2019). Of course, all eventual mistakes and errors are ours. The project is supported by NSFC (Nos. 71503044 and 71973024), Beijing Social Science Foundation (No. 18YJC017), Huiyuan Excellent Young Scholar (No. 17YQ19) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities in UIBE (CXTD11-01).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yutao Han.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Eckel, C., Han, Y., Hynes, K. et al. Structural fund, endogenous move and commitment. Int Tax Public Finance 28, 465–482 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09641-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09641-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation